Skip to main content

Full text of "Location and space-economy: a general theory relating to industrial location, market areas, land use, trade, and urban structure"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY 
OF  FLORIDA 
LIBRARIES 


Location 

and 

Space-Economy 


TECHNOLOGY  PRESS  BOOKS 
IN  THE  SOCIAL  SCIENCES 

Location  and  Space-Economy 
By  Walter  Isard 

Science  and  Economic  Development:  New  Patterns  of  Living 
By  Richard  L.  Meier 

Moscow  and  the  Communist  Party  of  India 

By  John  H.  Kautsky 
Language,  Thought  and  Reality 

By  Benjamin  Lee  Whorf 

Edited  by  John  B.  Carroll 
The  Terms  of  Trade:  A  European  Case  Study 

By  Charles  P.  Kindleberger 
Machine  Translation  of  Languages 

Edited  by  W.  N.  Locke  and  A.  D.  Booth 
An  American  Policy  in  Asia 

By  W.  W.  Rostow  and  R.  W.  Hatch 
Nine  Soviet  Portraits 

By  Raymond  A.  Bauer 
The  Prospects  for  Communist  China 

By  W.  W.  Rostow  and  others 
Labor  Mobility  and  Economic  Opportunity 

By  Members  of  the  Social  Science  Research  Council 
Nationalism  and  Social  Communication 

By  Karl  W.  Deutsch 
Industrial  Relations  in  Sweden 

By  Charles  A.  Myers 
Pressures  on  Wage  Decisions 

By  George  P.  Schultz 
The  Dollar  Shortage 

By  Charles  P.  Kindleberger 
Mid-Century:  The  Social  Implications  of  Scientific  Progress 

Edited  by  John  E.  Burchard 
Cybernetics:   Or  Control  and  Communication  in  the  Animal 
and  the  Machine 

By  Norbert  Wiener 
The  Movement  of  Factory  Workers 

By  Charles  A.  Myers  and  W.  Rupert  Maclaurin 


Location 

and 

Space-Economy 


A  General  Theory  Relating  to  Industrial  Location, 

Market  Areas,  Land  Use,  Trade, 

and  Urban  Structure 

by 

WALTER  ISARD 

Professor  of  Economics 
University  of  Pennsylvania 


PUBLISHED    JOINTLY   BY 

The  Technology  Press  of 
Massachusetts  Institute  of  Technology 

AND 

John  Wiley  &  Sons,  Inc.,  New  York 
Chapman  &  Hall,  Ltd.,  London 


Copyright  ©   1956 

by 

Tlie  Massachusetts  Institute  of  Technology 

All  Rights  Reserved 

This  book  or  any  part  thereof  must 
not  be  reproduced  in  any  form  without 
the  written  permission  of  the  publisher. 


Library  of  Congress  Catalog  Card  Number:  56-11026 
Printed  in  the  United  States  of  America 


To 
Alvin  H.  Hansen 

and 
Abbott  P.  Usher 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2010  with  funding  from 

Lyrasis  IVIembers  and  Sloan  Foundation 


http://www.archive.org/details/locationspaceecoOOisar 


Preface 


Over  the  historical  record,  the  process  of  social  development  and 
economic  growth  has  been  for  the  most  part  cumulative  though  at 
times  seemingly  erratic.  On  occasion  it  has  been  recessive.  Some  of  its 
stages  have  been  forced  to  start  at  their  origins  more  than  once. 
Moreover,  these  stages  have  started  independently  at  diverse  places 
on  the  earth  at  different  times.  Together  with  the  manifold  cultural, 
political,  social,  and  economic  forces  which  have  evolved  this  fact  has 
led,  over  the  centuries,  to  marked  regional  differentiations  and  to  tre- 
mendous disparities  in  the  welfare  of  the  peoples  of  the  several  regions 
of  the  world. 

Such  a  record  of  man's  adaptation  to,  and  interaction  with,  his 
physical  environment  suggests  that  a  comprehensive  theory  of  society 
or  economy  should  embrace  both  time  and  space  dimensions.  It  should 
be  able  to  unravel  the  dynamic  interplay  of  forces  not  only  currently 
but  also  over  the  long  past.  Its  propositions  should  be  testable  against 
the  background  of  historic  development  in  the  several  regions  of  the 
world  and  concomitantly  should  offer  explanation  of  this  development. 
Its  hypotheses  should  encompass  the  influence  of  past  events  and  inter- 
mingling of  forces  upon  existing  economic  and  social  structure  and 
conditions.  Ideally,  its  conceptual  framework  should  enable  one  to 
anticipate  the  course  of  future  development,  given  certain  premises 
and  judgments. 

Unhappily,  the  state  of  the  social  science  disciplines  leaves  very 


viii  PREFACE 

much  to  be  desired  in  the  way  of  achieving  such  a  comprehensive 
theory.  The  dynamic  frameworks  of  these  disciplines,  frameworks 
which  are  designed  to  catch  the  effect  of  what  some  characterize  as  the 
"time  variable,"  are  rather  crude  and  even  at  times  naive.  Still  more 
so  are  their  spatial  and  regional  frameworks. 

It  is  the  basic  objective  of  this  volume  to  improve  the  spatial  and 
regional  frameworks  of  the  social  science  disciplines,  particularly  of 
economics,  through  the  development  of  a  more  adequate  general  theory 
of  location  and  space-economy.  As  a  matter  of  course,  we  must  work 
within  the  setting  of  dynamic  techniques  and  frameworks  currently 
available.  Since  these  are  inadequate,  a  chief  limitation  of  this  volume 
is  its  inability  to  cope  satisfactorily  with  the  development  process  over 
time. 

Another  limitation  is  imposed  by  the  inherent  weaknesses  of  general 
theories.  General  theories  have  a  widespread  reputation  for  being 
sterile  in  terms  of  concrete  social  problems  and  related  policy  recom- 
mendations. As  one  critic  has  put  it,  we  "are  all  too  apt,  seizing  upon 
the  conditions  of  a  particular  period  of  time  and  extent  of  space  and 
applying  the  simplifying  processes  of  selection  and  emphasis  to  which 
economic  theorizing  seems  all  too  prone,  to  come  forth  with  a  system 
of  universalized  'laws,'  a  system  which  is  perhaps  not  implausible  at 
its  time  and  place  of  origin,  but  which,  as  it  becomes  increasingly 
concerned  about  the  consistency  of  its  internal  logic,  turns  in  upon 
itself,  and  grows  more  and  more  remote  from  reality." i 

Admittedly  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy  evolved 
in  this  volume  is  of  little  direct  utility  for  handling  specific  problems 
of  reality.  That  it  should  be  of  immediate  relevance  was  not  the 
author's  intention.  But  as  one  proceeds  to  the  materials  to  be  con- 
tained in  a  second  volume,  ^  where  less  general  and  more  useful  theo- 
retical frameworks  are  developed,  he  may  perceive  how  the  general 
principles  and  constructs  derived  in  this  volume  are  of  use  in  furnish- 
ing penetrating  insights  into  the  operation  of  economic  processes  in  the 
real  world.  Also,  they  facilitate  the  choice  of  those  structural  relations 
subject  to  empirical  estimation  which  are  the  more  significant  ones  for 
analytic  purposes.  At  least  the  author  has  found  the  general  statement 
of  conditions  of  equilibrium  extremely  helpful  as  a  background  against 
which  various  location  and  spatial  doctrines  could  be  contrasted  and 

1  John  H.  Williams,  "An  Economist's  Confessions,"  The  American  Economic 
Review,  XLII,  March  1952,  pp.  6-7.  The  words  in  itahcs  have  been  inserted  by 
the  author. 

Significant,  however,  is  Professor  WiUiams'  wilUngness  to  attribute  some  signif- 
icance to  Keynes'  remark  that  without  theory  we  are  "lost  in  the  woods"  (ibid., 
p.  23). 

2  For  some  details  on  the  contents  of  this  second  volume,  see  pp.  x-xi. 


PREFACE  ix 

subsequently  ordered  and  evaluated  according  to  content.  This  eased 
the  process  of  digestion,  enabling  the  author  to  achieve  for  himself  an 
improved  and  less  confusing  reformulation  of  ideas.  It  also  provided 
a  sharper  conception  of  the  manifold  spatial  processes  at  play  and  the 
manner  in  which  individual  ones  are  related  to  each  other  and  to  the 
array  as  a  whole. 

Still  another  serious  limitation  of  the  analysis  is  to  be  noted.  A 
presentation  of  conditions  of  equilibrium  in  a  theoretical  system  may 
seem  to  imply  a  tendency  toward  the  attainment  of  a  state  of  equilib- 
rium in  the  real  world.  But  in  a  full  historic  sense,  actual  economic 
life  never  does  realize  a  state  of  equilibrium.  There  are  always  changes 
impinging  upon  the  economy.  The  process  of  adjustment  is  constantly 
in  operation.  Witness,  for  example,  the  adaptation  of  population  to 
environment.  There  has  never  been  a  complete  adjustment  which 
might  be  said  to  characterize  an  optimum  or  equilibrium  spatial  dis- 
tribution of  population. 

As  Usher  has  neatly  put  it, 

"Classical  and  neo-classical  theory  rest  upon  a  concept  of  equilibrium  that 
becomes  a  source  of  serious  difficulty  in  historical  analysis.  It  is  implied 
that  disturbances  of  the  socio-economic  equilibrium  are  small  in  magnitude 
and  quickly  corrected  by  adaptive  changes.  Such  disturbances  do  exist, 
and  market  processes  have  developed  that  deal  with  some  measure  of 
adequacy  with  these  minor  disturbances  of  the  equilibrium.  But  these 
are  not  the  only  disturbances  that  occur  in  the  socio-economic  world. 
The  world  economy  is  beset  by  other  disturbances,  whose  magnitude  is 
of  such  an  order  that  adjustments  require  several  generations.  .  ."  3 

"The  most  dangerous  of  all  transfers  of  the  equilibrium  concept  appears 
when  the  ideal  of  stability  is  represented  as  a  characteristic  of  long-run 
conditions.  All  the  data  of  history  show  that  the  empirical  phenomena 
are  dynamic,  and  that  for  the  world  economy  as  a  whole  secular  change 
is  positive;  in  some  periods,  the  rates  of  growth  are  not  large;  in  partic- 
ular regions  contraction  may  occur  over  substantial  periods  of  time. 
Whether  it  be  growth,  or  cumulative  change  that  may  be  classed  as 
progress,  secular  change  cannot  be  described  as  a  condition  of  equi- 
librium." 4 

Despite  the  disrupting  effects  of  technological  advance  and  other 
dynamic  phenomena  and  the  consequent  failure  to  attain  equilibrium 
in  the  secular  sense, ^  there  is  still  value  in  equilibrium  analysis.    It  is 

3  Abbott  P.  Usher,  "The  Pattern  of  the  World  Economy,"  unpublished  essay, 
pp.  10-11. 

"*  Ibid.,  p.  17.  These  statements  were  written  in  the  1930's.  and  should  be  modi- 
fied somewhat  in  view  of  subsequent  developments  in  equilibrium  analysis. 

5  Usher's  thesis  is  of  broader  content.  Its  more  extensive  ramifications  are  worth 
noting  here.    In  Usher's  words: 

"The  broad  elements  of  differentiation  among  societies  in  their  various  his- 
torical worlds  rest  on  differences  in  the  maturity  of  settlement  of  the  various 


X  PREFACE 

thought  pertinent  and  worthwhile  by  some  who  conceive  of  the  socio- 
economic system  as  a  body  tending  toward  a  moving  equilibrium  and 
by  others  who  find  in  equilibrium  analysis  categories  of  reference  with 
which  the  extent  of  disequilibrium  can  be  measured.  Most  important, 
equilibrium  analysis  is  valuable  because  it  enables  one  to  grasp  better 
the  laws  of  change  and  the  workings  of  a  system.  In  doing  so,  it 
necessarily  casts  light  upon  the  long-run  interaction  of  diverse  forces 
and  can  yield  valuable  insights  for  historical  trend  projection  in  any 
concrete  situation. ^ 

As  the  reader  will  quickly  perceive,  the  first  and  third  chapters  of 
this  volume  were  designed  for  a  book  which  would  encompass  a  broader 
field  than  is  actually  covered.  The  initial  plan  was  to  devote  a  con- 
siderable part  of  this  volume  to  regional  analysis.  However,  as  the 
structure  of  the  manuscript  took  form,  it  became  advisable,  in  view 
of  the  quantity  of  materials  to  be  developed,  to  present  the  materials 
in  two  volumes.  During  the  next  years  therefore  a  companion  volume 
will  be  prepared  which  will  treat  the  principles  of  regional  science  and 
general  regional  theory.  (The  impatient  reader  may  glean  some  of 
the  contents  of  this  second  volume  from  the  articles  cited  below.'') 
Together  these  two  volumes  will  form  a  unit,  to  which  the  first  and 
third  chapters  of  this  first  completed  volume  relate. 

regions,  differences  in  culture,  differences  in  technical  knowledge,  differences 
in  the  material  resources  of  the  region.  Much  theoretical  discussion  presumes 
that  the  first  three  classes  of  differences  will  be  progressively  equalized  by  the 
diffusion  of  population,  culture,  and  technical  skills.  Some  even  presume  that 
differentiation  of  material  resources  becomes  less  and  less  important  as  tech- 
nical knowledge  progresses.  .  ." 

"There  is  nothing  in  the  historical  record  to  warrant  the  presumption  that  the 
elements  of  difference  have  diminished  significantly  in  intensity.  Changes  of 
great  importance  have  occurred,  but  it  would  not  be  difficult  to  defend  the 
proposition  that  the  world  of  effective  contacts  at  the  present  time  is  more 
highly  differentiated  than  the  world  as  known  to  the  Romans  of  the  Augustan 
age,  or  the  world  of  the  third  century  a.d."     (Ibid.,  p.  4.) 

".  .  .  it  must  be  evident  that  the  discovery  of  means  of  utilizing  new  ma^- 
terials  merely  sets  new  limits  to  the  scarcities  that  dominate  our  social  life. 
The  unbalanced  and  unequal  distribution  of  material  resources  must  always 
leave  us  with  a  world  pattern  of  unequal  and  unbalanced  distribution  of  the 
resources  of  primary  importance  to  social  life.  Regional  differentiation  will 
remain  important  however  much  the  specific  patterns  of  distribution  may  be 
changed  by  new  discoveries  and  new  technologies."     (Ibid.,  pp  7-8) 

6  For  example,  concentration  upon  substitution  among  transport  inputs  along 
the  lines  of  classical  and  neoclassical  equilibrium  analysis  to  be  discussed  in  a 
subsequent  chapter  yields  a  framework  for  partially  explaining  not  only  the 
current  locational  pattern  of  the  iron  and  steel  industry  but  also  the  changing 
historical  pattern  over  the  last  two  centuries. 

7  The  author's  writings,  which  contain  materials  to  be  incorporated  and  further 


PREFACE  XI 

The  writing  of  this  volume  was  begun  some  ten  years  ago.  Conse- 
quently, certain  materials  may  seem  a  bit  dated.  In  particular,  Chap. 
2,  which  was  largely  completed  by  1947,  points  up  an  imbalance  in 
the  Anglo-Saxon  literature  which  during  recent  years  has  been  some- 
what corrected.  Nonetheless,  the  earlier  statements  have  not  been 
qualified  or  tempered.  The  sharp  criticism  and  emphasis  of  these 
statements  are  retained  in  order  not  to  lose  whatever  potency  and  vigor 
the  argument  as  first  developed  may  have  contained. 

In  the  light  of  this  partial  correction  of  the  imbalance  in  the  Anglo- 
Saxon  literature,  I  have  changed  my  terminology,  for  which  I  must 
apologize.  In  previous  writings  the  movement  of  a  unit  weight  of  a 
particular  commodity  over  a  unit  of  distance  was  defined  as  a  distance 
input.  Such  a  movement  could  also  have  been  defined  as  a  transport 
input.  This  latter  term  would  have  been  more  in  keeping  with  the 
existing  usage  of  words.  However,  given  the  neglect  by  economic 
theorists  of  the  distance  variable  and  role  of  space,  it  was  decided  in 
these  early  writings  to  use  the  term  distance  inputs.  This  was  judged 
desirable  in  order  to  make  as  explicit  as  possible  the  significance  of 
transport  costs  and  the  distance  factor  in  shaping  economic  phenomena. 

expanded  in  this  volume,  are  in  chronological  order  of  development:  "Inter- 
regional and  Regional  Input-Output  Analysis:  A  Model  of  a  Space-Economy," 
Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  Vol.  33  (November  1951),  pp.  318-328;  "Re- 
gional and  National  Product  Projections  and  Their  Interrelations"  (with  G. 
Freutel),  Long-Range  Economic  Projection,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Re- 
search, Studies  in  Income  and  Wealth,  Vol.  16,  Princeton  University  Press, 
Princeton,  1954,  pp.  427-471 ;  "Some  Empirical  Results  and  Problems  of  Regional 
Input-Output  Analysis,"  in  Leontief  et  al.,  Studies  in  the  Structure  of  the  Ameri- 
can Economy,  Oxford  University  Press,  New  York,  1953,  pp.  116-181;  "Some 
Emerging  Concepts  and  Techniques  for  Regional  Analysis,"  Zeitschrift  fur  die 
Gesamte  Staatswissenschaft,  Vol.  109  (1953),  pp.  240-250;  "Regional  Commodity 
Balances  and  Interregional  Commodity  Flows,"  Papers  and  Proceedings  of  the 
American  Economic  Association,  Vol.  43  (May  1953),  pp.  167-180;  "The  Impact 
of  Steel  upon  the  Greater  New  York-Philadelphia  Industrial  Region:  A  Study 
in  Agglomeration  Projection"  (with  R.  E.  Kuenne),  Review  of  Economics  and 
Statistics,  Vol.  35  (November  1953),  pp.  289-301;  "Location  Theory  and  Trade 
Theory:  Short-run  Analysis,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  68  (May 
1954),  pp.  305-320;  "Economic  Structural  Interrelations  of  Metropohtan  Regions" 
(with  R.  Kavesh),  American  Journal  of  Sociology,  Vol.  60  (September  1954),  pp. 
152-162 ;  "Industrial  Complex  Analysis  and  Regional  Development  with  Particular 
Reference  to  Puerto  Rico"  (with  T.  Vietorisz),  Abstract  in  Papers  and  Proceed- 
ings of  the  Regional  Science  Association,  Vol.  1  (1955);  "The  Value  of  the 
Regional  Approach  in  Economic  Analysis,"  Regional  Income,  National  Bureau 
of  Economic  Research,  Studies  in  Income  and  Wealth,  Vol.  21,  Princeton  Univer- 
sity Press,  Princeton,  1956;  "Regional  Science,  The  Concept  of  Region,  and 
Regional  Structure,"  Papers  and  Proceedings  of  the  Regional  Science  Association, 
Vol.  2  (1956),  pp.  13-26;  and  an  extensive  manuscript  on  tools  and  techniques 
of  regional  analysis  to  be  published  by  Resources  for  the  Future,  Inc. 


xii  PREFACE 

Now  that  economists  are  more  aware  of  the  space  axis  and  the  spatial 
aspects  of  their  subject  matter,  it  seems  appropriate  to  employ  the 
more  customary  terminology  of  trans-port  inputs,  particularly  in  order 
to  facilitate  interdisciplinary  exchange  of  knowledge,  ideas,  and  tech- 
niques of  analysis  in  the  broad  field  of  regional  and  area  studies. 

I  am  indebted  to  a  host  of  individuals,  each  of  whom  has  contributed 
in  one  way  or  other  to  the  writing  and  preparation  of  this  volume. 
The  major  influence  of  one  of  the  two  outstanding  economists  and 
personalities  to  whom  this  book  is  dedicated  is  immediately  apparent 
in  the  first  few  sentences  of  the  Preface.  Professor  Abbott  P.  Usher 
has  been  a  constant  source  of  inspiration.  His  ever-present  encourage- 
ment and  guidance  and  his  vast  fund  of  knowledge,  which  was  always 
generously  made  available,  have  been  invaluable  in  the  development 
of  ideas. 

An  equally  strong  influence  stems  from  the  teachings  and  writings 
of  Professor  Alvin  H.  Hansen.  The  tremendous  stimulation  derived 
from  discussions  with  Professor  Hansen,  especially  in  the  formative 
stages  of  this  study,  cleared  the  way  of  obstacles  which  often  beset  an 
attempt  at  general  theorizing.  His  persistent  urgings  to  make  bold 
and  creative  attacks  upon  problems  have  added  immeasurably  to  the 
contents  of  the  volume. 

My  wife  has  given  freely  of  her  time  and  patience  in  the  preparation 
of  this  volume.  She  has  assisted  not  only  in  the  presentation  of  ideas 
but  also  in  their  logical  derivation. 

Many  others — former  teachers,  graduate  students,  and  associates — 
have  been  helpful  in  diverse  ways.  At  the  risk  of  failing  to  mention 
all  who  deserve  such  mention,  I  gratefully  acknowledge  the  help  of 
Joseph  Airov,  Martin  J.  Beckmann,  John  F.  Bell,  Edward  H. 
Chamberlin,  Edgar  Dunn,  Guy  Freutel,  Gottfried  von  Haberler, 
Seymour  E.  Harris,  Edgar  M.  Hoover,  Robert  Kavesh,  John  Kimber, 
Robert  E.  Kuenne,  Sven  Laursen,  Wassily  W.  Leontief,  Fritz  Machlup, 
Russell  Mack,  Leon  Moses,  C.  Reinold  Noyes,  Merton  J.  Peck,  Win- 
field  Riefler,  Paul  A.  Samuelson,  Eugene  Schooler,  Benjamin  Stevens, 
Edward  L.  Ullman,  and  Thomas  Vietorisz. 

Gerald  A.  P.  Carrothers  has  rendered  invaluable  service  in  the  con- 
struction of  the  figures;  and  Richard  Pfister,  in  the  development  of 
the  index.  I  am  indebted  to  Alexia  Hanitsch  and  Gabrielle  Fuchs  for 
competent  secretarial  assistance. 

The  Harvard  University  Press,  the  Yale  University  Press,  Richard 
D.  Irwin,  Inc.,  the  Addison-Wesley  Publishing  Company,  Inc.,  and 
the  editors  of  the  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Econometrica,  and 
Metroeconomica  have  kindly  granted  permission  to  use  previously 


PREFACE  xiii 

published  materials  in  direct  or  amended  form.  Chapters  2,  4,  9,  and 
parts  of  Chap.  5  are  largely  drawn  from  articles  appearing  in  the 
November  1949,  May  1951,  February  1954,  and  August  1951  issues, 
respectively,  of  the  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics.  Some  materials 
from  these  articles  also  appear  in  other  chapters  of  this  book.  Chapter 
10  is  a  splicing  of  two  articles,  one  of  which  appeared  in  Econometrica, 
Vol.  20,  No.  3,  July  1952,  and  the  other  in  Metroeconomica,  Vol.  5, 
No.  1,  April  1953. 

I  am  grateful  to  the  Social  Science  Research  Council  for  a  post- 
doctoral fellowship  which  enabled  me  to  initiate  the  development  of 
this  general  theory.  The  writing  of  the  final  chapters,  the  construction 
of  the  index,  and  the  completion  of  this  book  has  been  facilitated  by 
a  grant  from  Resources  for  the  Future,  Inc. 

Walter  Isard 
Cambridge,  Massachusetts 
September,  1956 


Contents 


chapter  page 

1  •  Introduction:  Posing  the  Location  and  Regional  Problem     ...         1 

1  •  Some  Basic  Development  Processes     1 

2  •  Some  Fundamental  Questions    9 

3  •  Possible  Theoretical  Approaches     15 

2  •  Some  General  Theories  of  Location  and  Space-Economy  ....       24 

1  •  The  Anglo-Saxon  Bias    24 

2  •  Some  Early  Attempts  at  General  Theory    27 

3  •  Predohl's  Conception    31 

4  •  Weigmann's  Formulation    37 

5  •  Palander's  Criticisms  and  Losch's  General  System    42 

6  •  Ohlin's  View  of  Trade  and  Location  Theory    50 

7  •  Closing  Remarks    53 

3  •  Some  Empirical  Regularities  of  the  Space-Economy 55 

4  •  Transport  Inputs  and  Related  Spatial  Concepts 77 

1  •  General  Introductory  Remarks    77 

2  •  Transport  Inputs  Contrasted  with  Capital  Inputs    81 

3  •  Transport  Rate:  The  Price  of  a  Transport  Input    86 

4  •  Transport  Inputs  and  the  Classification  of  Factors    89 

5  •  The  Locational  Equilibrium  of  the  Firm:  Transport — Orientation      91 

1  •  Some  Definitional  and  Classificational  Remarks    91 

2  •  Transport-oriented  Equilibrium  under  SimpHfied  Conditions     95 

3  •  Transport-oriented  Equilibrium  with  Realistic  Rate  Structures     104 

4  •  Transport-oriented  Equilibrium  Further  Extended     113 

Appendix  to  Chapter  5 — Transport  Inputs  and  Some  Formulations  of 
the  Transport-orientation  Problem     119 


xvi  CONTENTS 

chapter  page 

6  •  The  Locational  Equilibrium  of  the  Firm:  Labor  and  Other 

Orientation 126 

1  •  Introductory  Remarks     126 

2  •  Labor  Orientation     127 

3  •  Some  Other  Forms  of  Orientation    131 

4  •  A  Re-examination  of  the  Substitution  Framework  for  Spatial 

Analysis    138 
Appendix  to  Chapter  6 — The  Labor  Coefficient  and  a  Related  Ratio     141 

7  •  Market  and  Supply  Area  Analysis  and  Competitive  Locational 

Equilibrium 143 

1  •  Market  Area  Analysis     143 

2  •  Supply  (Purchasing)  Area  Analysis     154 

3  •  Some  Remarks  on  Spatial  Pricing  Systems  and  Competitive 

Locational  Equihbrium     158 

4  •  Concluding  Remarks     169 

8  •  Agglomeration  Analysis  and  Agricultural  Location  Theory  .     .     .     172 

1  •  Economies  of  Scale    173 

2  •  Localization  Economies     176 

3  •  Urbanization  Economies     182 

'4  •  Agricultural  Location  Theory     188 

Appendix  to  Chapter  8 — Some  Theoretical  Notes  on  Urban 
Land-use    200 

9  •  Some  Basic  Interrelations  of  Location  and  Trade  Theory  ....     207 

1  •  Prehminary  Remarks    207 

2  •  A  Fusion  of  Opportunity  Cost  Doctrine  and  Transport- 

orientation    208 

3  •  The  Effects  of  a  Change  in  the  Distance  Variable  upon  Trade, 

Industrial  Location,  and  Geographic  SpeciaHzation    215 

4  •  Some  Conclusions    219 

10  •  Aspects  of  General  Location  Theory  :  A  Mathematical  Formulation    221 

1  •  Weberian  Theory  Restated  and  Generalized    222 

2  •  Inclusion  of  Market  and  Supply  Areas  as  Variables    231 

3  •  The  Analysis  Extended  to  the  Case  of  Many  Producers    235 

4  •  Losch  Market  Area  Analysis  Encompassed    239 

5  •  Agriculture  Location  Theory  Embraced  and  GeneraUzed    243 

6  •  Concluding  Remarks    251 

11  •  Partial  Graphic  Synthesis  and  Summary 254 


List  of  Figures 


FIGURE  PAGE 

1  •  A  hypothetical  region.  4 

2  •  Communities  of  2500  or  more  inhabitants,  ranked  in  decreasing  order 

of  population  size.    U.S.A.  1790-1930.  56 

3  •  Frequency  distribution  of  cities,  at  shortest  distance  intervals,  by  size 

classes,  Iowa  1930.  59 

4  •  Railway  express.    Movement  by  weight  (less  than  carload  lots)  between 

13  arbitrary  cities  in  the  U.S.A.,  May  1939.  61 

5  •  Telephone  messages.     Number  of  messages  interchanged  between  311 

arbitrary  pairs  of  cities  in  the  U.S.A.,  1940.  62 

6  •  Bus  passengers.    Movement  of  persons  by  highway  bus  between  29  arbi- 

trary cities  in  the  U.S.A.  during  intervals  in  1933  and  1934.  63 

7  •  Family  migration.    Number  of  families  (plus  100)  moving  varying  dis- 

tances within  or  between  separated  areas  in  Cleveland,  1933-1935.  64 

8  •  Contours  of  equal  population  potential  for  the  United  States,  1940.  67 

9  •  Population  per  square   mile   and   dollar  value   of  selected  sustenance 

activities  per  1/100  sq  mile  of  hinterland,  by  distance  outward  from  the 
nearest  metropolis:  for  67  metropoHtan  communities  in  the  U.S.A., 
1939-1940.  69 

10  •  U.S.A.  Class  I  railroad  shipments.     Tonnage  of  all  commodities,  by 

distance  shipped  (25-mile  zones),  1949.    Bar  chart.  71 

11  •  U.S.A.  Class  I  railroad  shipments.     Tonnage  of  all  commodities,  by 

distance  shipped  (100-mile  zones),  1949.    Bar  chart.  72 

12  •  U.SA.  Class  I  railroad  shipments.     Tonnage  of  all  commodities,  by 

distance  shipped  (25-mile  zones),  1949.     Point  chart.  73 

xvii 


xviii  LIST  OF  FIGURES 

FIGURE  PAGE 

13  •  World   ocean-going  freight.     Tonnage,  by  distance  shipped    (500-mile 

zones),  1925.  74 

14  •  World  ocean-going  freight.     Tonnage,  by  distance  shipped  (2000-mile 

zones),  1925.  75 

15  •  A  locational  line.  96 

16  •  A  transformation  line  for  the  line  case.  97 

17  •  A  locational  triangle.  98 

18  •  A  transformation  line  for  the  triangle  case.  98 

19  •  A  four-sided  locational  polygon.  99 

20  •  A  transformation  line  for  a  four-sided  polygon.  100 

21  •  Locational  equilibrium:   discontinuous  transformation  line.  102 

22  •  Locational  equilibrium:  reahstic  rate  structures.  106 

23  •  Locational  equilibrium:  break  in  transport  system.  Ill 

24  •  Shift    of   transformation    curve    and    equilibrium   site    with  change    in 

weights.  114 

25  •  An  outlay-substitution  line  in  a  case  of  labor  orientation.  129 

26  •  A  revenue-outlay  substitution  line.  134 

27  •  Margin  hnes:  two  competitors.  149 

28  •  The  division  of  a  spatial  market:  two  competitors.  152 

29  •  The  division  of  a  market  among  several  supply  points.  156 

30  •  A  case  of  agglomeration  from  economies  of  scale.  173 

31  •  A  case  of  indeterminacy  in  location.  174 

32  •  Non-intersecting  critical  isodapanes:  no  agglomeration.  177 

33  •  Intersecting  critical  isodapanes:  agglomeration.  178 

34  •  Economies  of  scale  in  power  generation  with  urban  size.  184 

35  •  Hypothetical  economies  of  scale  with  urban  size.  187 

36  •  Price  and  cost  curves  of  an  agricultural  enterprise.  191 

37  •  Input  proportions,  scale,  and  equilibrium  for  an  agricultural  enterprise.     192 

38  •  Rent  functions  for  different  agricultural  land  uses.  195 

39  •  Variation  of  sales  with  distance  from  urban  core.  200 

40  •  Variation  of  cost  and  profit  with  volume  of  sales.  202 

41  •  Rent  functions  for  different  urban  land  uses.  203 

42  •  A  locational  triangle.  223 

43  •  Change  in  market  boundary  pattern  with  shift  of  production  points  in  a 

square  matrix.  241 

44  •  The  Launhardt-Palander  construction.                           '  256 

45  •  The  effects  of  a  weight  change.  258 

46  •  Division  of  a  market  region  between  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw 

materials.  261 

47  •  Spatial  production  patterns:  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw  materials, 

one  labor  location.  262 

48  •  Spatial  production  patterns:  scale  economies  introduced.  266 


LIST  OF  FIGURES  xix 

FIGURE  PAGE 

49  •  Spatial  production  patterns:  localization  and  scale  economies  introduced.  268 

50  •  Spatial  production  patterns:  urbanization,  localization,  and  scale  econo- 

mies introduced.  269 

51  •  A  simple  Losch  system  of  nets  of  market  areas.  270 

52  •  A  modified  Losch  system  consistent  with  resulting  population  distribu- 

tion. 272 

53  •  An  agricultural  land-use  pattern.  277 

54  •  An  urban  land-use  pattern.  279 

55  •  A  commodity  flow  pattern:  intranational  trade.  282 

56  •  A  commodity  flow  pattern:  international  trade.  284 

57  •  A  commodity  flow  pattern  with  modified  geographic  position  of  trading 

nations.  285 


Chapter 


Introduction: 

Posing  the  Location 

and  Regional  Problem 


In  this  chapter,  we  wish  to  paint  broadly  the  location  and  regional 
problem,  especially  for  the  reader  unacquainted  with  the  literature  and 
with  little  training  sympathetic  to  and  appreciative  of  the  spatial 
nature  of  social  phenomena.  We  shall  cast  the  discussion  against  a 
background  which  traces  the  evolution  of  an  area  and  shall  raise  certain 
key  questions.  In  a  final  section,  we  shall  consider  several  possible 
approaches  to  the  analysis  of  the  location  and  regional  problem,  i 

1.     Some  Basic  Development  Processes 

Broadly  speaking,  economic  evolution  stems  from  the  action  of  tech- 
nologic man  upon  the  elements  of  his  physical  environment.  On  the 
whole,  these  elements  are  passive,  most  of  them  changing  imperceptibly 
over  human  time.  However,  certain  changes  in  environmental  features, 
such  as  soil  erosion  or  silt  agglomeration  at  mouths  of  rivers,  do  in 
our  time  accumulate  to  a  critical  point  and  then  provoke  wholesale 
economic  and  social  adjustments.  These  relatively  few  instances  are 
the  exceptions  to  the  statement  that  the  dynamic  force  in  economic 
development  lies  in  the  activities  of  man  almost  to  the  point  of  exclu- 
sion. His  reaction  with  his  environment,  his  constant  modification 
of  the  restraints  and  scarcities  which  it  imposes,  and  his  incessant 

1  The  reader  is  reminded  that  this  chapter  serves  as  an  introduction  not  only  to 
this  volume  but  also  to  a  future  volume  on  the  principles  of  regional  science  and 
general  regional  theory. 


2  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

construction  of  techniques  which  revalue  resources  and  cause  certain 
natural  features  to  be  less  restrictive  and  others  more  spell  economic 
and  social  change  and  progress. 

Hence,  it  is  not  inappropriate  to  begin  with  a  framework  in  which 
natural  resources,  physical  configuration,  and  the  matrix  of  techno- 
logical conditions  are  given.  We  may  imagine  an  area  at  the  start 
isolated  from  other  areas  because  of  the  friction  of  physical  distance. 
Upon  this  area  of  varying  topography  and  uneven  resource  content 
settlement  takes  place. 

One  or  several  individuals  or  family  units  may  be  presumed  to  begin 
the  occupation.  The  selection  of  a  site  for  initial  habitation  and  cul- 
tivation of  crops  will  depend  on  a  host  of  factors.  These  include  the 
existing  vegetation  and  the  difficulties  of  clearing,  transport  resources, 
climate,  topography,  type  of  soil  and  nature  of  drainage,  the  available 
tools  and  techniques,  defense  considerations  and  the  cultural  inherit- 
ance of  the  individuals  and  family  units  which  in  any  given  instance 
sharply  defines  existing  knowledge  and  organizational  experience  and, 
thus,  the  horizon  of  possibilities.  But  also,  in  at  least  some  respects, 
the  selection  may  be  arbitraiy  and  indeterminate  in  terms  of  any 
ex  ante  rational  framework.  This  selection  may  be  subject  to  the 
whims  and  fancies  of  the  first  inhabitants  and  perhaps  to  a  particular 
series  of  historical  events.  And,  because  of  the  play  of  the  economic 
"irrational,"  the  first  site  of  settlement  may  be  later  abandoned  for 
another  not  bristling  with  so  many  hazards  and  rigors. 

Once  a  fairly  stable  adjustment  with  the  environment  is  attained, 
the  process  of  development  is  more  subject  to  predictive  analysis 
though  capricious  elements  remain  in  the  picture  exerting  influence  to 
varying  degrees.  As  more  individuals  and  family  units  come  to  inhabit 
the  area,  presumably  they  will  settle  in  close  vicinity  to  the  first.  The 
"gregarious  instinct,"  as  early  social  psychologists  were  prone  to  term 
it,  or,  more  accurately,  previously  acquired  behavior  patterns  would 
tend  to  foster  nucleation.  It  is  not  to  be  denied  that  where  individuals 
have  diverse  cultural  backgrounds  there  may  be  clash  and  dispersal 
rather  than  agglomeration,  or  that  idiosyncratic  elements  of  individual 
personalities  may  dominate  those  which  are  socially  and  culturally 
determined  and  thereby  induce  an  unpredictable  spatial  pattern  of 
settlement,  though  in  all  likelihood  a  more  unstable  one.  However, 
economic  forces  or,  more  specifically,  increasing  returns  from  co- 
operation in  combating  the  elements  when  population  numbers  are 
small,  operate  strongly  to  encourage  nucleation.  In  a  sense  these 
economic  forces  are  already  imbedded  in  an  existent  culture,  having 
previously  conditioned  the  emergence  of  particular  culture  traits  and 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM    3 

complexes  and  previously  influenced  the  dominant  interests  and  focal 
values  and  attitudes  to  which  a  given  cultural  pattern  is  oriented. 

In  any  case,  sooner  or  later  a  population  cluster  does  precipitate. 
What  is  its  internal  structure?  What  principles  govern  its  spatial 
configuration  and,  in  particular,  the  spatial  configuration  of  its 
economic  activities? 

For  a  society  which  engages  predominantly  in  agricultural  activities, 
the  conceptual  framework  developed  by  von  Thiinen  and  his  followers 
is  illuminating.  In  a  uniformly  fertile  plain  of  considerable  extent, 
which  is  undifferentiated  in  its  physical  features  and  isolated  from 
the  rest  of  the  world  and  which  contains  a  single  population  cluster 
at  some  distance  from  its  periphery,  cultivation  of  diverse  crops  and 
production  of  other  farm  commodities  will  tend  to  take  place  in 
concentric  zones  around  the  cluster  as  center.  To  each  zone  there 
will  correspond  a  particular  agricultural  product  or  combination  of 
products.  The  demand  for  the  various  products  by  the  given  popula- 
tion, the  effort  involved  in  transporting  a  unit  of  each  of  the  several 
products  over  any  unit  of  distance,  the  intensity  and  associated  cost 
at  which  a  unit  of  area  can  yield  each  product  or  combination  of 
products,  and  the  resulting  prices  or  barter  ratios  are  among  the 
various  factors  determining  in  which  zone  each  product  will  be 
produced.  The  relaxation  of  the  uniformity  assumptions  and  the 
introduction  of  realities  such  as  differentiation  in  ■  soil,  climate,  and 
topography  and  a  finite  number  of  transport  routes  in  general 
irregularly  placed  engender  serious  distortions  of  the  concentric 
pattern.  An  enclave  of  land  devoted  to  grazing  may  appear  in  a 
wheat-growing  zone  simply  because  the  topography  of  the  enclave 
precludes  any  other  activity.  In  an  area  stretching  along  a  transport 
route,  cultivation  of  land  may  be  much  more  intense  than  in  an  area 
closer  to  the  population  cluster  but  untapped  by  transport  media 
and  may  yield  entirely  different  crops.  In  short,  any  physical 
semblance  of  zonal  arrangement  may  be  completely  absent.  However, 
in  terms  of  time-cost  distance  and  in  terms  of  other  concepts  which 
would  give  explicit  recognition  to  areal  differentiation  with  respect  to 
significant  variables,  the  concentric  zonal  arrangement  would  remain 
undisturbed,  as  will  be  indicated  in  a  later  chapter. 

This  conception  of  competitive  equilibrium  in  land  use  is  at  least 
partially  refutable,  however,  because  of  its  static  nature.  As  already 
mentioned,  society  is  in  a  constant  state  of  disequilibrium,  continually 
striving  toward  a  condition  of  perfect  adjustment  but  just  as  per- 
sistently being  jarred  off  its  course  by  forces  of  change.  A  population 
nucleus  and  its  associated  hinterland  are  no  less  a  dynamic  organism. 


4  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

The  nucleus  typically  grows  in  size  from  an  initial  small  compact 
mass  reflecting  the  centripetal  drive  of  increasing  returns  to  a  larger 
and  larger  but  less  and  less  compressed  body,  at  times  even  sprawling 
seemingly  chaotic  and  without  coherence.  The  centrifugal  effects  of 
diminishing  returns  from  increasing  intensity  in  the  use  of  land  and 
the  mounting  diseconomies  and  congestion  from  multiplying  numbers 
become  manifest  in  the  growing  extent  of  the  spatial  spread.  At  the 
peripheries  of  each  of  the  zones  of  cultivation,  the  process  entails 
transition  from  one  type  of  land  use  to  another.  But  does  the  transi- 
tion take  place  smoothly  and  orderly  or  abruptly  and  haphazardly? 
Unquestionably,  cultural  values  and  institutions  condition  the  nature 


E 


X 


H     D 


Fig.  1.    A  hypothetical  region. 


of  the  transition.  But  just  as  certainly  economic  forces  are  at  work 
pressing  forward  the  succession  of  uses  to  which  a  given  piece  of 
land  is  subject  and  intensifying  its  exploitation.  But  how?  Unfor- 
tunately, little  is  known  and  can  be  said  about  this  dynamic  process. 

Imagine  before  the  nucleus  and  its  hinterland  have  reached  massive 
proportions  that  a  new  item  appears  in  the  food  basket  of  the 
inhabitants  of  the  city  which  we  shall  designate  as  point  A  (Fig.  1). 
Fish  are  found  to  abound  in  a  stream  some  days'  journey  from  A. 
Owing  to  previously  acquired  inclinations  or  to  initially  favourable 
reactions  and  a  non-resisting  set  of  social  attitudes  and  institutions, 
this  new  commodity  is  cumulatively  accepted  by  the  populace.  A  small 
colony  of  settlers  is  established  at  point  B  contiguous  to  the  stream. 
(See  Fig.  1.)     Since,  in  terms  of  the  best  known  transportation  means. 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM  5 

B  is  located  at  a  distance  of  several  days'  journey  from  A,  still  smaller 
colonies  are  established  at  C  and  D,  primarily  to  facilitate  the  process 
of  transportation  and  exchange  between  A  and  B  through  servicing 
the  porters  and  their  carriage  animals. 

The  phenomenon  of  geographic  specialization  among  separated  areas 
unevenly  endowed  with  resources  appears  in  full  flush.  Geographic 
specialization  per  se  is  not  a  new  phenomenon  as  it  has  already  been 
present  on  a  local  level.  Because  of  economies  of  scale,  individuals,  of 
necessity  residing  at  different  points  in  city  A,  have  come  to  specialize 
in  particular  activities.  The  specialization  in  the  cultivation  of  land 
differently  situated  with  respect  to  the  center  of  A  has  already  been 
alluded  to.  In  both  these  forms  of  local  specialization,  transport 
considerations  are  of  fundamental  importance.  Likewise,  the  critical 
significance  of  transport  cannot  be  denied  for  geographic  specialization 
among  separated  areas.  For  imagine  that  the  intervening  distance 
between  A  and  B  were  to  be  gradually  lengthened.  Transport  costs 
would  gradually  mount  and  reach  a  point  where  they  would  become 
intolerable.  Trade  and  specialization  between  A  and  B  would  gradually 
diminish  and  ultimately  cease.  Or,  imagine  the  opposite.  A  and  B  are 
gradually  brought  into  apposition.  Interareal  exchange  and  specializa- 
tion become  more  pronounced  as  the  resistance  of  intervening  distance 
declines. 

The  critical  significance  of  transport  considerations  is  indirect  as 
well  as  direct.  The  process  of  zone  formation  is  not  unique  to  A. 
Only  a  fraction  of  the  food  requirements  of  the  populace  of  B  will,  in 
general,  be  procured  in  exchange  for  fish.  Transport  costs  on  certain 
commodities  may  be  prohibitive  and  may  compel  the  cultivation  or 
production  of  these  commodities  in  the  immediate  hinterland  of  B.  A 
zonal  spatial  design,  distorted  by  peculiarities  of  topography,  soil 
characteristics,  and  a  host  of  other  factors,  emerges  around  B  as  the 
focus.  Clearly,  the  number  of  commodities  for  which  transport  costs 
will  be  judged  by  consumers  at  B  as  prohibitive,  the  number  of  persons 
engaged  in  fishing,  the  width  of  the  zones,  and  the  intensity  of  land 
use  about  B  are  interrelated  and  dependent,  too,  upon  distance  from 
A.  The  greater  the  intervening  distance,  in  general,  the  smaller  the 
trade  between  A  and  B,  the  fewer  who  ply  at  fishing,  and  the  higher 
the  degree  of  self-sufficiency  at  B.  But  the  effect  upon  the  spatial 
pattern  of  cultivation  at  B  is  not  subject  to  easy  perception.  It  is 
evident,  too,  that  because  the  magnitude  of  the  exchange  of  agricultural 
products  for  fish  is  related  to  intervening  distance,  the  amount  of 
agricultural  product  required  of  A's  hinterland  and  hence  its  zonal 
pattern  and  associated  intensity  of  land  use  will  also  be  affected  by 


6  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

intervening  distance.  This  distance  will  also  affect  the  amount  of 
servicing  activities  provided  by  C  and  D,  and  consequently  the 
character  of  their  hinterlands,  which  will  be  of  more  limited  extent 
than  those  of  A  and  B. 

As  trade  develops  pure  barter  arrangements  may  be  presumed  to  be 
displaced  by  the  introduction  of  a  medium  of  exchange  and  money 
prices.  We  do  not  purport  to  treat  at  length  here  or  elsewhere  the 
culture  complex  embodying  price  and  monetary  mechanisms,  broadly 
conceived.  However,  like  all  sets  of  associated  culture  traits,  it 
comprises  behavior  forms  which  have  evolved  consciously  or  uncon- 
sciously as  part  of  an  effort  to  achieve  directly  or  indirectly  a  more 
effective  adjustment  to  a  given  environment.  And  as  do  all  culture 
traits  and  sets  of  interrelated  culture  traits,  price  and  monetary 
mechanisms  condition  the  changes  in  cultural  forms,  complexes,  and 
patterns  which  transpire  as  a  society  evolves.  It  is  invalid,  then,  to 
take  the  position  that  price  and  monetary  phenomena  are  merely 
surface  manifestations  and  reflections  of  the  more  nearly  basic  and 
underlying  relations  and  interaictions  of  man  with  his  physical 
environment.  Price  systems  and  monetary  institutions  are  in  modern 
society  an  indispensable  set  of  cultural  tools,  which  are  inextricably 
interwoven  into  the  fabric  of  man's  culture  and  which  strongly  shape 
the  evolving  organizational  form  and  nature  of  man's  economic  and 
social  activities.  It  is  equally  invalid  to  assign  a  secondary  role  to 
the  geographic  distribution  of  resources,  topography  and  spatial 
position,  and  other  characteristics  of  environment  as  some  trade  and 
economic  theorists  are  inclined  to  do.  It  is  all  too  clear  from  the 
above  remarks  that  trade,  relative  and  absolute  spatial  position,  and 
the  geographic  pattern  of  resources  are  fundamentally  interrelated. 
Our  basic  position,  which  we  shall  reiterate  again  and  again,  is  that 
location  and  trade  are  as  the  two  sides  of  the  same  coin.  The  forces 
determining  one  simultaneously  determine  the  other.  To  understand 
and  anticipate  the  interaction  of  these  forces,  a  knowledge  of  resources, 
position,  topography,  and  other  environmental  characteristics  and  a 
knowledge  of  price,  exchange  control  and  monetary  mechanisms,  and 
other  cultural  institutions  and  behavior  complexes  and  patterns  are 
each  indispensable. 

Into  this  relatively  simple  frame  of  general  interdependence,  another 
element  of  change  may  be  injected.  Iron  ore  is  discovered.  Previously 
acquired  experience  or  successful  experimentation  with  iron  products 
leads  to  the  exploitation  of  the  iron  ore  deposits.  Deposits,  qualita- 
tively and  quantitatively  adequate,  are  found  to  exist  at  points  E,  F, 
and  G.    Since  charcoal  derived  from  timber  is  required  for  smelting 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM  7 

the  ore,  the  use  of  coal  being  infeasible  for  one  reason  or  another,  and 
since  timber  may  be  assumed  to  be  ubiquitous  in  this  early  stage  of 
development,  iron  will  tend  to  be  produced  at  E  and  G.  Working  of 
ore  close  to  markets,  scattered  over  an  area  according  to  the  scatter 
of  markets,  is  characteristic  at  this  stage,  provided  local  timber 
resources  and  supplies  of  water  and  water  power  suffice.  This  pattern 
minimizes  total  transport  costs  on  raw  materials  and  finished  products. 
Necessarily,  new  transport  routes  emerge,  interconnecting  E  and  A, 
and  G  and  B. 

The  iron  manufacture  sparks  an  incipient  industrialization.  The 
character  of  this  industrialization  is  markedly  different  from  that 
observable  in  modern  industrialized  societies.  The  agricultural 
stratum  serves  .  as  the  base  to  which  the  structure  of  industry  is 
oriented.  The  agricultural  stratum  provides  the  market  for  industrial 
products,  the  raw  materials  where  they  are  agricultural,  and  the  labor 
for  the  factories.  This  labor  frequently  is  available  only  seasonally 
or  secondarily  as  female  labor  and  thereby  immobile.  Additionally, 
the  agricultural  stratum  furnishes  the  food  and  drink  for  the  worker, 
which  frequently  exceeds  the  weight  of  the  raw  materials  used  by 
the  worker  combined  with  the  weight  of  the  finished  product  attributed 
to  his  effort.  This  condition  dictates  orientation  to  points  of  food 
supply.  Hence,  the  industrial  pattern  becomes  tied  to  and  reflects  the 
underlying  agricultural  stratum,  as  do  the  patterns  of  tertiary  and 
secondary  activities  for  related  reasons. 

Deviations,  however,  do  crop  up  as  when  indispensable  but  immobile 
and  highly  localized  mineral  resources  must  be  tapped.  More  impor- 
tant in  fostering  deviations,  and  in  nurturing  a  cumulatively  mounting 
emancipation  of  the  industrial  stratum  from  the  agricultural,  is  the 
increasing  productivity  stemming  from  improvements  in  technology. 
Technological  advance  revalues  resources  not  only  by  broadening  the 
horizon  of  materials  subject  to  transformation  and  by  multiplying 
production  possibilities  but  also  by  altering  the  strategy  of  diverse 
spatial  patterns  of  activities,  of  mineral  deposits,  and  of  transportation 
routes  through  changing  rates  of  output.  As  the  laborer  works  up 
greater  quantities  of  raw  materials  which  yield  larger  amounts  of 
finished  products,  while  simultaneously  his  consumption  of  food  and 
drink  at  most  rises  at  a  considerably  smaller  rate,  the  pull  of  the 
agricultural  stratum  is  attenuated  and  in  time  loses  its  dominance. 
Relocation  at  sites  of  mineral  reserves  and  at  new  critical  nodes  takes 
place.  Industry  severs  its  geographic  bonds  to  agriculture  and, 
concomitantly,  partially  binds  agriculture. 

As  an  instance,  posit  with  the  passage  of  decades  the  discovery  of 


8  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

an  excellent  bed  of  coking  coal  in  the  vicinity  of  F  and  the  acquisition 
of  crude  blast  furnace  techniques.  Compared  to  the  weight  of  food 
and  drink  of  the  worker  and  of  iron  ore  smelted  per  weight  unit  of 
manufactured  iron,  the  weight  of  coal  required  is  so  prodigious  as  to 
dictate  location  of  blast  furnaces  at  the  coal  site.  Major  industrializa- 
tion ensues  at  F  oriented  to  coal  resources  and  iron  manufacture.  A 
host  of  iron  and  steel  fabricating  activities,  of  heavy  fuel-consuming 
processes,  of  ancillary  by-product,  input-product,  and  service  func- 
tions, as  well  as  the  allied  subsidiary  operations  indirectly  induced 
or  required  to  support  the  flow  generated  by  the  basic  activities 
develops  in  juxtaposition,  each  activity  in  its  peculiar  way  attuned 
to  the  major  transport  and  agglomeration  economies  at  F.  The  rise 
of  F  signifies  drastic  changes  in  the  pattern  of  transport  routes  and 
commodity  movements,  and  the  emerging  steam-steel  complex  makes 
feasible  more  modern  transport  facilities.  A  superior  type  of  facility, 
more  suited  to  large-scale  movement  of  heavy  industrial  goods,  may 
be  presumed  to  be  constructed  to  connect  F  with  the  old  established 
transport  route  AB  at  H.  The  crossroads  position  of  H,  its  centrality 
as  well  as  the  probable  imbalance  of  traffic  and  thus  unutilized  trans- 
port capacity  in  certain  directions,  hastens  the  advent  and  growth  of 
new  enterprises  at  H. 

Realignment  of  agriculture  is  necessitated.  Zone  formation  proceeds 
about  F  and  H  while  the  configurations  of  cultivation  around  the  old 
foci  repattern  themselves  to  the  changing  geographic  structure  of 
industrial  and  household  demands.  More  commercialization  of  agri- 
culture and  greater  exchange  of  the  products  of  the  farm  for  those  of 
the  factory  take  place.  Dependence  of  agriculture  upon  industry 
mounts,  and  the  associated  problems  of  agricultural  prices,  output, 
and  income  emerge  and  grow  in  complexity. 

The  rise  of  F  and  H  spells  relative  and  perhaps  even  absolute 
decline  of  E  and  G,  and  C  and  D.  At  these  fading  cities,  workers  are 
displaced  at  their  iron-manufacture  and  transport-servicing  trades. 
Owing  to  established  modes  of  behavior  and  institutions  and  the 
occupational  and  geographic  immobilities  attached  thereto,  the  workers 
of  these  cities  form  a  pool  of  cheap,  downgraded  labor  upon  which 
parasitic  industry  may  draw.  Elsewhere,  socially  sanctioned  agricul- 
tural practices  deeply  rooted  in  folkways  and  community  structure  may 
resist  change.  A  resulting  inadequate  income  or  material  content  of 
living  may  impel  elements  of  the  agricultural  population  to  offer  their 
services  at  bargain  rates,  thereby  attracting  industry  that  has  no 
strong  inclination  to  locate  at  any  particular  site.  Additionally,  at 
F  and  H  where  heavy   basic   industry,   mining,  and  transport   can 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM  9 

utilize  effectively  the  labor  of  the  chief  breadwinner  only,  the  reserve 
of  surplus  women  and  child  labor  nurtures  the  growth  of  otherwise 
footloose  industry.  This  growth  of  footloose  activities  at  F  and  H, 
however,  is  not  independent  of  the  growth  of  such  activities  as  well 
as  basic  industry  and  agriculture  elsewhere.  It  takes  place  within 
a  system  of  activities  interdependent  spatially  and  industrially,  and 
only  against  such  a  system  as  background  can  it  be  fully  understood. 

2.     Some  Fundamental  Questions 

This  general  descriptive  analysis  of  the  evolutionary  course  of  an 
hypothetical  area  could  be  carried  forward  and  developed  extensively. 
To  proceed  thus,  however,  would  not  point  up  as  forcefully  as  we  should 
like:  (1)  certain  fundamental  location  and  regional  problems;  and 
(2)  the  need  for  the  general  type  of  theoretical  analysis  with  which 
this  book  is  concerned.  We  now  wish  to  focus  upon  these  problems 
and  this  need  by  posing  a  number  of  key  questions  which,  at  the 
same  time,  maintain  the  emphasis  on  the  spatial  order. 

For  example,  as  the  area  industrializes,  at  what  point  does  it  abandon 
the  phase  of  isolation  and  commence  trading  with  the  outside  world? 
Which  sites  develop  as  major  and  minor  ports?  In  what  commodities 
will  the  area  trade?  If  our  hypothetical  area  has  developed  late 
relative  to  other  regions  of  the  world,  it  may  at  the  beginning  of  trade 
export  agricultural  and  mineral  commodities  in  exchange  for  manu- 
factures. If  so,  does  its  general  composition  of  imports  and  exports 
change  toward  export  of  manufactures  and  import  of  raw  materials, 
food,  and  specialized  machinery  and  equipment  as  newer  areas  are 
brought  into  the  orbit  of  world  trade?  How  does  the  transition  from 
one  import-export  pattern  to  another  proceed?  If,  because  of  the 
conjunction  of  various  natural  factors,  cultural  forces  and  historical 
incidents,  P  emerges  as  a  dominant  port,  what  types  of  industry 
develop  at  P  and  how  much  of  each? 

With  further  economic  development,  a  diversified  transport  network 
evolves.  Internal  waterway  and  highway  projects  are  pushed  to 
completion;  pipelines  are  laid.  But  what  is  an  optimum  mix  and 
spatial  pattern  of  the  diverse  transport  facilities?  In  what  ways  is 
such  a  mix  or  pattern  conditioned  by  the  character  of  industrial  traffic 
generated  and  the  nature  of  intercommunity  and  intracommunity 
population  movement?  Should  any  government  subsidy  be  forth- 
coming? If  so,  how  should  it  be  distributed  among  the  several 
facilities  and  the  several  areas  and  between  current  and  capital 
expense? 
As  industrialization  proceeds,  problems  of  relocation  arise.     In  the 


10  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

initial  stages  of  heavy  manufacturing,  textiles  may  have  been  drawn 
to  F  because  of  the  location  there  of  excellent  coal  deposits  and  of  a 
reserve  of  women  and  child  labor  available  at  relatively  low  rates. 
With  time  a  heavy  concentration  of  textiles  may  have  developed  at  F, 
reflecting,  partially,  the  attraction  of  a  pool  of  skilled  labor  and, 
partially,  historical  inertia.  But,  as  the  force  of  innovation  presses 
the  spatial  structure  of  the  economy  and  its  parts  into  ever  new 
configurations,  the  strategy  of  existing  textile  sites  alters.  The  reserve 
of  low-cost  labor  at  these  textile  sites  may  have  become  depleted ;  what 
was  once  low-cost  labor  may  have  been  converted  into  high-cost  labor 
owing  to  the  continued  use  of  obsolete  equipment  and  processes.  Else- 
where, cheap  and  abundant  labor  incident  to  "cultural  lag"  and 
creeping  industrialization  and  urbanization  may  make  available 
savings  which  warrant  geographic  shift  despite  heavy  costs  of  reloca- 
tion. Resisting,  however,  is  the  force  of  historical  inertia,  a  force 
intimately  associated  with  the  cultural  variable.  A  critical  point  may 
exist  at  which  this  force  is  overcome.  But  exactly  how  does  this  point 
vary  with  the  institutional  environment?  Furthermore,  if  relocation 
is  expedient,  what  would  be  an  optimum  localization  pattern  of 
textiles?  What  distribution  among  regions?  How  large  the  factory? 
To  what  extent  can  a  textile  factory  serve  as  a  focal  point  for 
employment  in  an  esthetically  designed  "new  town"?  How  do  creative 
minds  generate  ideas  which  modify  accepted  ideals  and  values  which 
in  turn  form  the  scaffolding  within  which  decisions  are  made  by 
consumers,  and  political,  social,  and  business  leaders?  How  do  these 
creative  minds  condition  the  manner  in  which  the  spatial  structure 
yields  to  stresses  and  strains? 

The  problem  of  adjustment  to  change  in  the  relative  strength  of  the 
several  location  factors  may  be  raised  again  in  connection  with  iron 
and  steel  location.  Foreign  ores  become  accessible  while  concomitantly 
improvement  in  smelting  and  rolling  techniques  and  utilization  of 
a  swelling  supply  of  scrap  reduce  the  quantity  of  coal  spent  per  ton 
of  steel.  Should  a  major  integrated  iron  and  steel  works  be  established 
contiguous  to  the  port  P?  Or  should  the  manufacture  of  steel  at  P  be 
limited  to  the  operation  of  scrap  furnaces  only?  At  what  point  will 
the  pull  of  the  market  and  scrap  supplies  at  A  be  suflEicient  to  draw 
some  steel  capacity  to  A?  Does  the  relative  decline  of  steel  at  F  also 
imply  absolute  decline?  Furthermore,  how  do  competitive  ethics  and 
practices  and  institutional  pricing  arrangements,  whether  f.o.b.,  basing 
point,  or  some  other,  affect  the  process  of  locational  adaptation? 
Finally,  do  impending  new  techniques,  continuous  casting  for  example, 
spell  complete  decentralization  for  the  far  future? 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        11 

Intimately  associated  with  the  historic  shiftings  of  iron  and  steel 
location  are  the  dynamic  processes  of  the  urban-metropolitan  com- 
plexes at  P,  F,  H,  and  A.  Clearly,  the  magnitude  of  each  complex  is 
linked  to  its  content  of  such  basic  economic  activity  as  iron  and  steel. 
Spatial  realignment  of  such  activity  is  tantamount  to  reshuffling  of 
the  ranks  of  cities.  But  exactly  how  does  employment  in  any  particu- 
lar basic  activity  or  combination  of  basic  activities  generate  employ- 
ment in  non-basic  activities?  Why  does  the  ratio  of  non-basic  to  basic 
vary  from  city  to  city,  and  in  what  way  is  it  related  to  the  input 
structure  and  gravitational  impulse  of  a  particular  basic  activity? 
Can  a  meaningful  dynamic  structure  of  an  urban-metropolitan  complex 
be  constructed  and  depicted  in  terms  of  interactivity  relations? 

Additionally,  spatial  physiognomy  of  the  urban-metropolitan  region 
is  a  primary  concern.  Intensity  of  land  use  is  a  function  of,  among 
other  factors,  distance  from  the  core.  At  the  core  the  pyramiding  of 
activities  attains  a  maximum  maximorum.  With  movement  away 
along  radials  in  all  directions  the  intensity  of  land  use  diminishes,  but 
differentially  in  the  various  directions.  Moreover,  the  rate  at  which 
this  intensity  falls  in  any  direction  changes  with  distance.  In  addition, 
after  a  point  along  many  of  the  radials,  the  intensity  reaches  a  relative 
minimum,  reverses  its  trend  by  creeping  upward,  and  attains  a  relative 
maximum,  only  to  decline  again  and  perhaps  to  repeat  this  undulatory 
performance.  Along  a  few  of  the  radials,  generally  the  strategic  ones 
along  which  the  rate  of  decline  from  the  core  is  among  the  least  for 
all  radials,  relative  maxima  for  the  entire  metropolitan  region  are 
realized.  These  latter  represent  subfoci  from  which,  for  some  distance 
at  least,  intensity  falls  off  in  all  directions.  The  strategic  radials  also 
exercise  a  degree  of  dominance  to  the  extent  that,  in  directions 
perpendicular  to  their  course,  intensity  decreases. 

In  short,  an  urban-metropolitan  region  comes  to  comprise  an 
hierarchy  of  strategic  nodal  sites,  classifiable  by  order  and  degree  of 
dominance.  This  multinucleated  body  is,  viewed  from  another  angle, 
a  network  of  transport  interconnections  and  hence  of  interstitial  areas 
each  subject  to  hierarchical  order.  What  is  the  nature  of  the  ecological 
process  that  gives  rise  to  this  dynamic  organism?  How  do  (1)  the 
cost  relations  of  the  numerous  economic  activities,  (2)  the  spatial 
and  product  preferences  of  consumers,  of  familial  and  various  asso- 
ciational  units,  and  (3)  the  friction  of  distance  interact?  How  does 
progress  in  the  state  of  transport  technology,  which  in  turn  is  condi- 
tioned by  the  preferences  and  ideals  of  these  units,  impel  change  and 
rearrangement  of  centers  and  population  nuclei?  On  a  more  concrete 
level,  what  determines  the  use  to  which  any  given  piece  of  land  is  put? 


12  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Which  types  of  retail,  wholesale,  cultural,  governmental  and  adminis- 
trative, industrial,  and  service  activities  tend  to  appear  in  the  core 
and  in  each  of  the  several  types  of  subcenters  and  satellite  cities  in 
the  various  phases  of  urban-metropolitan  growth?  In  what  form  does 
specialization  among  the  several  metropolitan  regions  emerge?  Are 
there  forces  which  pervade  the  intrametropolitan  and  intermetropolitan 
structures  which  yield  stability  in  the  size  distribution  of  sites  and 
cities  as  a  whole,  even  though  there  is  constant  reshuffling  of  the  ranks 
of  individual  members  of  any  meaningfully  defined  population  of  sites 
and  cities?    Do  such  forces  deny  the  concept  of  an  optimum-size  city? 

For  our  hypothetical  region  these  questions  become  more  crucial 
with  time.  Impending  innovations,  such  as  aircraft  and  atomic  energy 
with  destructive  as  well  as  constructive  potential,  compel  a  recasting 
of  national  and  regional  values.  The  inherited  cultural  ideals  and 
productivity  sanctioning  and  extolling  the  cosmopolitan  life  in  peace- 
time must  be  weighed  against  the  suddenly  increased  risks,  whether 
calculated  or  imagined,  of  vulnerability  when  a  state  of  war  exists  or 
portends.  Policy  questions  concerning  urban  decentralization  arise. 
Intelligent  answers  to  these  questions,  however,  require  foresight  on 
the  probable  "normal"  effects  of  these  innovations.  To  such  effects 
we  first  turn. 

Environmental  barriers  deflect  the  path  of  growth  of  any  community, 
metropolitan  area,  or  regional  unit.  Physical  features,  however,  have 
critical  value  as  barriers  only  with  respect  to  a  given  or  assumed  state 
of  technology,  and  in  particular  of  transport  technology.  With  the 
advent  of  aircraft,  what  aspects  of  topography  lose  significance  as 
obstacles  to  the  movement  of  people,  ideas,  and  goods?  Which 
acquire  new  importance?  Will  any  new  trade  routes  and  major 
realignment  of  trade  patterns  develop?  Will  the  strategy  of  sites  for 
trading  activities  be  altered,  with  a  consequent  relative  decline  of  P? 
Will  the  emphasis  on  air  traffic  in  international  trade  provoke  the  rise 
of  new  centers  more  suitably  geared  to  such  traffic?  To  what  extent 
will  aircraft  find  widespread  use  in  industry  and  foster  increased 
productivity  and  new  location  patterns?  How  will  metropolitan 
structures  be  affected  both  indirectly  through  increased  effective 
demand  for  a  myriad  of  service  activities  made  possible  by  greater 
productivity  and  directly  through  increased  population  mobility 
inherent  in  the  use  of  family  aircraft?  What  should  be  the  position  of 
aircraft  in  a  diversified  transport  system,  and  to  what  degree  and  in 
what  manner  should  air  transport  be  subsidized? 

The  harnessing  of  atomic  energy  poses  somewhat  similar  questions. 
Will   nuclear   power   be    competitive   with    conventionally   produced 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        13 

power?  If  not,  will  a  given  society  deem  justifiable  the  allocation  of 
a  disproportionate  share  of  costs  to  the  military  to  encourage  active 
participation  by  private  enterprise  in  the  production  of  nuclear  power 
and  in  the  atomic  energy  industry  in  general,  and  hence  to  build  up 
and  maintain  skills  and  capacity  for  the  production  and  effective 
utilization  of  fissionable  materials?  Does  competitive  or  cheap  nuclear 
power  augur  for  our  hypothetical  area  the  emancipation  of  heavy 
industry  from  coal  belts,  the  dissolution  of  industrial  concentrations, 
and  a  wide  and  more  even  spread  of  economic  activities?  Or  will 
such  nuclear  power  alter  the  significance  of  merely  one  of  many 
location  factors  and  in  doing  so  modify  location  patterns  to  a  small 
degree  only,  even  to  the  extent  of  fostering  increased  industrial 
concentration  rather  than  diffusion  or  dispersion?  Will  a  host  of  new 
processes  and  industries  develop  concomitantly  to  yield  indirect  effects 
of  revolutionary  proportions?  Which,  if  any,  of  the  existing  industrial 
sectors,  including  the  public  utilities,  are  likely  to  become  obsolete 
in  whole  or  in  part?  What  may  be  the  impact  of  nuclear  power  upon 
other  regions  of  the  world  deficient  in  fuel  and  power  resources,  upon 
trading  relations  with  these  regions,  and  thus  indirectly  upon  the 
structure  of  our  hypothetical  space-economy? 

Tentative  answers  to  these  and  many  other  questions  are  required 
for  an  intelligent  approach  to  urban-metropolitan  and  industrial  de- 
centralization. A  program  of  decentralization  must  be  geared  to  the 
anticipated  future  geographic,  economic,  and  social  organization  of 
metropolitan  regions,  not  just  to  current  demands.  Decentralization 
policy  is  partially  "deviational"  policy,  a  policy  designed  to  accelerate 
certain  tendencies  and  strengthen  the  effectiveness  of  certain  forces, 
not  all  necessarily  centrifugal,  in  accordance  with  certain  values  judged 
to  be  in  the  interest  of  the  commonweal.  It  therefore  involves  insight 
into  processes  indicated  in  the  above  paragraphs,  which  are  subject 
to  a  fair  amount  of  objective  analysis.  It  also  involves  evaluation  of 
the  impact  of  innovation  upon  the  psychology  of  the  individual  and 
social  groups  and  requires  some  estimate  of  how  imagined  or  impend- 
ing military  applications  of  such  innovations  as  aircraft  and  atomic 
energy  ultimately  affect  individual  and  group  space  preferences.  These 
questions,  like  a  host  of  others  of  similar  stamp,  are  subject  to 
considerably  less  objective  analysis. 

Identification  of  meaningful  sectors  of  the  metropolitan  region  which 
should  be  dissected  from  the  urban  mass  and  located  elsewhere, 
whether  in  the  periphery  or  in  more  distant  districts,  is  not  unlike 
some  of  the  age-old  problems  of  regional  resource  use  and  conservation. 
A  meaningful  sector  is  not  necessarily,  and  perhaps  only  infrequently. 


14  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

a  wedge  of  activities  contiguous  in  space.  It  is  a  complex  of  activities 
where  association  leads  to  definite  agglomeration  economies,  but  where, 
subject  to  certain  restraints,  presence  of  these  activities  within  a 
Greater  Metropolitan  Region  in  any  of  many  possible  patterns  of 
scatter  and  concentration  may  more  often  than  not  satisfy  the  spatial 
associational  requirement.  Hence,  contiguity  in  physical  space  is  only 
one  of  several  constraining  factors  each  of  which  is  critical  in  the 
determination  of  some  of  the  several  combinations  of  activities  which 
comprise  meaningful  sectors  for  decentralization  purposes.  Other 
restraints  bear  upon  such  matters  as  the  volume  and  time-pattern  of 
demand  for  transportation  and  diverse  utility  services,  the  structure 
of  labor  requirements  by  occupation  and  other  characteristics,  and 
the  interrelations  of  activities  in  terms  of  stages  of  production,  by- 
product use,  and  input-output  functions.  Yet,  given  a  knowledge  of 
the  types  of  restraints  operative  and  even  detailed  information  about 
the  nature  of  some,  how  evaluate  the  net  interaction  of  different  groups 
of  them  under  different  sets  of  circumstances  in  order  to  identify  and 
effectively  to  carve  out  sectors  from  the  metropolitan  region? 

Correlatively,  how  achieve  a  satisfactory  geographic  balance  in  our 
hypothetical  region  if  the  pattern  of  activity  is  adjudged  too  con- 
centrated and  vulnerable  in  certain  sections,  for  example,  along  the 
industrial  band  which  stretches  from  A  to  H  and  H  to  Fl  Put  other- 
wise, how  plan  the  long-run  utilization  and  conservation  of  resources 
in  the  entire  region,  weighing  the  economic  desirability  of  each  de- 
velopment design  against  its  military,  political,  and  other  virtues  and 
limitations.  Guiding  new  growth  along  certain  channels  and  in  specific 
parts  of  the  region  is  one  expedient  for  achieving  a  redistribution  of 
activity.  Some  costly  relocation  of  other  activities  may  be  justifiable. 
More  significant,  an  entire  set  of  activities  located  within  an  industrial 
band  may  be  subject  to  decentralization  as  an  integral  unit,  when 
decentralization  of  the  activities  individually  would  be,  from  an 
economic  standpoint,  highly  irrational  because:  (1)  they  feed  inputs 
into  each  other  and  utilize  each  other's  by-products,  (2)  together  they 
can  maintain  the  high  quality  transport  service  which  each  requires, 
(3)  together  their  labor  forces  form  a  substantial  pool  of  diversified 
skills,  the  existence  of  which  is  a  sine  qua  non  for  each,  (4)  together 
their  combined  demand  for  diverse  urban  and  professional  services  is 
of  such  a  magnitude  as  to  insure  efficient  performance  at  relatively 
low  cost,  and  (5)  their  combined  labor  force  constitutes  a  market  for 
consumer  products  of  such  a  scale  as  to  restrict  the  cost  of  living  and 
hence  money  wages  to  moderate,  if  not  low,  bounds.  To  ascertain  each 
of  these  sets  of  activities  where  the  force  of  historical  inertia  binds 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        15 

location  to  original  or  old  sites  of  development,  where  relocation  in 
the  small  is  precluded  but  where  relocation  in  the  large  can  be  eco- 
nomically sanctioned  is,  to  reiterate,  a  difficult  problem.  To  attack 
this  problem,  and,  more  generally,  to  fonxiulate  effective  governmental 
policy  for  decentralization  and  for  the  long-run  planning  of  resource 
development  to  achieve  an  optimum  geographic  distribution  of  activi- 
ties, requires  full  utilization  of  all  the  existing  skills  of  social  scientists. 
And,  more  important,  it  requires  continued  and,  if  possible,  accelerated 
progress  in  the  social  sciences  in  the  fashioning  of  new  tools  and  tech- 
niques for  analyzing  the  interdependence  of  the  various  sectors  of  the 
space-economy,  and  hence  the  net  effects  of  certain  specified  changes. 

3.     Possible  Theoretical  Approaches 2 

Having  posed  a  host  of  key  questions,  w^e  must  confess  to  an  inability 
to  provide  even  partial  answers.  Our  intention,  as  stated  earlier,  is 
to  p6int  up  the  need  for  the  general  type  of  theoretical  and  empirical 
analysis  with  which  the  remainder  of  this  book  is  concerned.  What 
follow^s  is  a  modest  attempt  to  depict  and  understand  some  of  the 
basic  spatial  interrelations  which  underlie  the  location  of  economic 
activities  and  regional  development. 

Various  approaches  were  possible  in  undertaking  this  assignment. 
Several  are  recorded  in  the  event  that  future  students  of  location  and 
regional  development  may  find'  them  of  some  use.  One  obvious 
approach  toward  a  more  general  theory  would  involve  amassing  new 
and  reinterpreting  existing  historical  material — to  a  very  limited  extent 
along  the  lines  of  Roscher,  Schaffle,  Ritschl,  Weber,  and  Englander — 
to  a  very  significant  extent  along  the  paths  explored  by  Dean  and 
Usher.  (The  von  Thiinen  framew^ork  for  agricultural  location  would 
be  of  critical  value  here  for  understanding  initial  stages  of  develop- 
ment.) Unquestionably,  historical  generalizations,  more  comprehensive 
and  at  the  same  time  more  incisive  than  those  we  now  possess,  can 
be  achieved  in  the  study  of  the  past  and  current  spatial  and  regional 
structure  of  the  world  economy  and  its  various  sectors. 

A  second  approach  might  begin  with  the  pure  abstractions  of  Losch. 
These  are  presented  at  some  length  in  the  following  chapter.  Cannot 
one  further  pursue  these  abstractions  with  profit  as  Losch  does  to 
some  extent?  Imagine  one  relaxes  the  assumption  of  uniform  popula- 
tion scatter,  an  assumption  which  is  inconsistent  with  the  derived 

2  This  section  is  written  primarily  for  the  research  worker.  It  assumes  a  knowl- 
edge of  the  works  and  approaches  of  the  several  individuals  cited.  The  contribu- 
tions of  these  individuals  are  at  best  only  partially  recorded  in  the  following 
chapters. 


16  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

results  which  yield  cities  and  towns  of  diverse  sizes.  Further,  one 
can  introduce  geographic  inequalities  in  endowment  of  resources  of 
all  kinds,  differences  in  consumers'  space  preferences,  a  finite  number 
of  transport  routes  reflecting  high  fixed  costs  and  economies  of  scale, 
and  a  number  of  other  restraints  which  permit  a  closer  correspondence 
to  actual  conditions.  Could  not  a  more  meaningful  system  of  nets 
and  hierarchy  of  sites  be  depicted?  Since  the  character,  magnitude, 
and  direction  of  trade  among  all  sites  are  functionally  related  to  the 
nature  of  the  postulates  underlying  one's  abstractions,  would  not  a 
more  realistic  trade  pattern  be  yielded?  Furthermore,  the  Loschian 
framework,  which  has  most  relevance  for  market-oriented  processes 
and  service  functions  which  use  ubiquitous  raw  materials  or  none  at 
all,  may  be  extended  to  incorporate  agricultural  activities.  About 
each  population  cluster,  whatever  its  size,  zones  of  cultivation 
tend  to  develop  a  la  Thiinen  though  within  a  complex  web  of 
interrelations  about  which  some  remarks  will  be  made  in  the  following 
paragraphs. 

Another  approach  might  rather  build  upon  Thiinen's  model  with 
extensions  at  later  stages  to  encompass  the  significant  elements  of 
Loschian  and  Weberian  theory.  Imagine  two  isolated  city  regions, 
each  region  comprising  the  central  city  and  its  surrounding  hinterland 
devoted  to  agriculture  and  forestry.  With  the  development  of  transport 
technology  we  may  suppose  that  resistance  imposed  on  movement  by 
topographic  obstacles  and  by  the  sheer  friction  of  distance  is  gradually 
reduced.  This  change,  as  well  as  growth  in  population  numbers,  will 
induce  an  increase  in  the  consumption  of  various  agricultural  and 
forest  products  and  perhaps  also  in  the  types  of  products  available. 
A  new  equilibrium  arrangement  of  expanded  zones  will,  after  a  sufficient 
lapse  of  time,  be  established  for  each  city  region  although,  as  we  have 
already  indicated,  little  is  known  about  the  dynamic  process  of 
transition  from  one  equilibrium  pattern  to  another,  a  process  which  is 
intimately  linked  with  cultural  values  and  institutional  modes  of 
behavior.  In  time,  and  under  the  assumption  that  resources  are  uni- 
formly and  equally  distributed  among  the  city  regions,  the  hinterlands 
of  these  two  isolated  city  regions  may  have  expanded  to  such  a  degree 
that  their  outer  boundaries  become  tangent  or  coincide  along  a  certain 
stretch.  Nonetheless,  the  hinterlands  do  not  overlap  and  still  can 
be  rigorously  defined.  However,  the  symmetrical  concentric  zonal 
arrangement  about  each  city  is  disturbed  although  in  a  systematic, 
identifiable  manner.  The  introduction  of  a  third,  a  fourth,  and  finally 
an  nth  city  region  merely  adds  to  the  complexity  of  the  resulting 
design.    It  does  not  entail  any  overlapping  of  hinterlands  or  any  less 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        17 

rigor  in  their  demarcation  using  standard  Thiinen  principles,  to  be 
discussed  in  a  later  chapter. 

The  schema  of  a  space-economy  composed  of  many  city-regions  with 
some  hinterlands  bordering  on  each  other  for  limited  stretches,  and 
without  interregional  trade,  is  subject  to  considerable  improvement. 
Recognition  of  relations  which  Ohlin  and  Losch  have  emphasized — 
namely,  the  force  of  concentration  of  production  imbedded  in  economies 
of  scale  and  the  force  of  scatter  of  production  engendered  by  the 
cost  of  transportation — immediately  lays  the  basis  for  trade.  Return- 
ing for  the  moment  to  the  fiction  of  two  city-regions,  we  may  recognize 
that  not  all  commodities  produced  are  agricultural  and  forest,  that 
some  commodities  are  services  to  be  performed  at  central  places,  and 
that  others  are  associated  with  market-oriented  production  processes 
which  currently  we  may  postulate  use  only  ubiquitous  raw  materials. 
Each  of  the  commodities  belonging  in  these  latter  two  sets  may  be 
classified  as  to  the  size  of  market  area  most  economical  for  its  produc- 
tion. Some  may  be  produced  and  distributed  most  efficiently  when 
one  factory  serves  both  city-regions.  These  commodities  may  be 
classified  as  supraregional  and  national.  Others  may  be  produced  and 
distributed  most  efficiently  when  two  factories  operate,  one  located  in 
each  city,  each  serving  consumers  in  its  corresponding  city-region. 
These  may  be  classified  as  regional.  Still  others  may  be  most  efficiently 
produced  and  distributed  when  they  are  produced  in  many  factories, 
symmetrically  located  within  the  combined  area  of  the  city-regions. 
The  commodities  these  factories  produce  may  be  considered  sub- 
regional;  and  since  their  sites  of  production  to  a  large  extent  lie  outside 
the  core  of  the  two  main  cities,  they  give  rise  to  new  central  function 
sites.  As  these  sites  come  to  represent  population  nuclei,  effective 
demand  for  agricultural  products  gives  rise  to  zone  formations  at 
each  of  them. 

In  sum,  superimposing  a  Loschian  framework  upon  a  Thiinen 
arrangement  leads  to  an  hierarchical  pattern  of  sites  within  each  city- 
region  and  generates  interregional  as  well  as  increased  intraregional 
trade.  Confining  attention  to  only  two  city-regions  raises  the  basic 
question:  Which  of  the  two  serves  as  the  site  for  producing  supra- 
regional  and  national  commodities,  or  does  a  new  intermediate  city 
emerge  as  the  site  for  producing  such  commodities?  Historical  evidence 
would  seem  to  favor  the  hypothesis  that  one  of  the  two  existing  cities 
usurp  national  commodity  production.  This  tends  to  spell  relative 
decline  for  the  other.  The  latter  tends,  as  a  consequence,  to  expand 
its  output  of  agricultural  products  (and  hence  its  hinterland)  in  order 
to  provide  the  wherewithal  to  purchase   supplies  of  national   com- 


18  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

modities  from  the  former.  This  condition  in  turn  entails  relative 
contraction  of  the  agricultural  supply  hinterland  of  the  former  and 
specialization  among  the  city-regions.  However,  it  should  be  borne 
in  mind  that  there  may  be  decided  transport  advantage  to  an  inter- 
mediate location  and  that,  where  there  are  a  sufficient  number  of 
national  commodities,  a  major  shift  to  an  intermediate  location  may 
take  place.  This  shift  may  involve  either  a  simultaneous  relocation 
of  many  producers  or  a  gradual  transition  whereby  a  one-by-one 
sequence  of  relocations  is  experienced. 

To  pursue  this  interesting  two  city-region  schema  in  greater  detail 
is  outside  the  scope  of  this  book.  More  relevant,  but  still  beyond 
our  defined  bounds,  would  be  a  multicity-region  construct,  resulting 
again  from  both  population  growth  and  advance  in  transport  tech- 
nology. Here,  more  determinacy  is  likely  to  be  present.  The  city- 
region  central  to  all  is,  from  the  transport  standpoint,  the  ideal  location 
for  national  commodity  production.  It  tends  to  specialize  in  these 
commodities  while  on  balance  the  remaining  city-regions  tend  to 
specialize  in  agriculture;  necessarily  this  specialization  involves  zonal 
adaptations.  At  the  same  time,  there  may  be  subnational  commodities 
which  are  also  supraregional.  The  existence  of  such  commodities 
generates  a  still  gTeater  hierarchical  arrangement  of  city-regions. 

Hitherto,  the  postulate  that  resources  are  uniformly  and  equally 
distributed  among  city-regions  has  been  maintained.  Let  this  postu- 
late be  relaxed;  let  us  return  to  the  simple  two  city-region  schema 
where  both  regions  are  initially  isolated  from  the  rest  of  the  world 
and  from  one  another.  In  time,  as  there  is  advance  in  transport 
technology  and  increase  in  population  numbers,  trade  may  well  take 
place  before  the  hinterlands  have  expanded  so  as  to  be  contiguous 
with  one  another  over  some  stretch.  There  may  be  partial  or  even 
complete  specialization  in  the  production  of  various  agricultural  prod- 
ucts, each  city-region  supplying  to  the  other  crops  for  whose  produc- 
tion it  is  most  suited  by  reason  of  its  resources.  Upon  this  improved 
Thiinen  arrangement,  which  should  also  be  expanded  to  embrace  many 
city-regions,  a  Loschian  framework  may  be  superimposed  to  inject 
into  the  analysis  service  activities  and  ubiquitous  raw-material-using, 
market-oriented  production  processes.  Once  again,  a  hierarchical 
arrangement  of  cities  and  towns  evolves,  with  consequent  major  altera- 
tions in  zonal  patterns.  A  more  realistic  portrayal  of  a  space-economy 
results. 

However,  the  analysis  of  the  space-economy  can  be  further  improved. 
Relaxing  the  assumption  of  uniform  and  equal  resource  distribution 
allows  one  to  take  into  account  basic  production  processes  (for  example. 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        19 

steel,  aluminum,  and  chemicals)  which  use  raw  materials  which  are 
localized  in  varying  degrees  (for  example,  coal,  ores,  and  hydropower). 
Here  the  Weberian  type  of  analysis  can  be  added  to  the  derived 
Thiinen-Loschian  model.  Consideration  of  transport  costs  (as  they 
are  related  to  weight  loss,  relative  weights,  relative  positions,  and 
rate  structure) ,  of  labor  costs  and  other  costs,  and  of  agglomeration 
and  deglomeration  economies  is  required.  New  sites  of  production 
and  cities  may  emerge,  to  be  added  to  the  Thiinen-Loschian  hierarchy; 
and  of  the  existing  cities,  some  may  grow  while  others  decline.  The 
spatial  pattern  of  agricultural  production  and  of  service  and  market- 
oriented  activities  based  on  ubiquitous  raw  materials  will  con- 
comitantly undergo  change,  particularly  where  strong  local  multiplier 
effects  are  associated  with  basic  industry  (reflecting  partially  agglom- 
eration effects)  .3 

In  short,  the  development  of  a  combined  Thiinen-Loschian-Weberian 
framework  along  channels  suggested  above  and  elsewhere  in  this  book 
represents  another  approach  toward  achieving  a  general  theory  of 
location  and  space-economy  and  toward  a  more  thorough  understand- 
ing of  the  interrelations  of  the  space-economy.  •* 

A  fourth  approach  might  proceed  through  entirely  different  channels. 
Imagine  there  exists  only  one  non-agricultural,  non-service  production 

3  To  be  specific,  imagine  that  in  the  Thiinen-Loschian  framework  a  steel  plant, 
using  locaUzed  ore  and  coal,  is  introduced.  Since  steel  production  on  the  whole 
tends  to  be  transport-oriented,  the  steel  plant  may  or  may  not  be  located  in  an 
existing  city.  If  the  point  of  minimum  transport  cost  for  steel  production  does 
not  coincide  with  or  lie  close  to  an  existing  city,  a  new  city  tends  to  arise  especially 
since  steel  production  is  an  agglomeration-inducing  type  of  activity.  It  is  easily 
seen  how  service  and  agricultural  activities  in  city-regions  close  by  are  directty 
affected,  and  more  remote  city-regions  are  indirectly  affected.  Likewise,  that  there 
are  important  direct  and  indirect  repercussions  when  the  optimal  transport  point 
for  steel  production  coincides  with  an  existing  city  is  easily  perceived. 

4  The  above  approach  takes  into  account  a  steady  advance  in  the  state  of  trans- 
port technology  and  a  gradual  reduction  in  resistances  to  and  costs  of  movement. 
A  variant  of  this  approach  would  start  at  the  other  extreme.  Transport  costs  are 
assumed  zero.  A  corresponding  spatial  pattern  of  economic  activities  is  derived. 
By  degrees,  transport  costs  are  permitted  to  rise,  approaching  more  and  more  the 
levels  of  reality.  For  a  while,  at  least,  inequalities  of  human  and  natural  resources 
become  more  and  more  critical.  The  previous  spatial  pattern  related  to  consumer 
and  social  group  space  preferences  increasingly  takes  on  an  economic  hue.  An 
hierarchy  of  sites,  of  trade  routes,  and  of  flow  phenomena  in  general  develops,  as 
well  as  zone  formations  and  industrial  agglomerations  at  strategic  mineral  and 
nodal  sites.  Ultimately,  as  transport  costs  rise  to  exorbitant  levels,  the  hierarchy 
disappears,  as  does  interregional  trade,  and  the  hypothetical  isolated  city-regions 
of  Thiinen  are  attained. 

In  this  Thiinen-Loschian- Weberian  approach  and  its  variant,  the  effects  of  tariff 
barriers,  exchange  rate  and  balance  of  payments  considerations,  central  banking 


20  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

process  which  involves  only  a  single  stage.  Its  location  will  be 
associated  with  a  population  cluster.  Either  it  is  a  market-oriented 
operation  and,  hence,  drawn  to  an  agricultural  and  related  service 
population  nucleus,  or  it  is  an  operation  which  is  tied  to  a  raw 
material  source  and  which,  hence,  binds  a  population  cluster  composed 
of  the  families  of  its  labor  force  and  of  the  labor  force  of  allied 
service  activities.  Associated,  too,  with  the  latter  population  cluster 
will  be  a  farming  population,  but  one  which  does  not  need  to  be  in 
the  immediate  environs  owing  to  the  possibility  of  engaging  in  long- 
distance (interregional)  trade. 

Consider  an  advance  in  technology  which  permits  the  production 
of  the  identical  product  at  lower  cost,  but  by  a  two-stage  process. 
Both  stages  may  be  carried  on  at  a  market  site  or  at  a  raw  material 
site.  But  also  the  production  process  may  be  split  geographically, 
the  earlier  stage  being  linked  to  the  raw  material  site,  the  later  stage 
to  the  market.  Another  type  of  long-distance  (interregional)  flow 
phenomenon  may  be  observed,  namely,  the  movement  of  semifinished 
manufactures  in  exchange  for  finished  products.  History  records  that 
in  time  such  a  flow  phenomenon  appears  as  a  region  develops.  But 
what  are  the  conditions  that  the  process  be  split  geographically  and, 
hence,  that  such  a  flow  phenomenon  exists?  Are  these  conditions 
similar  to  the  conditions  for  long-distance  (interregional)  trade  in 
finished  products?  Cannot  the  conditions  for  both  these  types  of 
flow  phenomenon  be  expressed  in  terms  of  common  concepts  and 
principles? 

Permit  the  economy  to  become  still  more  complex.  Technological 
advance  compels,  through  making  possible  significant  cost  savings, 
the  shift  to  a  three-stage,  to  a  four-stage,  and  finally  to  an  n-stage 
production  process.  Again,  what  are  the  conditions  that  the  process 
be  split  geographically  and  among  more  than  two  sites  when  more 
than  one  raw  material  is  utilized?  The  statement  of  these  conditions 
should  involve  merely  a  further  generalization  of  a  common  set  of 
principles. 

Pursue  the  generalization  further.  Allow  the  production  by  a  single- 
stage  process  of  another  industrial  commodity.  AVhat  determines  the 
location  of  such  production?  In  addition  to  the  factors  which  were 
relevant  for  the  first  industrial  commodity,  linkage  relations  between 
the  two  industrial  commodities  must  be  considered.     Location  at  a 

and  monetary  institutions,  obstacles  to  immigration  and  labor  mobility,  and  vari- 
ous other  political  and  social  frictions  and  policies  should  be  investigated  to  obtain 
a  still  better  understanding  of  the  space-economy  of  reality  and  in  particular  of 
international  trade. 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        21 

site  of  one  of  the  raw  materials  utilized  in  the  manufacture  of  the 
first  industrial  commodity,  at  any  intermediate  point  at  which  a 
stage  in  such  manufacture  may  have  become  situated  as  well  as  at 
the  market,  at  a  site  of  a  raw  material  consumed  in  the  production 
of  the  second  industrial  commodity,  or  at  other  relevant  intermediate 
points  must  be  investigated.  The  appearance  of  agglomeration 
economies  may  alter  the  spatial  configuration  simply  derived  by  super- 
imposing upon  the  location  pattern  of  the  first,  the  location  pattern 
of  the  second  industrial  commodity  which  would  have  obtained  in 
the  absence  of  production  of  the  first.  As  already  intimated,  additive 
procedures  are  insufficient.  But  how  evaluate  the  effect  of  agglomera- 
tion?   What  are  the  principles  which  relate  these  forces  to  others? 

In  response  to  successive  technological  advances,  the  production 
of  the  second  industrial  commodity  is  performed  in  two  stages,  three 
stages,  and  finally  n  stages.  Should  not  the  identical  principles  apply 
to  the  spatial  affinities  of  one  or  more  stages  of  one  production  process 
as  to  one  or  more  stages  of  the  other?  Further  introduce  more  in- 
dustrial commodities  each  produced  in  one  or  more  stages.  Can  these 
principles  be  as  extensively  generalized?  Moreover,  since  these  prin- 
ciples relate  the  location  of  any  one  stage  of  a  production  process  to 
the  location  of  the  next  stage  or  the  consumer  (industrial  or  house- 
hold), should  not  these  same  principles  simultaneously  govern  flow 
phenomena  in  the  postulated  model  and,  hence,  all  trade? 

Why  consider  industrial  commodities  singly?  Slicing  the  economy 
by  individual  industrial  commodities  represents  an  extreme  of  indus- 
trial disaggregation.  For  certain  purposes  a  more  aggregative  analysis 
in  terms  of  groups  may  be  more  useful.  For  example,  a  somewhat 
less  disaggregated  classification  such  as  a  fine  Leontief-type  break- 
down may  be  more  expedient  for  purposes  of  operation.  At  the  other 
extreme,  the  highly  aggregative  Colin  Clark  classification  of  primary, 
secondary,  and  tertiary,  or  a  fourfold  classification  of  heavy  industry, 
light  industry,  agriculture,  and  trade  and  services  may  be  more 
appropriate  in  other  instances.  Could  not  the  previously  derived 
principles  be  restated  to  be  valid  for  groups,  the  nature  of  the  re- 
formulation being  dependent  upon  the  degree  and  manner  of  aggrega- 
tion? Could  these  principles  be  extended,  though  at  best  only  partially, 
to  encompass  the  effects  upon  the  spatial  industrial  pattern  of  different 
types  of  pricing  policies  and  institutional  business  ties,  different  geo- 
graphic patterns  of  income  distribution,  different  kinds  of  space 
preferences  of  individual  household  consumers  and  diverse  types  of 
aggregates  of  household  consumers,  and  like  factors? 

The  framework  may  even  be  extended  to  consider  interrelations  of 


22  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

large  regions.  We  have  alluded  to  long-distance  trade  as  interregional. 
Recognizing  that  an  hierarchy  of  regions  exists,  we  may  conceive  at 
the  start  of  this  long-distance  (interregional)  trade  as  taking  place 
among  the  smaller  regions  of  one  large  major  region,  but  not  as 
occurring  beyond  the  bounds  of  a  large  major  region.  Thus,  it  is 
possible  to  have  a  construct  of  several  large  major  regions,  each 
initially  isolated  from  the  other,  but  each  experiencing  its  own  variety 
of  internal  development  which  is  subject,  however,  to  explanation 
in  terms  of  a  common  set  of  general  principles. 

Of  the  several  large  regions,  consider  two  neighboring  ones.  One 
may  possess,  relative  to  existing  technology,  abundant  mineral  resources 
and  niggardly  amounts  of  agricultural  resources.  In  the  other,  the 
opposite  situation  may  obtain.  (It  is  clear  that,  ceteris  paribus,  in 
one  region  the  character  of  development  will  be  more  industrial  in 
the  other  more  agricultural.)  Let  there  be  progress  in  transport  tech- 
niques such  that  the  geographic  barriers  to  commodity  movement  are 
reduced  sufficiently  to  permit  intercourse.  The  pattern  of  geographic 
specialization  in  each  large  region  changes.  Industry  shifts  from  one 
region  to  the  other  with  concomitant  increases  in  productivity,  gross 
output,  and  degree  of  specialization.  Trade  internal  to  each  large 
region  likewise  changes,  and  an  hierarchical  order  of  trade  relations 
develops.  As  further  transport  advances  permit  the  introduction  of 
a  third,  fourth,  and  finally  an  nth  large  region  into  the  circle  of  inter- 
relations, further  changes  ensue,  each  functionally  dependent  upon  the 
state  of  transport  technology  and  level  of  transport  costs.  To  under- 
stand the  resulting  spatial  phenomena,  notwithstanding  their  com- 
plexity, could  not  the  same  common  set  of  general  principles,  somewhat 
adapted  and  extended  here  and  there,  be  invoked?  Does  not  the 
introduction  of  hierarchical  relations  merely  add  complexity  to  the 
statement  of  these  principles,  and  not  basic  change? 

With  the  raising  of  these  questions  the  discussion  of  the  fourth  type 
of  approach  to  a  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy  is 
concluded.  The  recently  developed  approaches  of  Vining,  who  places 
emphasis  on  the  search  for  distributional  stability  characteristics 
among  spatial  flow  phenomena,  and  of  Koopmans  and  others,  whose 
primary  attack  is  upon  the  transportation  problem,  are  other  fruitful 
ones.  Several  other  approaches  associated  with  the  older  location 
literature  will  be  discussed  at  length  in  the  following  chapter.  Still 
another  approach,  a  variant  of  the  fourth,  might  start  with  individual 
persons  rather  than  with  individual  production  processes.  The  spatial 
preference  of  each  person,  both  as  a  consuming  unit  and  as  an  income- 
earning  unit,  would  be  considered.     Aggregating  individuals  to  form 


POSING  THE  LOCATION  AND  REGIONAL  PROBLEM        23 

meaningful  social  and  economic  groups  would  introduce  group  space 
preferences,  which  in  turn  would  affect  the  geographic  association  of 
employment  opportunities,  and  thus  industrial  location  and  trade. 
Optimal  spatial  patterns  from  the  standpoint  of  a  group  are  not 
necessarily  consistent  with  an  optimal  position  for  each  individual. 
Conflicts  may  arise  which  involve  some  of  the  hitherto  unsolved  prob- 
lems of  welfare  economics.  In  this  manner  the  variant  of  the  fourth 
approach  might  proceed. 

Before  this  chapter  is  brought  to  a  close,  a  few  words  might  be 
said  about  the  author's  approach.  In  a  real  sense  it  is  eclectic,  drawing 
upon  various  elements  of  the  works  of  others.  It  aims  at  developing 
in  this  volume  principles  for  a  general  theory  through  reducing  to 
common  simple  terms  the  basic  elements  of  the  various  location 
theories,  beginning  first  with  Weberian  dogma.  It  does  not  purport 
to  present  in  detail  and  evaluate  various  location  theories  nor  to  weave 
the  fabric  of  a  complete  and  realistic  space-economy.  Rather,  with 
a  full  recognition  of  the  deficiencies  and  non-operational  character  of 
our  general  location  principles,  it  seeks  to  bring  the  separate  location 
theories  into  one  general  doctrine,  to  the  extent  possible;  and  to  fuse 
the  resulting  doctrine,  where  this  can  be  done,  with  existing  production, 
price,  and  trade  theory.  This  is  sought  in  order  to  develop  a  superior 
set  of  tools  and  conceptual  framework  for  the  theoretical  and  empirical 
type  of  regional  analysis  which  will  be  attempted  in  a  second  volume 
and  which,  together  with  the  general  location  analysis,  aims  at  increas- 
ing the  understanding  of  the  structure  and  changing  character  of 
spatial  phenomena. 


Chapter 


Some  General  Theories 
of  Location  and  Space-Economy' 


1.     The  Anglo-Saxon  Bias 

The  difficulties  of  the  problem  depend  chiefly  on  variations  in  the  area 
of  space,  and  the  period  of  time  over  which  the  market  in  question  ex- 
tends; the  influence  of  time  being  more  fundamental  than  that  of  space. 2 

Thus  spoke  Marshall,  in  line  with  Anglo-Saxon  tradition,  and  in 
the  half-century  to  follow  Anglo-Saxon  economists  were  to  hearken  to 
his  cry.  Theoreticians  of  today  are  chiefly  preoccupied  with  intro- 
ducing the  time  element  in  full  into  their  analyses,  and  the  literature 
abounds  with  models  of  a  dynamic  nature.  Yet  who  can  deny  the 
spatial  aspect  of  economic  development:  that  all  economic  processes 
exist  in  space,  as  well  as  over  time?  Realistically,  both  time  and 
space  must  be  vital  considerations  in  any  theory  of  economy.  Unfor- 
tunately, however,  aside  from  those  of  the  monopolistic  competition 

1  As  already  indicated  in  the  Preface,  the  basic  material  for  this  chapter  was 
written  in  1947  and  published  in  1949.  At  that  time  we  emphasized  an  imbalance 
of  the  Anglo-Saxon  literature.  Since  then  this  imbalance  has  been  partially  cor- 
rected, in  particular  in  the  works  of  Enke,  Samuelson,  Koopmans,  Beckmann,  and 
Fox  which  will  be  cited  in  a  later  chapter.  Nevertheless,  the  statements  are  left 
unqualified  in  order  to  retain  the  forcefulness  of  the  argument  as  first  developed. 

It  should  be  noted  that  this  chapter  is  not  intended  as  a  survey  of  all  location 
theory  but  only  of  general  location  theory  up  to  1947.  It  therefore  fails  to  treat 
many  of  the  contributions  to  partial  location  theory  of  such  individuals  as  Thiinen, 
Launhardt,  Englander,  Palander,  and  Hoover. 

2  Alfred  Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics,  8th  ed.,  London,  1936,  Book  V, 
Chap.  XV,  Sect.  1. 

24 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  25 

school  of  thought,  particularly  Chamberlin,^  the  architects  of  our 
finest  theoretical  structures  have  intensified  the  prejudice  exhibited 
by  Marshall.  They  continue  to  abstract  from  the  element  of  space, 
and  in  so  doing  they  are  approaching  a  position  of  great  imbalance. ^ 

Let  us  consider,  as  an  example,  modern  general  equilibrium  theory. 
The  latest  contributors  have  concentrated  their  efforts  on  attacking  the 
problem  of  time  to  the  exclusion  of  that  of  space.  Hicks, ^  Mosak,^ 
Lange,'''  and  Samuelson,^  to  name  a  few,  have  all  treated  an  economy 
in  which  all  factors  and  producers,  commodities  and  consumers 
are,  in  effect,  congregated  at  one  point.  Hicks,  to  be  sure,  begins 
by  formulating  the  problem  in  a  manner  pregnant  with  spatial 
implications: 

It  turns  out,  on  investigation,  that  most  of  the  problems  of  several 
variables,  with  which  economic  theory  has  to  concern  itself,  are  problems 
of  interrelations  of  markets.  Thus,  the  more  complex  problems  of  inter- 
national trade  involve  the  interrelations  of  the  markets  for  imports  and 
exports  with  the  capital  market.  .  .  . 

.  .  .  The  method  of  General  Equilibrium,  which  these  writers  (Walras, 
Pareto,  and  Wicksell)  elaborated,  was  especially  designed  to  exhibit  the 
economic  system  as  a  whole,  in  the  form  of  a  complex  pattern  of  inter- 
relations of  markets.  Our  work  is  bound  to  be  in  their  tradition,  and  to 
be  a  continuation  of  theirs. ^ 

But  actually  he  confines  himself  to  a  wonderland  of  no  spatial  dimen- 

3  E.  H.  Chamberlin,  The  Theory  of  Monopolistic  Competition,  Cambridge, 
Mass.,  1933;  and  Chamberlin 's  doctoral  dissertation  deposited  under  the  same 
title  in  the  Harvard  University  library,  1927.  In  his  doctoral  dissertation  Cham- 
berlin treats  the  space  factor  somewhat  more  thoroughly  and  more  as  an  integral 
part  of  his  theory.  See  also  S.  Enke,  "Space  and  Value,"  Quarterly  Journal  oj 
Economics,  Vol.  LVI  (August  1942),  pp.  627-37. 

4  Outside  of  the  field  of  monopolistic  competition  there  have  been  scattered 
treatments  by  Anglo-Saxon  theorists  of  certain  aspects  of  space  as  an  economic 
factor.  For  example,  F.  A.  Fetter  has  treated  space  in  "The  Economic  Law  of 
Market  Areas,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  XXXVIII  (May  1924),  p. 
525;  treatises  on  international  trade  have  attributed  some  importance  to  spatial 
resistances;  rent  theorists  have  been  forced  to  recognize,  however  inadequately, 
the  existence  of  space  in  the  separation  of  immobile  natural  resources  and  markets ; 
and  so  forth.  But  in  these  latter  instances  only  passing  attention  has  been  given 
to  this  vital   consideration. 

5  J.  R.  Hicks,  Value  and  Capital,  Oxford,  1939. 

6  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  General  Equilibrium  Theory  in  International  Trade,  Cowles 
Commission  Monograph  No.  7,  Bloomington,  Ind.,  1944. 

"^  Oscar  Lange,  Price  Flexibility  and  Employment,  Cowles  Commission  Mono- 
graph No.  8,  Bloomington,  Ind.,  1944. 

8  Paul  A.  Samuelson,  Foundations  of  Economic  Analysis,  Cambridge,  Mass., 
1947. 

9  Hicks,  op.  cit.,  p.  2.    The  words  in  parentheses  are  added. 


26  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

sions.  Apparently  he  assumes  markets  to  be  perfect,  one  price  ruling 
throughout  each  of  them.  Or,  otherwise  expressed,  transport  costs 
and  other  costs  involved  in  movement  within  a  "market"  are  assumed 
to  be  zero.  In  this  sense  the  factor  of  space  is  repudiated,  everything 
within  the  economy  is  in  effect  compressed  to  a  point,  and  all  spatial 
resistance  disappears. ^^ 

The  approach  to  unreality  which  is  inherent  in  such  a  treatment  is 
best  illustrated  by  Mosak's  work,  Gerieral  Equilibrium  Theory  in 
International  Trade,  which  is  excellent  in  other  respects.  Although 
*  Mosak  expands  Hicks's  analysis  to  embrace  an  international  economy, 
spatially  speaking  he  is  still  dwelling  within  a  dimensionless  habitat. 
His  study  of  the  effects  of  international  exchange,  of  unilateral  pay- 
ments, and  of  impediments  to  international  trade, n  can  be  interpreted 
as  treating  an  anomalous  field:  a  one-point  ivorld,  which  somehow  or 
other  is  conceived  as  divided  into  n  -parts,  representing  n  nations, 
between  which  trade  and  trade  barriers  exist. ^"^ 

We  may  now  consider  the  relations  of  general  equilibrium  theory 
to  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy  envisaged  in  this 
book.  We  conceive  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy 
to  be  one  which  comprehends  the  economy  in  its  totality.    Not  only 

10  The  explanation  may  partly  lie  in  Hicks's  rejection  of  monopolistic  competi- 
tion theory  generally  in  favor  of  perfect  competition  on  the  ground  that  the 
former  introduces  elements  of  indeterminacj^,  whereas  his  preference  is  for  deter- 
minate solutions  (ojo.  cit.,  pp.  83-85).  It  is  clear  that  Hicks  fails  to  reveal  an 
appreciation  of  the  spatial  aspect  of  monopolistic  competition  theory  and  of  the 
extent  to  which  determinate  solutions  are  obtained  in  monopolistic  competition 
analysis  through  its  consideration  of  the  space  factor. 

Professor  Schumpeter  has  pointed  out  to  me  in  conversation  that  one  might 
maintain  that  transport  cost  is  implicitly  contained  in  production  cost,  and  that 
the  Hicksian  analysis  is  thus  sufficiently  comprehensive.  My  point  is  this:  pro- 
duction theory,  having  gone  bej'ond  the  mere  statement  that  the  producer  maxi- 
mizes his  profits  (in  which  statement  all  production  costs  are  implicitly  treated), 
from  a  methodological  standpoint  cannot  justifiably  treat  certain  production  costs 
expUcitly  and  other  important  ones  implicitly  in  order  to  avoid  the  obstacles  to 
anatysis  which  the  latter  present.  For  a  balanced  treatment,  the  particular  effects 
of  transport  and  spatial  costs  in  separating  producers  from  each  other  must  be 
considered.  They  are  too  vital  to  be  sidestepped  through  impHcit  treatment,  as 
Hicks  and  others  may  be  interpreted  as  having  done. 

11  Transport  costs  are  not  explicitly  treated.  The  analysis  of  their  effects,  it  is 
maintained,  follows  similar  lines  to  that  of  the  effects  of  import  and  export  taxes 
(Mosak,  op.  cit.,  pp.  64r-65). 

12  At  this  stage  in  the  development  of  theory,  it  is  as  unjustifiable  and  inade- 
quate to  lump  transport  costs  into  one  category  along  with  all  trade  resistances 
in  the  theory  of  trade  as  it  is  to  treat  them  as  implicit  production  costs  in  the 
theory  of  production. 

Although  these  indictments  are  levelled  specifically  at  Mosak,  they  apply  to 
others  as  well. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  27 

are  the  mutual  relations  and  interdependence  of  all  economic  elements, 
both  in  the  aggregate  and  atomistically,  of  fundamental  importance; 
but  the  spatial  as  well  as  the  temporal  (dynamic)  character  of  the 
interrelated  economic  processes  must  enter  the  picture.  Seen  in  this 
perspective,  Hicksian  general  equilibrium  analysis  is  but  a  very  special 
case  of  a  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy  which  con- 
cerns itself  with  the  local  distribution  of  factors  and  resources  as  well 
as  with  local  variations  in  prices  and,  thus,  with  the  immobilities  and 
spatial  inelasticities  of  factors  and  goods. 

In  the  sections  to  follow,  the  contributions  of  several  authors  who 
have  pioneered  in  this  field  will  be  restated  and  critically  evaluated. 
It  will  not  be  surprising  to  find  that  these  authors  have  come  under 
the  influence  of  German  thought,  i^  The  classical  school  and  their 
followers  were  too  prone  to  overlook  the  local  differences  within  the 
English  economy.  England's  dominant  international  position  and 
the  dynamic  aspects  of  her  industrial  development  fm'ther  helped  to 
cloud  their  vision.  It  was  in  international  trade  theory  that  the  spatial 
structure  of  the  domestic  economy  was  most  explicitly  assumed  away 
or  relegated  to  the  background.  This  step  facilitated  a  macroscopic 
process  analysis  (though  quite  elementary)  of  international  trade  w^iich 
seemed  so  urgent  to  the  classical  school. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  reaction  of  German  thought  to  classical 
teachings,  which  precipitated  the  rise  of  the  German  historical  school, 
ploughed  the  ground  for  contributions  in  the  field  of  "Raumwdrtschaft." 
In  the  study  of  the  stages  of  economic  development,  the  spatial 
structure  of  economic  processes  w^as  necessarily  a  primary  concern. 
And,  wdth  the  impress  of  the  Lausanne  school  of  thought  upon  German 
economics,  it  was  almost  inevitable  that  attempts  w^ould  be  made  at 
a  fusion  of  space  with  general  equilibrium  analysis. 

2.     Some  Early  Atteivipts  at  General  Theory 

The  first  attempt  to  construct  a  general  location  theorj^  is  to  be 
attributed  to  Alfred  Weber  in  his  Chap.  VII,  "Manufacturing  Industry 
Within  the  Economic  System."  i4  it  is  true  that  the  father  of  location 
theorists,  von  Thiinen,  who  was  far  in  advance  of  his  time,  did  progress 

13  In  his  various  writings  Chamberlin,  who  has  not  come  under  German  influence, 
does  treat  spatial  position  explicitly,  but  only  as  one  of  the  leading  manifestations 
of  the  broader  category  of  "product  differentiation."  From  his  analysis  emerges 
explicitly  the  need  for  applying  the  techniques  of  monopolistic  competition  in 
handling  the  space-econom}'  of  reality.  However,  his  works  cannot  be  classified 
as  general  location  theory. 

!■*  i/ber  den  Standort  der  Industnen,  Tubingen.  1909;  English  translation  with 
introduction  and  notes  by  Carl  J.  Friedrich,  Alfred  Weber's  Theory  of  the  Loca- 
tion oj  Industiies,  Chicago,  1929. 


28  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

somewhat  toward  a  general  locational  analysis.  It  may  have  been 
that  his  interests  and  experiences  in  the  operation  of  his  estate  'Gut 
Tellow'  served  to  restrict  the  generality  of  his  abstract  thinking. 
Nonetheless,  the  seeds  for  developing  the  basic  methodology  in  analysis 
of  specific  as  well  as  general  location  problems  can  be  found  in  Thiinen's 
work.  15  The  science  of  economics  has  suffered  from  the  relative 
neglect  of  his  methods  during  the  nineteenth  and  early  twentieth 
centuries. 

Launhardt,  the  other  major  predecessor  of  Weber,  also  failed  to 
achieve  sufficient  generality  in  his  analysis.  In  fact  Launhardt's  studies 
of  industrial  location  and  market  areas  ^^  treated  a  narrower  set  of 
circumstances  than  were  encompassed  in  Thiinen's  isolated  state. 

Weber's  attempt  at  general  locational  analysis  was  undoubtedly 
greatly  influenced  by  the  writings  of  Roscher  and  Schaffle.i'^  Weber 
pursued  an  essentially  evolutionary  approach.  He  tried  to  develop 
the  general  basis  upon  which  any  given  historical  system  orients 
itself  or,  in  other  words,  a  theory  of  the  transformation  of  locational 
structures. 

His  method  is  to  inquire  into  the  forces  that  come  into  operation 

The  material  in  the  rest  of  Weber's  book  does  not  concern  general  location.  It 
deals  with  what  is  usually  conceived  of  as  Weberian  location  theory,  namely,  an 
industrial  location  theory  under  the  special  conditions  that:  (1)  the  location  and 
the  size  of  the  places  of  consumption  are  fixed;  (2)  the  location  of  the  material 
deposits  is  given;  (3)  the  geographic  cost  pattern  of  labor  is  given,  and  at  any  one 
point  labor  is  unlimited  in  supply  at  constant  cost. 

Weber's  other  important  contribution  ("Industrielle  Standortslehre :  Allgemeine 
und  kapitahstische  Theorie  des  Standortes,"  Grundriss  der  Sozialokonomik,  Part 
VI,  2nd  rev.  ed.,  Tiibingen,  1923)  merely  touches  the  field  of  general  location 
theory. 

15  Johann  Heinrich  von  Thiinen,  Der  isolierte  Staat  in  Beziehung  auf  Land- 
wirtschajt  und  N ationalokonomie ,  Hamburg,  1826.  See  also  the  interesting  article 
by  Bertil  Ohlin,  "Some  Aspects  of  the  Theory  of  Rent :  von  Thiinen  vs.  Ricardo," 
Economics,  Sociology  and  the  Modern  World:  Essays  in  Honor  of  T.  N.  Carver, 
Cambridge,  Mass.,  1935. 

16  See,  in  particular,  "Die  Bestimmung  des  zweckmassigsten  Standortes  einer 
gewerbhchen  Anlage,"  Zeitschrijt  des  Vereins  deutscher  Ingenieure,  Vol.  XXVI, 
No.  3,  Berlin,  1882,  and  Mathematische  Begrundung  der  Volkswirischaftslehre, 
Leipzig,  1885,  Part  III. 

1'^  Wilhelm  Roscher,  "Studien  liber  die  Naturgesetze,  welche  den  zweckmassigen 
Standort  der  Industriezweige  bestimmen,"  Ansichten  der  Volkswirtschaft  aus  dem 
geschichtlichen  Standpunkte,  3rd  ed.,  1878;  A.  Schaffie,  Das  gesellschajtliche  Sys- 
tem der  menschlichen  Wirtschajt,  3rd  ed.,  Tiibingen,  1873.  Both  were  of  the 
German  historical  school  and  were  primarily  concerned  with  discovering  whether 
or  not  there  were  any  natural  laws  or  regularities  in  the  evolving  locational  struc- 
tures of  economies.  Their  contribution  rests  in  their  collection  of  historical  facts 
and  in  their  presentation  of  an  abundance  of  conflicting  ideas. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  29 

when  a  people  occupy  an  undeveloped  country  and  establish  an  isolated 
economic  system.  At  first  an  agricultural  stratum  forms  to  produce 
the  necessary  means  of  subsistence.  As  indicated  in  the  preceding 
chapter,  the  settled  area  with  its  agricultural  population  serves  then 
as  the  geographical  foundation  for  all  other  strata.  It  determines  in 
the  first  instance  the  loci  (places)  of  consumption  for  the  second 
stratum,  namely,  the  primary  industrial  stratum,  which  produces  for 
the  agricultural  stratum.  In  turn,  the  primary  industrial  stratum 
serves  as  the  loci  of  consumption  for  the  third  stratum,  namely,  the 
secondary  industrial  stratum.  This  third  stratum  actually  consists  of 
numerous  substrata,  each  of  which  is  oriented  to  and  is  smaller  than 
the  preceding  one,  the  first  substratum  being  the  only  one  directly 
oriented  to  the  primary  industrial  stratum.  These  three  strata  form 
the  core  of  the  economic  system.  The  mass  of  local  tradesmen  and 
functionaries,  engaged  in  the  process  of  circulation  and  in  performing 
personal  services,  strengthens  proportionally  the  different  parts  of  this 
system. 

A  fourth  stratum,  the  central  organizing  stratum,  is  essentially 
independent  of  any  of  the  three  preceding  ones.  It  consists  of  officials 
and  businessmen  with  general  organizing  and  managing  functions, 
members  of  the  liberal  professions,  and  persons  living  off  accumulated 
wealth.  Their  pattern  of  locations  within  the  economic  system,  if 
not  arbitrary,  is  determined  not  by  economic  forces  but  by  others. 
A  fifth  stratum,  the  central  dependent  stratum,  is  formed  and  tied  to 
the  central  organizing  stratum  in  the  same  way  as  is  the  secondary 
industrial  to  the  primary  industrial  stratum. 

The  locational  structures  of  these  five  strata  are  interrelated  with 
forces  playing  back  and  forth  among  them.  For  example,  though  the 
agricultural  stratum  appears  on  the  scene  first,  the  formation  of  cities 
incident  to  industrial  development  induces  rearrangements  of  the 
agricultural  structure  to  conform  more  closely  to  the  pattern  of  con- 
centric zones  as  conceived  by  von  Thiinen. 

This  is  as  far  as  Weber  goes.  Despite  the  later  writings  of 
Englander,i8  which  elaborate  and  develop  the  evolutionary  approach 

18  Oskar  Englander,  "Kritisches  und  Positives  zu  einer  allgemeinen  reinen  Lehre 
vom  Standort,"  Zeitschrift  fur  Volkswirtschaft  und  Sozialpolitik,  Neue  Folge, 
Vol.  V,  Nos.  7-9  (1926).  With  Englander  the  problem  is  to  investigate  first  the 
spatial  form  of  primary  production,  i.e.,  of  a  land  and  forest  economy,  where  all 
households  are  self-sufficient.  Next,  specialized  products  are  assumed  to  be  culti- 
vated on  land  of  particular  quality,  and  the  consequent  changes  in  the  spatial 
structure  of  the  economy  are  observed.  In  turn,  agricultural  industries,  mining, 
manufacturing,  and  other  economic  elements  and  complicating  factors  are  suc- 
essively  introduced  and  the  resulting  spatial  realignments  of  economic  activities 


30  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

in  other  ways,  and  of  Ritschl/^  too,  no  essential  advance  in  this 
technique  of  general  analysis  is  made.  The  technique  is  currently 
inadequate;  it  does  not  present  any  general,  heuristic  principle  by 
means  of  which  one  can  order  the  spatial  complexities  involved  in 
the  total  location  of  economic  activities.  It  merely  records  the  inter- 
relations of  the  various  strata  and  some  of  the  reactions  of  one  stratum 
upon  another.  For  any  given  stratum,  or  combination  of  strata,  it 
fails  to  get  at  the  rule  or  rules  governing  structure  and  provides  no 
common  denominator  in  terms  of  which  all  the  forces  stemming  from 
the  various  interrelations  can  be  expressed  and  evaluated  and  by  means 
of  which  a  net  effect  could  perhaps  be  deduced. ^o  This  is  the  task  of 
a  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy. 

Nonetheless,  the  evolutionary  approach  is  very  useful.  It  not  only 
furnishes  a  convenient  and  meaningful  breakdown  for  studying 
historical  sequences  of  locational  structures  and  for  classifying  his- 
torical facts  but  also  will  be  very  suggestive  for  pursuing  dynamic 
analysis,  once  an  improved  general  static  theory  has  been  achieved. ^i 

noted.  Ultimately,  according  to  Englander,  an  approximation  to  the  picture  of 
a  modern  economy  is  realized. 

19  Hans  Ritschl,  "Reine  und  historische  Dynamik  des  Standortes  der  Erzeu- 
gungszweige,"  Schmollers  Jahrbuch,  Vol.  LI  (1927),  pp.  813-70.  Ritschl,  recog- 
nizing that  the  location  picture  is  historically  relative,  follows  Weber's  classification 
of  strata  and  traces  in  detail  their  development  during  the  periods  of  village,  city, 
territorial,  national,  and  world  economy. 

Also  see  R.  G.  Hawtrey,  The  Economic  Problem,  New  York,  1925,  Chaps.  VII 
and  IX,  in  which  to  some  extent  he  adopts  the  approach  of  Englander  and  Ritschl. 

20  This  is  clearly  indicated  in  Ritschl's  work.  After  describing  in  detail,  in  a 
section  on  pure  dynamics,  the  various  possible  effects  of  changes  in  ten  or  more 
major  locational  elements,  he  is  unable  to  find  a  method  for  combining  their 
effects.    (Op.  cit.,  pp.  853-56.) 

21  In  the  order  of  treatment  of  subject  matter,  the  work  of  E.  M.  Hoover,  Loca- 
tion Theory  and  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Industries,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1937,  some- 
what resembles  the  evolutionary  approach.  But  Hoover's  analysis  is  definitely 
partial,  though  in  a  broad  setting.  Through  carefully  drawing  up  a  set  of  assump- 
tions and  relaxing  them  one  by  one,  he  is  able  to  proceed  from  an  analysis  of 
extractive  industries  to  a  treatment  of  manufacturing,  first  under  simple  condi- 
tions and  then  under  more  complex  ones.  He  emphasizes  the  major  specific  forces 
at  work  and  does  not  pay  too  much  attention  to  general  interrelations,  especially 
when  they  can  be  stated  only  in  broad  terms.  In  this  way  he  is  able  to  synthesize 
the  various  theoretical  contributions  of  his  predecessors  that  are  of  practical  value 
and,  by  employing  illustrative  empirical  material,  is  able  to  stick  close  to  reahty. 
From  the  standpoint  of  balance  and  sound  judgment  Hoover's  writings  are  the 
best.    See  also  his  Location  of  Economic  Activity,  New  York,  1948. 

Other  major  works  in  English  on  location  theory  are  by  A.  P.  Usher  {A  Dynamic 
Analysis  oj  the  Location  of  Economic  Activity,  unpubUshed)  and  by  W.  H.  Dean, 
Jr.   {The   Theory  of  the  Geographic  Location  of  Economic  Activities,  doctoral 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  31 

3.     Predohl's  Conception 

Shortly  after  the  appearance  of  Weber's  book,  Bortkiewicz^s  and 
Schumpeter2  3  recognized  the  need  of  a  general  equilibrium  analysis 
to  supplement  partial  locational  theories. 2 4  Considerably  later 
Englander2  5  came  to  appreciate  in  full  the  implications  of  a  general 
theory  of  location.  The  pure  theory  of  location,  according  to 
Englander,  is  the  general  theory  of  "local  conditionality"  within  an 
economy.  Any  given  entrepreneur,  in  choosing  the  site  at  which  to 
produce  or  render  services,  considers  the  various  supply  prices  existing 
in  the  various  localities  for  the  inputs  that  he  might  possibly  employ. 
At  the  same  time  he  considers  the  various  prices  which  might  be 
obtained  in  the  various  localities  for  his  product  or  services.  When 
finally  he  does  locate  at  a  site,  he  influences  in  turn  the  prices  of  various 
inputs  and  outputs.  Through  being  so  interrelated,  the  pattern  of 
local  price  differences  and  the  location  of  economic  activities  are  simul- 
taneously determined  by  a  general  theory  of  "local  conditionality."  2  6 

dissertation,  Harvard  University,  1938:  Selections  published  by  Edward  Brothers, 
Inc.,  Ann  Arbor,  Mich.,  1938).  Usher  and  Dean,  too,  follow  a  partial  approach 
both  in  their  static  analyses  and  in  their  dynamics  where  they  rely  upon  extensive 
use  of  historical  matei'ial.  Their  interests  are  in  "the  broader  aspects  of  the 
developing  geographic  patterns  of  population  density"  and  in  "the  relations  of 
these  patterns  to  localized  resources  and  to  the  significance  that  regional  resources 
possess  under  the  technological  conditions  of  each  historical  period."  (Usher, 
op.  cit.,  p.  2.)  They  study:  (1)  topography  as  a  vital  and  partially  independent 
factor  in  the  pattern  of  settlement;  (2)  the  impact  of  transport  innovation  par- 
ticularly as  it  relates  to  the  accessibility  of  resource  deposits  to  the  primary 
regions  of  the  world;  (3)  nodality  and  industrial  agglomeration;  (4)  externally- 
conditioned  labor  and  the  controlling  role  of  energy  resources;  (5)  the  historical 
patterns  of  urban  settlements;  and  (6)  other  related  subjects.  These  studies  are 
in  a  sense  interwoven,  but  at  best  only  loosely.  The  result  is  a  set  of  highly  valu- 
able partial  analyses,  and  not  a  finely  spun  general  framework. 

^^ Deutsche  Literaturzeitung,  Vol.  XXXI   (1910),  pp.  1717-24. 

^^  Jahrhuch  fiir  Gesetzgebung,  Verwaltung  und  Volkswirtschajt,  Vol.  XXXIV, 
No.  3   (1910),  pp.  444-47. 

24  V.  Furlan  ["Die  Standortsprobleme  in  der  Volks-  und  Weltwirtschaftslehre," 
Weltwirtschajtliches  Archiv,  Vol.  II  (1913),  pp.  1-34]  makes  a  somewhat  abortive 
attempt  at  general  locational  analysis.  The  complicated  interrelations  of  various 
economic  factors  as  well  as  the  "spatial  transformation  of  goods"  are  fully  recog- 
nized; but  the  contributions  to  knowledge  are  essentially  along  the  lines  of  devel- 
oping overly  simplified  models  of  markets,  domestic  and  international,  more 
specifically  of  determining  points  of  collection  and  distribution  of  goods  and  of 
export  and  import,  and  the  related  paths  of  commerce. 

25  0?).  cit. 

26 Further:  (1)  by  classifying  raw  materials  and  factors  of  production,  whether 
mobile  or  immobile,  as  place-free  (available  everywhere  under  the  same  condi- 


32  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Somewhat  earlier  (1925)  than  Englander's  publications  there  ap- 
peared an  article,  "Das  Standortsproblem  in  der  Wirtschaftstheorie,"  ^^ 
by  Andreas  Predohl,  which  utilized  a  principle  by  means  of  which  a 
general  equilibrium  approach  could  be  systematically  applied  to 
location  analysis.  This  was  none  other  than  the  familiar  substitution 
principle,  already  well  established  in  general  equilibrium  theory. 

Although  Predohl  did  visualize  new  horizons  in  the  extended  use  of 
this  principle,  he  unfortunately  tried  to  remain  within  the  scope  of 
traditional  thought.  He  purported  to  deduce  a  general  location  theory 
as  a  special  case  of  the  existing  general  economic  theory,  as  a  logical 
and  inherent  element  of  it.  The  general  economic  theory  to  which  he 
alluded  was  the  theory  of  interdependent  prices  and  quantities,  of 
general  equilibrium  as  expounded  successively  by  Walras,  Pareto,  and 
Cassel.  He  wished  to  investigate  how  far  the  location  problem  is  a 
price  problem;  location  theory,  a  price  theory.  In  other  words,  to 
what  extent  does  the  local  distribution  of  production  lie  inside  the 
economic  relationship  of  interdependent  prices? ^8 

Predohl  contends  that  the  problem  of  the  local  distribution  of 
economic  activity  is  synonymous  with  the  problem  of  the  distribu- 
tion of  determined  groups  (bundles)  of  productive  factors  (he  groups 
productive  factors  under  the  categories  of  land,  labor,  and  capital) 
since  every  economic  activity  uses  a  grouping  of  factors.  The  distribu- 
tion of  determined  groups  of  productive  factors  in  turn  is  a  special 
case  of  the  distribution  of  productive  factors  in  general. ^ 9    To  Predohl, 

tions),  conditionally  place-bound  (available  at  all  or  some  places  under  unequal 
conditions),  and  unconditionally  place-bound  (present  at  one  site),  and  (2)  by  con- 
ceiving immobile  goods  as  goods  of  infinite  weight  which  enter  into  production 
with  infinite  weight-loss,  Englander  brings  together  the  specific  location  theories  of 
industry  and  agriculture  within  the  confines  of  his  pure  location  theory,  not  as 
distinct  compartments,  but  as  internally  related  sectors. 

Elsewhere,  too,  Englander  has  attacked  a  broad  range  of  location  problems, 
but  only  through  elucidation  of  simplified,  isolated  cases.  See  his  Theone  des 
Giiterverkehrs  und  der  Frachtsdtze,  Jena  1924,  and  "Standort"  in  Handworterbuch 
der  Staatswissenschajten,  4th  rev.  ed.,  Jena  1926,  Vol.  VII. 

27  Weltwirtschaftliches  Archiv,  Vol.  XXI  (1925),  pp.  294-331.  A  briefer  article 
in  English,  "The  Theory  of  Location  in  its  Relation  to  General  Economics,"  ap- 
peared in  the  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  XXXVI  (1928),  pp.  371-90.  A 
much  more  recent  statement  in  German  which  was  available  only  after  the  fol- 
lowing paragraphs  were  written  is  contained  in  his  book,  Aussenwirtschajt :  Welt- 
ivirtschaft,  Handelspolitik  und  Wdhrungspolitik,  Gottingen,  1949.  Also  see 
Predohl's  reply  to  Englander's  criticism,  "Zur  Frage  einer  allgemein  Standorts- 
theorie,"  Zeitschrijt  filr  Volkswirtschajt  und  Sozialpolitik,  Vol.  V,  Nos.  10-12 
(1927),  pp.  756-63. 

28  "Das  Standortsprobleme  .  .  ."     Op.  cit.,  pp.  295-97. 

29  As  will  be  shown  later,  this  statement  is  very  weak,  if  not  untenable. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  33 

general  interdependence  theory  explains  the  distribution  of  productive 
factors  in  general  by  means  of  the  principle  of  substitution.  Therefore 
general  location  theory  is  deducible  from  the  application  of  the 
principle  of  substitution  to  the  employment  of  the  several  groups  of 
productive  factors.  ^^ 

Predohl  in  his  reasoning  overestimates  the  scope  of  Walrasian- 
Casselian  general  equilibrium  analysis.  On  the  whole  he  seems  to  be 
under  the  impression  that  this  analysis  implicitly  embraces  the  space 
element  in  its  entirety.  However,  as  indicated  previously,  modern  as 
well  as  earlier  general  equilibrium  analyses,  with  minor  exceptions, 
concern  a  one-point  world.  The  element  of  transport  cost  is  generally 
abstracted;  factors  and  products  possess  perfect  mobility.  In  essence  , 
there  is  no  spatial  distribution  of  factors;  the  relevant  problem  is  the 
distribution  of  factors  among  the  various  types  of  production.  In 
reality,  then,  the  situation  is  the  reverse  of  what  Predohl  has  con- 
ceived although  several  times  he  appears  to  realize  the  truth  of  the 
matter.  As  we  have  pointed  out,  Walrasian-Casselian  general  equi- 
librium analysis  is  but  a  special  case  of  a  general  location  theory. ^i 

Nevertheless,  the  tools  shaped  by  general  equilibrium  theory  are 
useful,  as  Predohl  discovered.  Starting  with  the  familiar  case  of 
Thiinen's  isolated  state, ^^  Predohl  assumes  all  locations  fixed  except 
that  of  one  enterprise.  A  shift  of  this  enterprise  toward  the  periphery 
implies  that  capital  and  labor  outlays  (including  transport  outlays) 
are  substituted  for  land-use  outlays.  The  reverse  takes  place  in  a 
shift  toward  the  central  consumption  point.  Application  of  the  prin- 
ciple of  substitution  will  yield  the  site  of  minimum  cost  so  far  as  these 
two  all-inclusive  groups  of  expenditures  are  concerned.  However, 
within  these  two  all-inclusive  groups,  there  are  other  substitution 
points.  For  example,  within  the  former  group,  there  is  a  substitution 
point  between  transport  outlays  and  local  capital  and  labor  outlays 
(such  as  is  involved  in  determining  whether  or  not  to  process  a  product 

30  Op.  cit.,  pp.  299-303. 

31  However,  see  Predohl's  reaction  to  these  statements  in  his  recent  article 
"Von  der  Standortslehre  zur  Raumwirtschaftslehre,"  Jahrbuch  fur  Sozialwissen- 
schaft,  Band  2,  Heft  1,  pp.  97-102. 

32  The  features  of  Thiinen's  familiar  model  are :  a  uniform  plain  with  equal 
fertiUty  and  possibilities  for  agricultural  production  at  all  points,  at  the  center 
of  which  hes  a  city  possessing  potential  transport  facilities  of  similar  character  in 
all  directions  (i.e.,  transport  costs  proportional  to  weight  and  distance).  Produc- 
tion aUgns  itself  around  the  city  in  rings  in  accordance  with  the  price  and  transport 
cost  of  each  particular  product  cultivated.  Predohl  adopts  at  the  start  an  ex- 
panded version  of  Thiinen  where  all  conditions  for  all  production,  whether  agricul- 
tural or  industrial,  are  uniform  throughout  the  plain  (ibid.,  p.  299). 


34  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

in  order  to  reduce  its  weight  or  bulk)  ;  and  within  the  category  of 
transport  outlay,  there  may  be  a  substitution  point  involved  in 
allocating  a  given  portion  between  transporting  a  raw  material  lying 
at  the  periphery  and  transporting  a  raw  material  lying  near  the  con- 
sumption center.  In  this  manner  innumerable  interdependent  points 
of  substitution  arise  which  determine  the  location  of  any  individual 
enterprise.  This  proposition,  states  Predohl,  can  be  extended  by  means 
of  general  equilibrium  analysis  to  cover  the  location  of  all  economic 
activities.  3  3 

Inequalities  in  local  resource  patterns,  land,  labor,  capital,  and 
transport  do  not  invalidate  the  operation  of  the  substitution  principle. 
They  present  various  technical  possibilities  for  production  which  are 
different  from  those  that  would  exist  in  Thiinen's  homogeneous  plain; 
but  essentially  these  new  production  possibilities,  like  the  old,  can 
be  expressed  in  terms  of  economic  values  and,  thus,  fall  within  the 
scope  of  substitution  operations.  Similarly,  economic  values  can  be 
imputed  to  various  historical-political  forces,  though  here  many  more 
difficulties  and  arbitrary  elements  creep  in.  Recognizing  these  various 
limitations  (for  example,  in  accounting  for  the  locus  of  consumption 
of  the  rentier  classes) ,  Predohl  does,  however,  maintain  that  the 
locationally  relevant  substitution  points,  thus  logically  deduced,  are 
applicable  in  general. ^  4 

It  is  to  be  expected  that  Predohl  in  this  first  attempt  at  substitution 
analysis  would  be  unable  to  resolve  all  the  difficulties  that  beset  his 
path.  His  argument  is  particularly  weak  when  he  becomes  specific 
and  illustrates  substitution  operations — a  step  which  he  avoids  as  much 
as  possible.  For  example,  he  utilizes  a  vague  concept,  namely,  a 
land-use  unit,  and  speaks  of  rent  outlays  at  different  sites  as  being 
proportional  to  the  quantities  of  land-use  units  at  those  sites.  Land 
more  distant  from  a  city  and  yielding  less  rent  therefore  relates  to 
fewer  technical  units  of  land  use  than  does  land  less  distant  which 
yields  greater  rent.  Englander  easily  demonstrated  that  this  proposi- 
tion is  false:  that  two  pieces  of  land  unequally  distant  from  a  city  can 

33  "Der  Standort  der  Produktion  bzw.  Produktionsstufe  ist  also  bestimmt  durch 
ein  System  von  Substitutionspimkten,  das  derart  gegliedert  ist,  dass  die  Gruppen 
einer  iibergeordneten  Kombination  untergeordnete  Kombination  in  sich  enthalten. 
Ubertragen  wir  diese  Losung  auf  samtliche  Produktionen,  dann  konnen  wir  unter 
Zuspitzung  eines  allgemeinen  Casselschen  Satzes  auf  unser  besonderes  Problem 
sagen:  Wenn  das  Preisverhaltnis  in  dieser  Weise  fur  jeden  einzelnen  Betrieb  die 
standortlich  relevanten  Substitutionspunkte  bestimmt,  sind  offenbar  durch  dasselbe 
fUr  die  gesamte  Gesellschaft  die  zu  verwendenden  Mengen  in  Verhaltnis  zueinan- 
der,  mithin  die  Standorte  bestimmt."    Ihid.,  pp.  306-7. 

34 /bid.,  pp.  308-11. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  35 

be  of  the  exact  same  quality  and  be  utilized  to  the  same  degree,  and 
yet  yield  different  rents.  ^^ 

Further,  Predohl  tends  to  convert  all  spatial  and  quality  differences 
into  differences  in  quantities  of  use  units.  Immobile  labor,  situated  at 
diverse  places  and  of  different  qualities,  can  be  converted  into  amounts 
of  labor-use  units  and  thus  made  comparable.  And  so  with  all  types 
of  resources. 3  6  In  this  way  all  geographic  differences  in  land,  labor, 
and  capital  can  be  summed  up  into  use  units  of  land,  labor,  and 
capital  at  any  given  point.  This  reasoning  lies  behind  Predohl's 
argument  that  the  distribution  among  various  economic  activities  of 
determined  groups  of  productive  factors  (each  group  at  any  point  of 
time  having  a  unique  spatial  position)  is  a  special  case  of  the  distribu- 
tion among  various  economic  activities  of  productive  factors  in  general 
in  terms  of  a  one-point  society. 

It  is  not  necessary  to  carry  the  argument  to  such  an  extreme,  if 
not  untenable,  position.  It  is  appropriate  now  to  suggest  certain 
revisions  and  extensions  to  be  developed  in  subsequent  chapters  in 
order  to  strengthen  the  basis  for  a  widespread  use  of  the  substitution 
principle  in  location  analysis. 

First  one  ought  to  distinguish  between  two  types  of  substitutions: 
(1)  that  between  transport  inputs;  and  (2)  that  between  outlays, 
between  revenues,  and  between  outlays  and  revenues.  If  there  is  any 
sense  at  all  to  location  economics,  it  is  because  there  are  certain 
regularities  in  the  variations  of  costs  and  prices  over  space.  These 
regularities  arise  primarily  because  transport  cost  is  some  function  of 
distance.  If  this  were  not  so,  if  transport  costs  were  completely 
irregular  and  their  changes  unpredictable — for  example,  if  transport 
costs  on  a  certain  item  were  positive  for  a  distance  of  100  miles 
and  negative  for  a  distance  of  101  miles — there  would  be  little  sense 
in  searching  for  a  general  economics  of  plant  locations.  The  spatial 
pattern  of  industrial  concentrations,  of  consuming  centers,  and  of  the 
production  of  raw  materials  would  be  quite  arbitrarj^  from  the  economic 
standpoint. 

Since  it  is  the  distance  factor  that  is  the  heart  of  locational  analysis, 
there  is  every  reason  to  speak  of  transport  inputs  (a  concept  to  be 
defined  later) ,  wherein  distance  and  weight  are  the  two  basic  factors, 
and  of  transport  rates  as  prices  of  these  inputs.  Location  theorists 
unfortunately  have  shied  away  from  such  a  concept.     However,  it 

35  "Kritisches  imd  Positives  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  499-500.  See  Predohl's  weak 
reply  ("Zur  Frage  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  758-60).  Also  see  his  later  and  stronger  reply 
("Von  der  Standortslehre  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  100-101). 

36  "The  Theory  of  Location  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  380-81. 


36  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

brings  into  bold  relief  the  basic  aspects  of  spatial  analysis  without 
the  necessity  of  tagging  each  unit  of  land,  labor,  and  capital  with  a 
set  of  absolute  spatial  co-ordinates  or  of  converting  them  into  common 
units,  if,  indeed,  this  can  be  done.  The  problem  of  production  becomes 
a  problem  of  choosing  the  right  combination  of  the  various  types  of 
capital, 'labor,  land,  and  transport  inputs.  In  the  case  of  transport- 
oriented  industries  and  transport- oriented  sets  of  economic  activities, 
how  the  essential  location  analysis  reduces  to  a  consideration  of 
substitution  between  transport  inputs  will  be  demonstrated. 

The  selection  of  the  correct  substitution  points  between  transport 
inputs  is  easy  to  visualize  although  in  practice  it  may  be  difficult  to 
effect  because  of  the  complicated  nature  of  transport  rate  structures. 
However,  selection  of  the  correct  substitution  point  between  a  transport 
input  and  a  labor  input,  or  between  the  two  groups,  transport  inputs 
and  labor  inputs,  cannot  be  so  satisfactorily  handled.  That  here  the 
choice  of  the  optimum  location  requires  an  outright  comparison  of 
outlays  on  the  various  kinds  of  labor,  or  of  total  labor  outlays  and 
total  transport  outlays,  or  of  total  labor  outlays  and  total  interest 
outlays,  and  so  forth  will  be  indicated.  Substitution  analysis  in  terms 
of  outlays  and  revenues  must  supplement  substitution  analysis  in 
terms  of  transport  inputs  in  order  to  achieve  a  proper  locational 
methodology. 

By  this  approach,  Predohl's  original  conception  can  be  made  more 
digestible  and  broadened  into  a  general  equilibrium  theory  of  space- 
economy,  which  includes  as  special  cases  various  types  of  location 
theories  as  well  as  actual  modern  general  equilibrium  theory.  ^'^ 

37  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  Predohl  and  others  have  rightly  pointed  out 
that  Weber's  industrial  location  theory  is  chiefly  based  on  technical  empirical 
knowledge.  Transport  costs  are  reduced  to  weight  and  distance,  i.e.,  to  technical 
factors;  varying  raw  material  prices  and  other  elements  are  reduced  in  similar 
fashion.  Technical  concepts  such  as  locational  weight,  material  index,  coefficient 
of  labor,  Formkoeffizient,  and  others  are  the  critical  measures.  The  point  of  trans- 
port orientation  is  merely  the  point  of  minimum  transportation  in  terms  of  ton- 
kilometers.  Essentially  Weber  abstracts  from  most  economic  interrelations  and 
reactions.    Only  under  severe  limitations  is  Weberian  doctrine  generally  applicable. 

However  these  criticisms  do  not  detract  from  the  merits  of  Weber's  contribu- 
tion. Formal  theory,  in  and  of  itself,  is  highly  unsatisfactory,  too  general  and, 
accordingly,  too  sterile.  As  Predohl  emphasizes,  it  needs  to  be  supplemented  by 
concrete  information;  abstract  and  vague  values  must  be  replaced  by  exact, 
quantitative  data.  In  other  words,  supplementary  explanations  are  required,  even 
if  they  are  obtained  in  such  a  manner  as  to  limit  their  general  validity.  It  is  in 
fulfilling  this  need  that  Weber's  work  is  of  great  significance.  If  the  general  theory 
of  location  constructed  upon  the  principle  of  substitution  is  to  be  of  pragmatic 
value,  to  it  must  be  added  empirical  location  theory  and  statistical  investigation 
which  seeks  out  regular  movements  in  major  economic  variables,  even  though 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  37 

4.     Weigmann's  Formulations 

In  this  section  a  summary  of  the  contributions  of  Hans  Weigmann,3  8 
which  have  received  but  slight  attention  in  the  literature  is  presented. 
Weigmann's  writings  on  general  location  theory  are  very  difficult  to 
comprehend,  because  of  both  his  vague  style  and  the  complexity  of  the 
basic  concepts.  These  concepts  do  not  lend  themselves  to  a  general 
synthesis  as  do  those  of  other  contributors.  Nonetheless,  they  seem 
to  disclose  some  of  the  more  promising  channels  of  exploration  for 
further  theoretical  development. 

Weigmann  attempts  to  formulate  the  foundations  for  a  realistic 
economic  theory  which  embraces  the  spatial  structure  of  economic 
processes,  the  spatial  extent  and  bonds  of  markets,  and  the  spatial 
interrelations  of  all  economic  quantities. 

The  first  principle  that  Weigmann  establishes  is  that  a  theory  of 
space-economy  embraces  a  theory  of  limited  competition.  Actually  all 
factors  and  goods,  regardless  of  setting,  face  immobilities  of  varying 
extent  in  all  directions;  and,  in  accordance  with  the  nature  of  the 
obstacles  to  movement,  whether  they  be  economic,  social,  political,  or 
cultural,  markets  are  restricted  in  scope.  The  competition  which  any 
good  or  factor  can  ofTer  to  other  goods  and  factors  at  different  locations 
is  incomplete.     The  existence  of  physical  space  implies  immobility, 

this  means  eliminating  the  numerous  special  factors  which  affect  each  individual 
situation.  Weber's  theory  of  industrial  location  is  just  such  a  supplementary, 
empirical  theory  (it  excludes  economic  details  which  he  considers  relatively  unim- 
portant, and  thus  in  great  part  hypothesizes  that  the  set  of  technical  substitution 
points  approximately  parallels  the  set  of  economic  substitution  points).  But 
ultimately  all  such  empirical  technical  functional  observations  must  be  translated 
into  economic  terms. 

Indeed,  it  is  only  by  utilizing  chiefly  the  Weberian  approach  with  supplementary 
economic  data  that  I  have  found  it  meaningful  to  analyze  the  locational  structure 
of  the  iron  and  steel  industry.  See  my  "Some  Locational  Factors  in  the  Iron 
and  Steel  Industry  since  the  Early  Nineteenth  Century,"  Journal  of  Political 
Economy,  Vol.  LVI  (June  1948) ;  and  (with  W.  Capron)  "The  Future  Locational 
Pattern  of  Iron  and  Steel  Production  in  the  United  States,"  Journal  of  Political 
Economy,  Vol.  LVII  (April  1949).  Also  see  E.  Niederhauser,  "Die  Standorts- 
theorie  Alfred  Webers,"  Staatswissenschaftliche  Studien,  Vol.  XIV  (Weinfelden, 
1944). 

38  "Ideen  zu  einer  Theorie  der  Raumwirtschaft,"  WeUwirtschaftliches  Archiv, 
Vol.  XXXIV  (1931),  pp.  1-40;  and  "Standortstheorie  und  Raumwirtschaft"  in  Joh. 
Heinr.  von  Thilnen  zuvi  150  Geburtstag,  ed.  by  W.  Seedorf  and  H.  Jurgen,  Rostock, 
Carl  Hinstorffs,  1933,  pp.  137-57.  To  trace  the  development  of  Weigmann's 
thought  the  reader  is  also  referred  to  the  following  of  his  works :  Kritischer  Beitrag 
zur  Theorie  des  internalionalen  Handels,  G.  Fischer,  Jena,  1926,  and  Politische 
Raumsordnung,  Hanseatische  Verlagsanstalt,  Hamburg,  1935. 


38  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

limited  competition,  and  spatial  inelasticity  (or  negative  spatial 
elasticity).  Thus  the  generally  accepted  principle  of  pure  competition 
is  not  applicable  to  the  analysis  of  spatial  economic  processes.  ^^ 

A  second  basic  principle  concerns  the  question  of  form.  In  place  of 
customary  linear  causal  analysis,  Weigmann  favors  the  approach 
of  general  equilibrium  theory  in  the  employment  of  Gestalt  analysis. 
He  observes  the  space-economy  as  a  whole  in  its  full  array  of  spatial 
markets.  In  that  sense  he  aims  at  presenting  a  realistic  functional 
picture  of  the  "form-full"  of  economic  life,  wherein  the  various 
elements  are  weighted  in  accord  with  their  importance.  Having 
adopted  this  methodology,  he  confronts  the  primary  problem  of 
determining  the  basic  form  (Grundgestalt)  of  economic  phenomena, 
i.e.,  the  Gestalt  core.  This  basic  form  should  then  provide  an 
heuristic  principle  to  help  master  and  order  systematically  the  "form 
wealth"  of  real  economic  life,  or  in  other  words,  the  countless  spatial 
forms  of  moving  economic  processes. ^o 

At  this  point  Weigmann  differentiates  between  statics  (mobility  or 
competition  as  potential  energy)  and  dynamics.  Since  he  purports 
to  describe  the  space-economy  in  its  realistic  setting,  he  is  compelled  to 
complicate  his  problem  manifoldly  by  introducing  the  time  element  and 
by  assigning  time  co-ordinates  to  his  various  markets  and  processes. 
Weigmann  poses  the  perplexing  problem  of  dynamics  as  follows:  to 
choose  that  time  period  which  would  yield  in  the  resulting  spatial  array 
of  markets  a  competition  field  (a  broad  market  area  in  time  and  space) 
which  could  be  valid  as  the  basic  form.^i  He  resolves  the  problem  by 
formulating  a  concept  quite  difficult  to  comprehend,  the  concept  of 
"relative  maximum."  It  states  that  as  an  increasing  amount  of  physical 
space  (therefore  spatial  resistance)  is  to  be  overcome  in  movement 
by  an  economic  object,  the  time  period  necessary  for  such  movement 
increases  until  it  reaches  a  maximum — a  maximum  in  the  sense  that 
given  still  more  time  a  further  spatial  movement  would  be  improbable 
because  of  the  overpowering  force  of  the  countless  obstacles.     There, 

39  "Ideen  zu  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  6-9.  These  points  are  also  developed  by  Cham- 
berlin  in  his  doctoral  dissertation  of  1927,  op.  cit.,  especially  pp.  105-09,  167-84; 
and  in  The  Theory  oj  Monopolistic  Competition,  1933,  passim.  In  the  latter,  a 
portion  of  the  earlier  analysis  devoted  to  two-dimensional  space  was  simplified 
to  one  dimension  and  removed  from  Chapter  5  to  Appendix  C. 

40 /bid.,  pp.  9-12. 

•*i ".  .  .  welches  Konkurrenzgebeit  ist  essentiell  im  Sinne  des  Gestaltganzen, 
wenn  behebiger  Absteckung  der  Zeitgrenzen  eine  Fiille  raumhche  variierender 
Flachen  entsteht?  Oder  anders  ausgedriickt:  welcher  Zeitraum  ist  zu  wahlen, 
damit  ein  mit  diesem  Zeitmass  gegebenes  Konkurrenzfeld  als  Grundgestalt 
gelten  kann?"    Ihid.,  p.  14. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  39 

where  the  time  period  reaches  its  maximum,  competition  ends  and  the 
competition  field  becomes  bounded.  In  other  words,  the  force  of  com- 
petition does  not  have  the  power  to  span  a  distance  greater  than  the 
radius  (or  axis)  of  its  field,  irrespective  of  the  time  factor  for  all 
practical  purposes.  This  principle  contains  the  definition  of  basic 
form.  The  basic  form  is  depicted  as  that  unit  of  space  (corresponding 
to  a  market  region  or  competition  field)  of  the  relatively  greatest  time- 
weight,  hence,  of  the  relatively  greatest  stability  and  permanence. ^  2 

Having  exposed  the  tremendous  magnitude  of  the  task  of  formulat- 
ing a  theory  of  space-economy,  Weigmann  stops  for  breath.  How  to 
locate  the  basic  form?  How  to  represent  as  an  empirical  Gestalt  unit 
the  multitude  of  interlaced,  mutually  related  individual  markets, 
market  strata,  and  market  densities?  From  here  on  our  author  can 
only  offer  fruitful  suggestions  and  preliminary  observations  for  con- 
quering the  manifold  difficulties  which  appear.  First  we  have  the 
classification  of  markets  according  to  structure.  Each  individual 
commodity  market  including  its  labor,  capital,  and  land  orientation 
possesses  a  particular  structure  which  offers  a  certain  resistance  to 
change.  Some  change  frequently,  others  slowly.  Some  are  active, 
others  highly  inactive.  By  definition  those  markets  of  a  relatively 
permanent  nature,  of  persistent  inactivity,  are  grouped  together  as  the 
essential  ones,  as  the  basic  form;  their  combined  structure  determines 
the  basic  structure  of  the  Gestalt  whole,  of  the  space-economy  under 
question.  On  the  other  hand,  the  rapidly  changing  markets  are  con- 
sidered as  accidental  or  secondary;  their  movements  are  charac- 
terized as  minor  modifications  of  the  Gestalt  form,  and  these 
movements  are  to  a  certain  extent  conditioned  by  the  already 
determined  basic  form,  by  the  core  of  markets  of  greatest  continuity. 
Fundamental  organic  change  of  the  Gestalt  picture  of  the  space- 
economy,  therefore,  implies  only  change  within  this  relatively  immu- 
table core  of  persistent  markets.  ^^ 

42  ".  .  .  und  fiihren  angesichts  des  Vorhandenseins  eines  relativen  Maximums 
zeitkostender  Bewegung  innerhalb  jedes  Gestaltganzen  zu  einem  Bilde  sich  biin- 
delnder  und  iiberschneidender  Konkurrenzfelder  als  den  akzidentiellen  und  peri- 
pheren  Erscheinungsformen  einer  zentralen  Grundgestalt.  Der  Begriff  des 
relativen  Maximums  besagt  dabei  folgendes:  Die  Konkurrenz  wird  gradweise 
beschrankt  und  als  dort  aufhorend  bedacht,  wo  die  zahlreichen  hemmenden 
Faktoren  den  sukzessiv  steigenden  Zeitaufwand  der  Bewegung  zu  einem  Maximum 
hinfuhren,  bei  dem  unter  den  konkret  gegebenen  tjmstanden  die  weitere  Bewegung 
unwahrscheinlich  wird  oder  auf  lange  Sicht  nicht  mehr  die  Kraft  besitzt,  mit 
Ansicht  auf  anhaltenden  Erfolg  Spannungsunterschiede  aufzugleichen.  Die  Grund- 
gestalt ist  also  die  Raumeinheit  des  relative  grossten  Zeitgewichtes;  die  Dauer 
des  Bestandes  gibt  ihr  den  Charakter  der  essentiellen  Form."    Ibid.,  pp.  14-15. 

43 /bid.,  pp.  16-19. 


40  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Our  task  is  further  illuminated  by  reference  to  the  structures  of  the 
specific  markets  for  land,  labor,  and  capital  goods.  Weigmann 
maintains  that  the  markets  for  the  productive  factors  of  labor  and 
land  are  primary  constituencies  of  the  basic  form.  Movements  in  all 
commodity  markets  course  back  to  these  two,  whether  directly  or 
indirectly,  through  semifinished  products  and  various  stages  of  produc- 
tion. And  in  these  markets  for  labor  and  land,  which  offer  great 
resistance  to  change,  are  focused  the  facts  of  scarcity  within  the 
economy. 

The  land  market  is  portrayed  as  a  spatially-connected  area  of 
supplied  land  services.  Actually  each  individual  piece  of  land  is 
distinct  and  immobilized  by  nature,  so  that  its  supply  area  has  no 
spatial  extent.  But  for  practical  purposes  Weigmann  conceives  of  a 
Gestalt  whole  (space-economy)  already  in  existence.  This  whole 
exerts  an  hypothetical  aggregate  demand  which,  in  turn,  defines  the 
boundaries  of  the  land  market,  the  peripheral  area  being  considered 
as  marginal  land.  The  supply  of  land  in  general  is  not  perfectly 
inelastic,  spatially  speaking.  Change  in  the  land  market  ensues  (1) 
from  additions  or  subtractions  at  the  fringe  to  the  land  under  cultiva- 
tion, i.e.,  an  expansion  or  contraction  of  the  space  base  of  the  economy, 
and  (2)  from  variations  in  the  intensity  of  use  and  in  the  methods  of 
cultivation  and  organization  of  each  individual  land  unit.  ^ 4 

The  size  and  nature  of  the  hypothetical  demand  mentioned  above  is 
obviously  related  to  the  labor  market.  The  labor  market,  in  contrast 
to  the  market  for  land,  is  much  less  rigid  and  invariable;  for  that 
reason  the  conception  and  description  of  it  are  theoretically  and 
empirically  much  more  difficult.  There  are  many  forms  of  labor 
immobility  and  inelasticity.  Weigmann  makes  a  beginning  at  analysis 
by  explaining  one,  namely  migi^ation  mobility.  To  delimit  the  labor 
market  accordingly,  one  must  recognize  the  various  tiijae  stages  of 
migration  (e.g.,  seasonal,  cyclical,  and  secular)  and  their  spatial 
forms.  In  line  with  familiar  Weberian  technique,  the  long-run  labor 
base  is  presented  as  a  continually  moving,  organic  process  whereby 
labor,  step-by-step  through  varying  intervals  of  time,  gradually 
moves  from  farms  or  rural  communities  to  giant  metropolitan  centers 
via  town  and  urban  clusters  of  increasing  size.^s    This  ever  structural 

^^Ibid.,  pp.  20-23. 

45  Weber  ("Industrielle  Standortslehre  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  74-84)  distinguishes 
two  stages  of  modem  capitalistic  development:  (1)  bound  (gebundene)  capitalism 
and  (2)  free  capitalism.  In  the  former,  which  characterizes  the  sixteenth  to  the 
eighteenth  centuries,  labor  is  historically  fixed,  locationally  immobile.  In  the 
latter,  which  characterizes  the  present  times,  labor  becomes  mobile,  released  from 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  41 

movement  within  the  labor  base  is  designated  as  one  of  the  essential 
dynamic  aspects  of  modern  space-economies.'* ^ 

With  respect  to  markets  for  capital  goods,  Weigmann  offers  a  few 
suggestions.  First  we  must  distinguish  capital  in  substance  from 
capital  in  title.  The  former  obviously  has  far  more  limited  mobility. 
Second,  capital  goods  (a  concept  which  in  its  broadest  formulation 
includes  all  commodities)  must  be  classified  according  to  the  extent 
to  which  they  become  bound  up  in  production.  At  one  end  of  the 
scale  would  be  "combination-free"  capital  goods;  at  the  other  end 
would  be  capital  goods  permanently  tied  to  a  given  production 
combination.  The  spatial  elasticities  and  markets  of  the  several 
divisions  of  capital  goods  would  vary  accordingly.  Unfortunately, 
present  day  terminology  regarding  capital  (e.g.,  fixed  and  circulating) 
is  unsuited  for  depicting  its  spatial  elasticity;  nor  has  theory  recog- 
nized the  influence  of  spatial  elasticity  upon  the  various  other  elasticity 
forms  of  capital. 

The  formulation  of  the  problem  of  a  theory  of  space-economy  thus 
is  more  comprehensive  than  that  of  traditional  location  theory.  The 
latter  has  chiefly  treated  capital  as  a  "combination  free"  factor  in  its 
long-run  agglomerative  setting  but  has  given  little  attention  to  the 
mobility  of  existing  equipment,  to  the  short-run  adaptability  of  capital 
goods.  In  fact,  for  an  empirical  theory,  there  are  even  strong  grounds 
for  considering  the  mobility  of  a  given  combination  of  various  produc- 
tive factors  as  a  whole,  rather  than  of  their  constituent  parts — a  phase 
of  the  problem  which  location  theory  has  rarely  posed. ^^  Furthermore, 
location  theory  has  frequently  been  of  restricted  scope  in  that  it  has 
often  sought  the  ideal  location  of  a  given  firm,  others  assumed  in 
equilibrium. 

Thus  Weigmann  sketches  his  picture  of  the  space-economy  as  a 
rhythmic-moving  Gestalt  whole  with  a  core  composed  of  the  markets 
for  land,  labor,  and  capital  goods  and  of  numerous  other  markets 
superimposed  upon  these,  overlapping  and  irregularly  intersecting 
each  other  and  at  times  extending  into  other  space-economies.^s    His 

its  historical  bonds.  The  economies  of  concentration  and  large-scale  organization 
can  come  into  operation  and  can  offer  incentives  for  huge  masses  of  labor  to 
agglomerate  at  given  points.  On  the  other  hand,  these  forces  are  offset  by  the 
community  attachments  (home  feeling)  of  the  individual  laborer,  by  his  lack  of 
perspective  and  initiative,  and  by  the  consequent  increase  in  rent  at  the  points 
of  agglomeration.    The  net  result  is  the  step-by-step  migration  already  mentioned. 

46"Ideen  zu  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  23-27. 

^Ubid.,  pp.  27-32. 

48  In  the  Thiinen  Festschrift  (op.  cit.)  Weigmann  commences  with  existing  loca- 
tion theory  (the  Englander  and  Predohl  versions)   and  approaches  a  theory  of 


42  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

presentation  lacks  clarity  and  frequently  one  is  forced  to  construe  an 
imaginary  model  in  order  to  follow  the  argument.  Nevertheless,  one 
obtains  penetrating  insight  into  the  subtle  spatial  relations  of  economic 
life  and  is  given  an  original  as  well  as  a  challenging  view  of  the 
immense  magnitude  of  the  assignment. 

5.     Palander's  Criticisms  and  Losch's  General  System 

In  Sect.  3  a  development  of  the  framework  of  a  general  (static) 
theory  of  location  and  space-economy  in  terms  of  the  substitution 
principle  has  been  suggested.  However,  it  has  been  customary  in 
general  equilibrium  analysis  to  present  the  relations  of  a  given  one- 
point  economic  order  by  means  of  a  system  of  mathematical  equations. 
Should  a  solution  for  this  system  of  equations  exist,  the  merit  of  the 
presentation  is  generally  regarded  as  considerably  enhanced.  Can  a 
solvable  system  of  equations  be  evolved  for  a  space-economy? 

Tord  Palander,  in  the  first  major  work  on  location  theory  to  originate 
outside  of  Germany,  addressed  himself  to  this  question. ^  9  He  con- 
sidered insuperable  the  difficulties  encountered  by  the  general  approach 
in  representing  or  even  closely  approximating  reality. 

First,  states  Palander,  writing  in  1935,  the  Walras-Pareto-Cassel 
general  equilibrium  theory  in  its  present  form  is  meaningful  for  a 
locational  analysis  only  of  an  economic  district  wherein  transport 
costs  are  zero,  capital  and  labor  perfectly  mobile,  and  technical 
conditions  of  production  uniform  throughout — in  other  words,  where 
the  district  in  question  can  be  compressed  into  a  point  market.  To  be 
sure,  he  continues,  a  somewhat  closer  approximation  to  reality  can 
be  obtained  by  withdrawing  one  by  one  the  simplifying  assumptions 
given  above.  For  example,  there  might  be  introduced  into  the  simpli- 
fied model  the  following  series  of  complications:  freight  costs  on 
product  based  on  distance  and  weight,  transport  costs  for  mobile  pro- 
duction factors,  equal  real  wages  throughout  the  district,  consumption 
as  dependent  upon  location  choice,  and  so  forth.  Even  so,  contends 
Palander,  this  procedure  would  not  take  us  far,  for  in  respects  other 
than  the  neglect  of  local  differences  in  demand  and  supply  of  factors 
and  commodities,  the  deviations  of  a  general  equilibrium  theory  from 

space-economy  ("total  localization")  in  part  through  the  extension  of  Predohl's 
substitution  principle  to  include  "quantity  elasticity."  Quantity  elasticity  is 
synonymous  with  a  broad  definition  of  elasticity  of  supply,  one  that  embraces, 
among  others,  spatial  elasticity.  In  this  way  Weigmann  brings  out  the  logical 
bond  of  location  theory  and  general  price  theory. 

'^^  Beitrdge  zur  Standortstheorie,  Almqvist  &  Wiksells  Boktryckeri-A.-B., 
Uppsala,  1935,  Chaps.  X  and  XI. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  43 

reality  are  severe.  Interdependence  theory  has  as  an  underlying 
premise  the  principle  of  pure  competition.  Yet,  in  no  sense  at  all, 
can  the  traditional  interpretation  of  this  premise  hold  when  we  intro- 
duce space  and  thus  transport  costs  into  the  analysis.  If  the  various 
places  in  a  region  under  consideration  are  treated  as  different  markets 
(corresponding  in  this  way  to  the  varying  local  prices  resulting  from 
transport  costs  between  these  places) ,  then  the  necessary  condition 
of  a  large  number  of  buyers  and  sellers  for  each  commodity  and  factor 
at  each  market,  cannot  be  fulfilled.  If  the  region  itself  is  viewed  as 
one  market,  one  could  interpret  the  different  prices  ruling  for  a  given 
commodity  at  the  various  places  within  the  region  (1)  as  signifying 
non-uniformity  of  product,  or  better  yet,  (2)  as  signifying  a  uniform 
product  in  a  persistently  imperfect  market  where  individuals  are  in 
monopoly  situations  in  accordance  with  the  advantages  of  their 
respective  positions.  Neither  case  could  be  regarded  as  pure 
competition.  5  0 

If  one  now  discards  the  premise  of  pure  competition,  he  must 
necessarily  forsake  certain  supplementary  simple  principles  which 
have  served  as  scaffolding  for  general  equilibrium  theory,  namely,  that 
the  price  of  a  commodity  equals  average  cost  (the  latter  including  a 
normal  profit)  and  that  the  price  of  a  factor  equals  the  value  of  its 
marginal  product,  ^i 

Further  censure  of  general  equilibrium  analysis  follows  from  its 
limitation  to  static  conditions,  a  widely  recognized  limitation  which 
does  not  need  to  be  discussed  here.^^  Palander  insists  on  the  necessity 
of  depicting  the  economic  development  process.  His  conscience  thus 
compels  him  to  forego  Walrasian  economics  in  favor  of  the  Launhardt- 
,  Weber  tradition.  His  energies  are  confined  to  analyzing  the  economic 
starting  point,  the  adaptations  of  enterprise  during  a  time  period,  the 
movement  of  factors  during  the  same  period,  and  the  concomitant 
changes  of  technique,  institutions,  and  consumer  base.  ^  3 

August  Losch,  however,  has  not  accepted  these  views.  In  his 
monumental  work,  Die  rdumliche  Ordnung  der  Wirtschaft,^^  he  goes 

50/6id.,  pp.  273-77. 
51- Ibid.,  pp.  277-78. 

52  However,  see  the  work  of  Samuelson  which  relates  the  comparative  statical 
behavior  of  a  general  equilibrium  system  to  its  dynamical  stability  properties 
{op.  cit.,  Part  II). 

53  Palander,  op.  cit.,  pp.  278-85. 

54  G.  Fischer,  Jena,  1st  ed.  1940,  2nd  ed.  1944.  All  page  references  are  to  the 
second  edition.  Part  of  the  material  of  this  book  is  available  in  English  in  the 
article  "The  Nature  of  Economic  Regions,"  Southern  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  V 
(July  1938),  pp.  71-78,  and  in  a  review  article  by  W.  F.  Stolper,  American  Eco- 


44  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

beyond  partial  analysis  and  the  mere  recognition  of  the  complex  spatial 
interrelations  of  economic  factors.  He  presents  succinctly,  through  a 
set  of  elementary  equations,  a  highly  simplified  static  model  of  a  space- 
economy  operating  under  conditions  of  monopolistic  competition.  To 
appreciate  fully  this  model,  one  must  understand  Losch's  concept  of  the 
market,  by  means  of  which  space  is  introduced  into  the  problem  and 
which  represents  his  other  major  contribution  to  location  theory. 
What  is  the  market  area?  How  is  it  bounded?  These  questions  are 
fundamental. 

Losch  postulates  the  following:  a  broad,  homogeneous  plain  with 
uniform  transport  features  in  all  directions  and  with  an  even  scatter 
of  industrial  raw  materials  in  sufficient  quantity  for  production;  a 
uniform  distribution  of  agricultural  population  with  a  uniform  set  of 
tastes  and  preferences,  each  homestead  at  the  start  being  self- 
sufiicient;  technical  knowledge  disseminated  throughout  the  plain  and 
production  opportunities  available  to  all.  In  all  other  respects,  too, 
extra-economic  forces  are  excluded.  If  in  this  situation  an  individual 
finds  it  profitable  (owing  to  the  economies  of  large-scale  production  as 
opposed  to  the  handicap  of  transport  cost)  to  produce  a  commodity 
over  and  above  the  needs  of  his  homestead,  his  market  area  would 
assume  a  circular  form.  However,  if  one  farmer  finds  it  profitable 
to  produce  over  and  above  his  needs,  so  will  others,  and  the  force  of 
competition,  by  eliminating  all  excess  profits,  not  only  will  contract 
the  market  area  of  the  original  producer  but  also  will  transform  the 
circular  shape  of  the  market  area  into  a  hexagon.  The  hexagon  is 
the  ideal  economic  form  of  market  area,  it  is  maintained.  Firstly,  a 
net  of  hexagonal  market  forms  will  exhaust  (completely  cover)  any 
area  under  consideration,  whereas  circular  ones  will  leave  empty 
unutilized  corners,  as  is  readily  seen  from  a  graphic  presentation. 
Secondly,  of  all  the  regular  polygons  (hexagon,  square,  and  triangle) 
which  will  exhaust  a  given  area,  the  hexagon  deviates  least  from  the 
circle  form  and,  in  consequence,  minimizes  the  transport  expenditures 
in  supplying  a  given  demand  or,  expressed  differently,  maximizes 
the  demand  of  the  population  of  a  given  area.^s 

For  each  commodity,  then,  the  plain  is  dissected  into  a  honeycomb 

nomic  Review,  Vol.  XXXIII  (September  1943),  pp.  626-36.  Also  see  Losch's 
article,  "Beitrage  zur  Standortstheorie,"  Schmollers  Jahrbuch,  Vol.  LXII  (1938), 
pp.  329-35. 

Since  the  writing  of  this  and  other  chapters,  Losch's  basic  work  has  become 
available  in  an  English  translation:  The  Economics  of  Location,  Yale  University- 
Press,  New  Haven,  1954. 

55  Die  rdumliche  Ordnung  .  .  .  ,  op.  cit.,  pp.  70-78. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  45 

(a  net  of  hexagons)  of  market  areas.  Losch  next  groups  these 
honeycombs  according  to  the  size  of  their  respective  market  units. 
And,  in  a  manner  consistent  with  the  estabUshed  criterion  of  minimum 
transport  effort,  he  orders  the  resulting  nets  about  a  common,  central 
production  point  to  obtain  his  system  of  nets.  ^  6 

We  are  now  in  a  position  to  reproduce  Losch's  attempt  at  a  general 
equilibrium  scheme.  At  the  start  Losch  attacks  the  problem  of  the 
location  of  the  production  of  industrial  goods  alone.  The  same 
hypotheses  which  were  basic  to  the  above  determination  of  market 
areas  are  retained  for  the  general  analysis.  Table  I  presents  the 
symbols  of  spatial  arrangement.  The  position  in  the  plain  of  each 
production  place  of  each  commodity  is  designated  by  a  set  of  x,  y 
co-ordinates;  the  boundary  of  the  market  area  of  each  production  place 
is  described  by  a  set  of  equations,  each  equation  being  represented  by 
a  corresponding  Greek  symbol  in  Table  I. 

Losch  puts  forth  the  following,  as  either  given  or  imknown: 

A.  Given: 

^m  ^  /'"(tt)     individual  demand  for  good  m 
TTg™  =  (f)"^{Dq)  the  factory  price       1  of  the  good  m  at  place  g  as  a 

I  function  of  the  total  demand 
j^m  =  x^iDq)  the  average  produc- 1  Dg'"  =  ^(J"",  x^y^,  a^i^^ 

tion  cost  J  ■  ■  ■  ^|^'^  ^1  ^9™  ■  ■  ■)• 

S>^  =  Dg™(7rg™  —  /c/O  the  profit  on  product  m  at  place  g 

0-  =  rural  population  per  square  kilometer 
a^  =  population  of  the  city  Pq"^ 
r  =  freight  rate 
m  =  number  of  products 
G  =  total  surface  area 

B,  To  be  sought: 


Number  of 

unknowns 

L 

TT,- 

=  factory  price  of  the  good  m  at 
location  Pq^ 

n 

2. 

Qm 

=  market  area  of  the  location  Pq"" 
in  square  kilometers 

n 

3. 

g- 

=  the  number  of  towns  which  pro- 
duce good  m 

m 

4. 

X^: 

.  2/r 

=  co-ordinates  of  the  location  Pq"^ 

2n 

5. 

«r 

,/3r-- 

•  •  €q"^  =  equations  of  the  boundaries  of 
the  market  area  of  Pg^ 

N 

Total:     ^n  +  m  +  N 

Corresponding  to  the  list  of  unknowns,  Losch  presents  in  Table  II 
a  set  of  equilibrium  conditions.     The  first  condition  for  equilibrium 

56 /bid.,  pp.  79-90. 


46 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Table  I.     Symbols  of  Spatial  Arrangement 


Prod- 

Production Places 

Market  Boundaries 

uct 

Num- 

Num- 

Abbreviations of 

Num- 

ber 

Position 

ber 

their  equations 

ber 

1 

Pi 

^{xi'yi');}H'---Va' 

a 

al^/3ll•••ell;a2^/32l•• 

A 

2 

Vi 

Hxihj,'^);P2'---pb' 

b 

«l^^l^•••r?l2;a2^/32^•• 

■       B 

ii"'(xi™yi'");  ^2" 


(total) 
A+B  +  --- 


m  (total)  n  (total)  N 

=  a  +  b  +  ---  +  q 

which  must  be  fulfilled  is  that  each  producer  occupy  a  spatial  position 
which  maximizes  his  profits;  as  a  result  he  will  not  find  it  desirable 
to  change  his  location  either  in  the  x  or  y  direction. 

Second,  the  whole  plain  under  consideration  must  be  exhausted  by  the 
various  market  areas  for  any  particular  good.  Third,  no  abnormal 
profit  may  exist;  the  cost  of  each  commodity  produced  at  any  factory 
must  equal  its  factory  price.  Fourth,  the  changes  in  average  price 
and  average  cost  ensuing  from  an  infinitesimal  change  in  the  size  of 
any  producer's  market  area  must  be  equal.  This  follows  from  the 
assumption  of  free  entry  into  any  fine  of  production  and  from 
the  negatively  sloping  demand  curve  confronting  each  producer.  In 
other  words,  a  Chamberlinian  tangency  solution  results  which  guaran- 
tees that  the  size  of  each  producer's  market  area  must  be  the  minimum 
economically  possible.  This  condition  together  with  the  second  and 
third  insures  a  maximum  number  of  independent  producers. 

The  fifth  condition  requires  that  any  consumer  on  any  boundary 
line  be  indifferent  as  to  the  possible  production  sources  from  which  he 
can  obtain  a  given  commodity  at  the  same  minimum  delivered  price. 

Since,  in  toto,  the  number  of  fulfilling  equations  of  Table  II  equals 
the  number  of  unknowns,  the  system  of  spatial  economy  is  determinate ; 
the  unknowns  can  be  derived. ^"^ 

^'^  Ibid.,  pp.  63-68.  Tables  I  and  II  and  the  lists  of  given  and  unknown  condi- 
tions are  for  the  most  part  literal  translations. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION 


47 


^ 


T3 

vli; 

II 

3 

+ 

^~ 

o 

Cb" 

Xi 

^ 

o 

II 

+ 

w 

o 

5S5 

s.  s 

Q 

H 

1 

+ 

g 

X 

*& 

8^ 

fl 

> 

S 

II 

'^ 

Cb 

'o 

o 

+ 

'^ 

f^ 

a 

^ 

II 

Q 

g 

1 

s 

OS 

5^ 
+ 

^^i 

S^ 

^ 

Cb* 

o 

s 

c^     ^ 

^ 

-0- 

^ 

^ 

f^ 

^ 

G 

c« 

73 

a:> 

i=l 

rS 

3 

O 

o 

6 

' ^ 

m 

M 

X! 

1 

2 

a 

a 

5:; 

a 

s 

3    c3 

o 

is 

c3 

Xi 

§ 

1 

X  '+-' 

'^ 

cS 

03 

11 

I 

o 

2 

^ 

l-H 

gJ90npojd 
JO 


48  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

In  a  manner  analogous  to  the  above,  states  Losch,  the  location  of 
the  production  of  agricultural  goods  can  be  analyzed.  In  a  similar 
manner,  too,  the  reverse  propositions,  which  concern  the  conditions  for 
the  best  location  of  industrial  and  agricultural  places  in  their  capacity 
as  consumption  centers,  can  be  attacked.  Unfortunately,  however, 
the  optimal  location  for  production  does  not  necessarily  coincide 
with  the  optimal  location  for  consumption;  and  Losch  fails  to  develop 
the  necessary  additional  sets  of  equations. 

This  is  the  way  in  which  Losch  spins  his  web  of  general  equilibrium.. 
Although  his  approach  minimizes  the  elements  of  interdependence  and 
does  not  comprehend  the  space-economy  as  a  whole  but  as  consisting 
of  several  major  sectors,  and,  although  it  has  other  severe  limitations, ^^ 
we  have  here  for  the  first  time  an  attempt  to  encompass  general  spatial 
relations  in  a  set  of  equations.  And  through  eschewing  the  assumption 
of  pure  competition  and  postulating  monopolistic  competition  in  its 
stead,  Losch  goes  far  toward  meeting  Palander's  objections  to  spatial 
general  equilibrium  analysis. 

One  need  not,  however,  proceed,  as  does  Losch,  in  deriving  a  set  of 
equations.  Losch  assigns  a  set  of  spatial  co-ordinates  to  each  producer 
and  consumer.  This  step  permits,  in  a  sense,  a  geographic  description 
of  a  space-economy.  But  his  presentation  would  become  exceedingly 
complex  if  one  were  to  relax  the  simple  uniformity  assumptions  which 
are  basic  to  his  model — if  one  were  to  allow  inequality  in  raw  material, 
labor,  and  capital  resources,  an  uneven  and  discontinuous  distribution 

58  Some  of  the  more  significant  criticisms  of  Losch's  scheme  may  be  noted : 

1.  Losch's  model  is  not  a  true  general  equilibrium  system  since  his  commodity 
and  factor  markets  are  not  interrelated  via  utility  and  production  functions  in  the 
complex  manner  which  tj^pifies  a  Walrasian  system.  E.g.,  the  model  is  based  on 
the  assumption  that  the  price  of  a  commodity  is  a  simple  function  of  its  demand, 
an  assumption  which  is  open  to  serious  objection. 

2.  A  simple  coimt  of  equations  and  unknowns  does  not  necessarily  prove  the 
existence  of  an  equilibrium. 

3.  His  treatment  of  boundarj^  equations  as  single  unknowns  is  also  subject  to 
major  criticism.  A  conception  of  a  continuous  field  of  price  gradients  would  be 
much  superior. 

4.  It  may  be  claimed  that  Losch's  model  has  both  too  many  unknowns  and  too 
many  equations.  If  conditions  are  assumed  which  lead  to  the  formation  of  a 
honeycomb  of  regular  hexagonal  market  areas  for  any  given  commodity,  then 
once  the  location  of  one  producer  of  that  commodity  is  fixed  and  once  the  equa- 
tion of  one  of  his  six  boundary  lines  is  known,  the  location  of  all  other  producers 
of  that  commodity  and  the  equation  of  all  other  boundary  lines  are  known  and 
determined. 

5.  His  system  is  built  implicitly  upon  an  hexagonal  net  of  market  areas  whose 
derivation  and  construction  involve  inconsistencies  some  of  which  will  be  noted 
later  in  this  book. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  49 

of  population,  and  all  other  types  of  local  differences.  To  introduce 
inequality  in  the  spatial  pattern  of  inputs  alone  is  a  very  difficult  task. 

From  a  functional  standpoint — one  that  is  relevant  to  the  incessant 
struggle  within  the  economy  as  a  whole,  as  well  as  within  its  various 
parts,  to  obtain  the  correct  set  of  substitution  points  with  respect  to 
inputs,  outputs,  outlays,  and  revenues — Losch's  model  is  anemic.  It  is 
much  more  meaningful  to  design  a  set  of  equations  depicting  general 
equilibrium  in  terms  of  input-output  relations  and  price-cost  relations, 
including  therein  transport  inputs  (and  if  possible  local  price-cost 
variations)  in  order  to  give  explicit  recognition  to  the  factor  of  space. 
This  latter  model,  constructed  without  reference  to  absolute  spatial 
co-ordinates,  would  be  much  more  able  to  cope  with  further  possible 
theoretical  developments,  for  example,  with  the  structural,  dynamic 
developments  visualized  by  Weigmann;  although,  to  be  sure,  any 
spatial  description  of  the  order  of  Losch  is  desirable  if  it  does  not 
impose  restrictions  upon  the  basic  operations  of  the  model. ^ 9 

With  respect  to  input-output  relations,  the  Leontief  technique,  within 
the  severe  limits  to  substitution  imposed  by  its  assumptions,  offers  a 
powerful  tool  of  analysis.  ^^  It  will  be  seen  in  a  second  volume  that 
one  can  give  an  increasing  amount  of  play  to  spatial  substitution 
operations  (1)  through  rearranging  the  activities  included  in  the 
structural  matrix  and  bill  of  goods  sector  in  order  to  incorporate 
locational  shifts  of  basic  industries  (and  the  associated  local  multiplier 
effects)  resulting  from  substitution  between  transport  inputs  and 
between  various  outlays  (including  transport  outlays)  and  revenues; 
(2)  through  detailing  interindustry  flow  tables  by  decomposing  the 
nation  into  regions  and  establishing  an  hierarchy  of  regions;  and  (3) 
through  introducing  resource  limitations  and  other  non-linearities  by 
employing  an  iterative  approach,  by  changing  relevant  coefficients,  and 
by  other  devices.  Such  a  modified  model  can  thus  reflect,  to  a  large 
extent,  the  interactivity  relationships  of  the  space-economy. 

Apropos  of  price-cost  relations,  it  cannot  be  too  strongly  emphasized 
that  the  theories  of  space-economy  and  of  monopolistic  competition 
(broadly  conceived^^)   are  inextricably  bound  together.     The  note- 

59  For  other  relevant  criticism  of  Losch,  see  W.  F.  Stolper,  op.  cit.  and  Hans 
Ritschl,  "Aufgabe  und  Methode  der  Standortslehre,"  WeltwirtschaftUches  Archiv, 
Vol.  LIII   (1941),  pp.  115-25. 

60  w,  "w.  Leontief,  The  Structure  of  American  Economy,  ] 919-1939,  New  York, 
1951;  and  W.  W.  Leontief  et  al..  Studies  in  the  Structure  of  the  American 
Economy,  New  York,  1953. 

61  To  include  oligopoly  with  or  without  product  differentiation.  See  E.  H. 
Chamberlin,  "Some  Final  Comments,"  The  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics, 
Vol.  XXXI  (May  1949),  pp.  123-4. 


50  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

worthy  contribution  of  Chamberlin  in  developing  techniques  for  spatial 
analysis  has  not  been  treated  specifically  since  it  has  been  largely 
digested  by  Losch  and  Palander.  Progress  along  Chamberlinian  lines, 
however,  is  a  sine  qua  non  for  developing  further  the  theory  of  the 
space-economy  in  its  welfare  aspects^s  which,  however,  are  beyond 
the  scope  of  this  book.  Triffin  has  already  built  upon  Chamberlin's 
structure,  setting  the  monopolistic  competition  techniques  in  a  general 
equilibrium  framework. 6  3  Triffin's  interdependence  analysis,  in  many 
places  explicitly  cloaked  in  substitution  terms,  is  not  unlike  Predohl's 
substitution  technique  (although,  to  be  sure,  Triffin  hardly  thinks  in 
terms  of  spatial  or  location  relations).  In  this  sense,  then,  a  gen- 
eralized theory  of  monopolistic  competition,  broadly  defined  and 
including  the  physical  production  (input- output)  problem  in  its  spatial 
setting,  can  be  conceived  as  synonymous  with  our  general  theory  of 
location  and  space-economy. 

6.     Ohlin's  View  of  Trade  and  Location  Theory 

One  final  matter  should  be  discussed,  namely,  the  interrelation  of 
trade  theory  and  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy. 
In  1911  Weber  pointed  out  that  classical  trade  theory  ignored  entirely 
the  transport  cost  involved  in  traversing  space.  ^  4  He  particularly 
criticized  the  classicists  for  overlooking  the  large  portion  of  inter- 
nationally distributed  industry  which  is  transport-oriented  and  which 
seeks  the  minimum  transport  cost  point  with  respect  to  raw  materials 
and  markets,  and  for  attributing  to  international  division  of  labor  and 
capital  the  international  distribution  of  transport-oriented  industry. 

Furlan,  Englander,  Ritschl,  Weigmann,  and  others  have  stressed 

62  For  most  situations  of  the  space-economy,  it  is  quite  meaningless  to  apply 
the  norms  of  pure  competition.  Also  see  Chamberlin,  Theory  of  Monopolistic 
Competition,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  3rd  ed.,  1938,  pp.  208-13. 

63  R.  Triffin,  Monopolistic  Competition  and  General  Equilibrium  Theory,  Cam- 
bridge, Mass.,  1940.  Although  the  monopolistic  competition  of  Chamberlin  seems 
to  be  more  than  a  particular  equilibrium  theory  (certainly  it  is  at  least  a  quite 
broad  particular  equilibrium  theory  for  it  embraces  the  problems  both  of  indi- 
vidual equilibrium  and  of  equilibrium  for  an  elastically  defined  group),  nonetheless 
it  is  not  a  general  equilibrium  theory  in  the  full  meaning  of  the  term  (see  Triffin, 
pp.  8-9,  54,  67,  and  elsewhere).  Triffin's  contribution  consists  of  extending  the 
scope  of  monopolistic  competition  to  encompass  the  complex  net  of  competitive 
interrelationships  throughout  the  entire  economic  collectivity.  In  doing  this, 
Triffin  discards  the  concepts  both  of  an  industry,  and  of  a  group  of  firms.  Rather, 
he  emphasizes  the  individual  firm  (or  more  strictly,  the  maximizing  unit)  and 
the  various  coefficients  of  interdependence  between  any  given  firm  and  each  of 
all  the  other  fiims  in  the  economy,  both  with  respect  to  factors  and  to  products. 

6-1  "Die  Standortslehre  und  die  Handelspolitik,"  Archiv  fur  Sozialwissenschaft 
und  Sozialpolitik,  Vol.  XXXII  (May  1911),  pp.  667-88. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION  51 

the  interrelation  of  trade  and  location  theories,  but  not  until  the 
appearance  of  Ohlin's  Interregional  and  International  Trade^^  do  we 
have  a  serious  attempt  to  integrate  the  two.  As  one  of  his  objectives 
Ohlin  purports: 

"to  demonstrate  that  the  theory  of  international  trade  is  only  part  of  a 
general  localization  theory,  wherein  the  space  aspects  of  pricing  are  taken 
into  full  account,  and  to  frame  certain  fundamentals  of  such  a  theory  as 
a  background  for  a  theory  of  international  trade,  wherein  the  influence  of 
local  differences  in  the  supply  of  factors  of  production  and  transportation 
costs  within  each  country  is  duly  considered." 6 6 

Ohlin  plants  his  objectives  within  the  framework  of  a  mutual- 
interdependence  theory  of  pricing,  the  latter  to  be  expanded  to  enfold 
the  multitude  of  markets  and  local  price  variations  which  ensue 
from  the  varying  spatial  immobilities  and  indivisibilities  of  goods  and 
factors.  Thus  his  general  localization  theory  would  determine  simul- 
taneously prices,  markets,  location  of  industry,  commerce  and 
agriculture,  spatial  distribution  of  factors  and  commodities,  and  other 
economic  magnitudes. 

It  would  seem  logical  that  Ohlin  should  first  develop  a  general 
localization  theory.  Then,  by  focusing  upon  certain  forms  of  immo- 
bilities of  factors  and  goods  (consideration  of  other  relations  set  aside 
for  the  time  being)  he  could  develop  at  length  his  theory  of  inter- 
regional and  international  trade  as  a  special  case.  Unfortunately, 
Ohlin  adopts  an  entirely  different  procedure  and  as  a  consequence  has 
to  employ  a  nearly  unique  casuistry.  Parts  I  and  II  of  his  book  are 
devoted  to  the  theory  of  interregional  trade  and  a  simplified  version 
of  international  trade,  respectively.  These  parts,  however,  are 
constructed  upon  an  unrealistic  set  of  hypotheses.  The  region  is 
defined  as  that  area  within  which  there  is  perfect  mobility  of  factors. 
Between  regions  factors  are  considered  perfectly  immobile.  And  all 
impediments  to  movement  of  commodities  are  assumed  away.  In 
Part  III  he  attempts  to  approach  reality  through  the  successive  intro- 
duction of  the  following:  (1)  interregional  costs  of  transfer  of 
commodities;  (2)  interregional  factor  movements;  (3)  interior  costs 
of  transfer  and  factor  movement;  (4)  local  differences  in  labor  and 
capital  supply.  The  inclusion  of  the  last  two  items  represents  an  effort 
to  subject  the  theory  of  interregional  trade  to  a  broadening  process 
and  thus  convert  it  into  a  general  localization  theory. 

65  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1933.  Some  of  his  other  relevant  works  are:  Handelns 
teon,  Stockholm,  1924,  and  "Some  Aspects  of  the  Theory  of  Rent:  von  Thiinen 
vs.  Ricardo,"  op.  cit. 

66  Op.  cit.,  p.  vii. 


52  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Ohlin  at  most  achieves  a  weak  (and  only  verbal)  general  localization 
theory.  He  does  not  attain  the  total  systematic  analysis  which 
characterizes  his  interregional  trade  theory.  His  treatment  of  loca- 
tional  forces  (Chaps.  X-XII,  inclusive)  is  quite  sketchy  and  flimsy. 
At  the  start,  a  modified  version  of  Thiinen's  isolated  state  is  applied 
to  industrial  production  within  a  district,  "the  frontiers  of  which  are 
not  described."  Ohlin  imagines  at  first  that  his  district  possesses 
"uniform  transport  features"  throughout  its  area  and  that  within  it 
the  factors  of  labor  and  capital  are  perfectly  mobile.  At  the  center  lies 
a  strategic  natural  resource,  perhaps  coal  or  iron  ore  deposits.  The 
surrounding  zones  of  cultivation  of  various  agricultural  products,  rent 
of  land,  and  prices  of  commodities  can  be  determined  only  through  a 
mutual-interdependence  system.  Next,  the  general  approach  on  the 
whole  is  abandoned  in  favor  of  a  step-by-step  analysis  commencing 
in  typical  Weberian  style.  The  localization  of  manufacturing,  of  raw 
material  production,  of  consumers'  markets,  local  differences  in  trans- 
port resources  and  facilities,  economies  of  large-scale  operation  and 
concentration,  local  differences  in  capital  and  labor  supply  are 
successively  considered.  In  the  end,  however,  Ohlin  returns  to  a 
general  interdependence  setting  in  depicting  the  relations  of  the  various 
economic  forces. 

This  singular  approach  has  turned  out  to  be  misleading  to  many. 
One  sympathetic  critic  maintains  that  Ohlin  does  not  successfully 
bridge  the  gap  between  interregional  trade  theory  and  general  localiza- 
tion theory,  and  thus  does  not  achieve  a  unified  theory ;  for  the  district 
whose  total  localization  is  supposed  to  be  explained  by  a  general  theory 
does  not  necessarily  have  to  possess  the  same  mobility  characteristics 
as  the  region,  which  is  the  unit  of  study  for  interregional  trade.  ^^  To 
the  extent  that  the  exposition  of  the  total  analysis  for  the  district  is 
deficient  (and  of  this  there  is  no  question),  the  gap  is  not  bridged,  but 
the  district  itself  can  be  conceived  as  boundless  or,  more  realistically, 
as  synonymous  with  the  world  (which  Ohlin  does  not  explicitly  do). 
A  satisfactory,  exhaustive,  total  analysis  for  the  district  would  then 
describe  all  economic  relations  within  the  world  and  explain  all  manner 
of  trade.     One  could  then  deduce  interregional  trade  analysis    (no 

67Tord  Palander,  op.  cit.,  pp.  266-67.  Elsewhere  (pp.  262-64)  Palander  sum- 
marizes Ohlin's  earlier  study,  Handelns  teori.  Here  an  attempt  is  made  to  extend 
interregional  trade  to  a  theory  of  interlocal  trade  (thus  accounting  for  local  differ- 
ences in  factor  supply)  through  subdividing  the  region  (within  which  perfect 
mobility  of  factors  reigns)  until  the  subregions  become  identical  with  the  locali- 
ties themselves.  Obviously  this  technique  is  inadeciuate;  it  assumes  away  the 
location  problem,  for  at  the  start  the  basis  of  interregional  trade  is  presumed  to 
be  the  different  relative '  scarcities  of  productive  factors  among  regions. 


SOME  GENERAL  THEORIES  OF  LOCATION      53 

matter  on  what  basis  the  region  and  subregions  are  delineated)  by 
singhng  out  from  among  the  complex  of  relations  those  of  relevance. ^8 
However,  it  is  not  necessary  at  all  to  view  trade  theory  as  narrowly 
as  Ohlin  does.  It  is  true  that  international  trade  theory  historically 
and  as  it  exists  in  such  standard  works  as  Viner's^^  and  Haberler's'^'o 
does  tend  to  correspond  to  Ohlin's  conception  of  it.  It  is  still  subject 
to  Weber's  criticism:  it  does  not  incorporate  transport-oriented 
industry  into  its  analytical  framework  and  is  thus  inadequate  for 
determining  policy.  Nonetheless,  one  can  view  trade  theory  and  the 
general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy  as  synonymous.  For 
(1)  location  cannot  be  explained  unless  at  the  same  time  trade  is 
accounted  for  and  (2)  trade  cannot  be  explained  without  the  simul- 
taneous determination  of  locations.  Once  we  recognize  this  it  is  futile 
to  argue  whether  trade  theory  is  or  is  not  a  special  form  of  general 
location  theory. ''^i  As  we  shall  see  later,  an  improved  location-trade 
doctrine  can  be  achieved  through  synthesis  of  the  better  elements  of 
existing  trade  and  location  theories. 

7.     Closing  Remarks 

In  summary,  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy  is 
conceived  as  embracing  the  total  spatial  array  of  economic  activities, 
with  attention  paid  to  the  geographic  distribution  of  inputs  and 
outputs  and  the  geographic  variations  in  prices  and  costs.  Modern 
general  equilibrium  theory  is  a  special  case  of  this  theory,  in  which 
transport  costs  are  taken  as  zero  and  all  inputs  and  outputs  are  viewed 
as  perfectly  mobile ;  international  trade  theory,  as  narrowly  conceived 
by  Ohlin,  is  also  a  special  case  of  this  theory.  One  proceeds  from  the 
latter  to  the  former  by  assuming  a  given  locational  structure  of 
economic  activities,  by  erecting  appropriate  barriers  within  the  world 
economy  to  correspond  to  the  boundaries  of  nations,  and  so  forth. 

68Losch  ("Beitrage  zur  Standortstheorie,"  op.  cit.,  p.  331)  has  also  charged 
Ohlin  with  lacking  a  clear  answer  to  the  location  problem  within  his  regions,  and 
with  a  failure  to  perceive  labor  distribution  as  a  result  of  economic  activity  be- 
tween men,  not  between  regions.  The  latter  accusation  falls,  however,  with  the 
definition  of  the  district  as  the  world,  or  as  an  area  greater  in  extent  than,  and 
inclusive  of,  the  region. 

On  the  other  hand,  one  may  perhaps  with  some  justification  raise  objections 
to  the  liberal  and  generous  interpretation  given  herein  to  Ohlin's  reasoning. 

^^  Studies  in  the  Theory  oj  International  Trade,  New  York,  1937. 

70  The  Theory  oj  International  Trade,  London,  1936. 

■^i  Thus  Viner's  cynical  remark  about  Ohlin's  dictum  that  the  theory  of  inter- 
national trade  is  nothing  but  international  location  theory  is  really  unnecessary 
and  indicates  either  Viner's  confusion  or  his  failure  to  appreciate  the  scope  of 
location  theory  (op.  cit.,  p.  468  note). 


54  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

However,  it  is  important  to  bear  in  mind  that  the  distinction  between 
trade  theory  and  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy 
is  one  of  definition  only.  Trade  theory  can  be  broadly  conceived  as 
synonymous  with  the  general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy. 
And  in  a  sense,  too,  because  of  the  monopoly  elements  which  are  almost 
invariably  present  in  spatial  relations,  a  broadly  defined  general  theory 
of  monopolistic  competition  can  be  conceived  as  identical  with  the 
general  theory  of  location  and  space-economy. 

The  substitution  principle  provides  one  of  the  best  analytical  tools 
for  developing  this  general  theory.  However,  Predohl's  use  of  this 
tool  must  be  modified  and  extended  to  embrace  various  substitution 
relations  between  transport  inputs,  and  between  various  types  of 
outlays  and  revenues.  The  formulation  of  these  relations  in  terms 
of  a  system  of  mathematical  equations  ought  first  to  embrace  the 
concept  of  transport  inputs  and  later,  if  possible,  Losch's  sets  of 
spatial  co-ordinates. 

The  evolutionary  approach  of  Weber  and  others,  and  especially  the 
writings  of  Weigmann,  who  conceives  the  space-economy  as  a 
rhythmic-moving  Gestalt  whole  with  a  basic  structural  core  of  land 
and  labor  markets,  should  be  very  helpful  in  suggesting  lines  along 
which  this  general  theory  may  be  nurtured  to  embody  dynamic 
relations. 


Chapte 


r3 


Some  Empirical  Regularities 
of  the  Space-Economy 


Before  the  development  of  appropriate  concepts  is  undertaken,  it 
is  pertinent  to  examine  some  of  the  currently  available  empirical 
material  and  observations  on  the  space-economy.  This  should 
establish  whether  or  not  there  are  in  fact  significant  regularities 
associated  with  variation  in  the  distance  factor.  If  there  are,  these 
empirical  regularities  should  furnish  a  valuable  background  against 
which  concepts  and  techniques  may  be  silhouetted.  Concomitantly 
they  should  afford  insights  into  the  ways  in  which  new  concepts  and 
techniques  should  be  fashioned.  A  comprehensive  canvass  and 
processing  of  available  material  is  not  intended,  since  this  is  beyond 
the  scope  of  the  book.  Rather  we  wish  to  benefit  from  what  a  prelim- 
inary and  cursory  examination  reveals. 

Historically,  the  empirical  rank-size  rule  for  cities,  noted  by 
Auerbach,  Lotka,  Gibrat,  Singer, i  and  others,  has  spurred  on  the  search 
for  related  empirical  regularities  over  space.  The  rank-size  rule  which 
is  claimed  to  have  widespread  validity  is  given  by  the  equation: 

(1)  r-P'^  =  K 

1  F.  Auerbach,  "Das  Gesetz  der  Bevolkerungskonzentration,"  Petermanns  Mit- 
teilungen,  Vol.  59  (February  1913),  pp.  74-76,  and  Chart  14;  A.  J.  Lotka,  Elements 
of  Physical  Biology,  Baltimore,  1925,  pp.  306-7;  R.  Gibrat,  Les  Inegalites  Eco- 
nomiques,  Paris,  1931,  pp.  250-52,  280;  H.  W.  Singer,  "The  'Courbe  des  Popula- 
tions.' A  Parallel  to  Pareto's  Law,"  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  XLVI  (June  1936), 
pp.  254r-63. 

55 


56 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


where  q  and  K  are  constants  for  the  given  group  of  cities,  r  stands  for 
the  rank  of  a  particular  city  in  population,  and  P  its  population.  For 
example,  according  to  the  1940  census  data  on  metropolitan  districts 
for  the  United  States,  in  which  instance  q  is  approximately  equal  to 


8000 


1930 
1920 

\VV^   ^1890 

1880 


•1870 
1860 


50    100 
Rank 

Fig.  2.  Communities  of  2500  or  more  inhabitants,  ranked  in  decreasing  order 
of  population  size.  U.  S.  A.  1790-1930.  (Source,  G.  K.  Zipf,  Human  Behavior 
and   the  Principle   of  Least   Ejfort,   Addison-Wesley,   Cambridge,   Mass.,   1949.) 


unity,  the  population  of  the  New  York  metropolitan  area  was 
11,690,520.  This  roughly  sets  the  value  for  K  since  the  New  York  area 
ranks  first.  And  in  line  with  the  rank-size  rule  the  Boston  metropolitan 
area  which  ranked  fifth  (r  =  5)  had  a  population  of  2,350,514,  approxi- 
mately one-fifth  of  K.    In  logarithmic  terms  the  above  equation  is: 

log  r  =  —q  log  P  +  C 

which,  just  as  does  the  equation  representing  Pareto's  "law"  of  income 
distribution,  yields  a  straight  line  on  double  logarithmic  paper. 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       57 

The  best  presentation  of  the  empirical  findings  on  rank  and  size 
of  cities  is  given  by  Zipf.2  In  Fig.  2  he  has  plotted  the  relevant 
decennial  data  for  the  United  States  over  the  period  1790-1930, 
logarithmic  scales  being  used  on  both  the  horizontal  and  vertical  axes.^ 
The  closest  approximation  to  a  linear  distribution,  as  is  implied  by 
Eq.  1,  seems  to  be  reached  in  year  1930.  The  distributions  for  earlier 
years  seem  to  diverge  increasingly  from  a  linear  form.  It  should  also 
be  noted  that  the  distributions  for  metropolitan  districts  of  the  United 
States  for  years  1940*  and  1950^  each  show  roughly  as  close  an 
approximation  to  a  straight  line  as  do  the  distributions  in  Fig.  2 
since  1900. 

How  much  validity  and  universality  should  be  attributed  to  this 
rank-size  rule  is,  at  this  stage,  a  matter  of  individual  opinion  and 
judgment. 6  However,  it  cannot  be  denied  that,  to  a  limited  extent  at 
least,  there  is  some  basis  for  the  formulation  of  hypotheses  and 
additional  exploration.  If  further  research  corroborates  the  belief  that 
these  and  other  distributions  exhibit  a  statistical  regularity  over 
various  time  periods  and  diverse  parts  of  the  world,  expectation  that 
there  are  regularities  associated  with  the  distance  variable  would  not 
be  unjustified.  For,  according  to  one  possible  line  of  reasoning,  modern 
cities  have  become  increasingly  centers  of  numerous  market-oriented 
activities,  each  activity  tending  to  have  a  defined  sales  area.  Since 
the  size  of  a  city  is  positively  associated  with  the  number  of  activities 
which  locate  within  it  and  since  economies  of  scale  and  other  factors 

2  G.  K.  Zipf,  National  Unity  and  Disunity,  The  Principia  Press,  Bloomington, 
Ind.,  1941;  and  Human  Behavior  and  the  Principle  of  Least  Effort,  Addison- 
Wesley  Press,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1949,  Chaps.  9  and  10. 

3  The  encircled  points  are  estimates  of  Zipf.  For  full  particulars  on  the  process- 
ing of  the  data,  see  National  Unity  and  Disunity,  pp.  41-43.  It  should  be  observed 
that  early  census  data  are  particularly  faulty. 

4  G.  K.  Zipf,  Human  Behavior  .  .  .  ,  op.  cit.,  p.  375. 

5  See  Figs.  1  and  2  in  Rutledge  Vining,  "A  Description  of  Certain  Spatial  Aspects 
of  an  Economic  System,"  Economic  Development  and  Cidtural  Change,  Vol.  Ill 
(January  1955),  pp.  147-195. 

6  See  the  interesting  statistical  analysis  in  G.  R.  Allen,  "The  'Courbe  des  Popula- 
tions': A  Further  Analysis,"  Bulletin  of  the  Oxford  University  Institute  of  Statis- 
tics, Vol.  16  (May  and  June  1954).  This  analysis  lends  considerable  support  to 
the  rank-size  rule. 

Additionally,  Zipf  has  plotted  relevant  rank-size  data  on  cities  for  Canada, 
1881-1931,  for  Germany,  1875-1939,  for  France,  1886-1936,  for  India,  1911  and  1921, 
and  for  other  areas.  In  general,  he  concludes  that  the  data  conform  to  a  rec- 
tilinear pattern  (logarithmic  scales).  However,  as  in  the  case  of  the  United 
States  in  1840  and  of  the  Austro-Hungarian  empire  in  1910,  the  conformity  is  not 
always  good;  this  fact  is  interpreted  by  Zipf  as  an  indication  of  some  inherent 
poUtical,  economic,  or  social  instability  within  the  system.  (Zipf,  Human 
Behavior  .  .  .  ,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  10.) 


58  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

preclude  the  presence  of  each  activity  in  each  city,  cities  of  different 
sizes  emerge.  Further,  one  can  expect  the  longer  (and  a  larger  volume 
of)  population  and  commodity  flows  to  be  generally  associated  with 
the  larger  cities  which  have  been  fortunate  in  usurping  those  functions 
wherein  economies  of  scale  are  marked  and  with  which  the  larger 
market  areas  are  linked.  Still  more,  economies  of  scale  have  varying 
significance  for  different  commodities  and  activities;  when  they  are 
most  dominant,  the  commodity  produced  (or  service  rendered)  tends 
to  be  national,  being  supplied  to  all  market  points  from  one  location. 
Hence,  that  city  which  captures  the  largest  amount  of  these  "national 
market  area  activities"  and  which  concomitantly  engages  in  all  other 
activities  whose  market  areas  are  of  lesser  geographic  scope  tends  to 
be  largest  in  size.  It  tends  to  be  a  terminal  point  of  the  longest 
average  population  and  commodity  flows  and  of  the  largest  volume  of 
such  flows,  ceteris  paribus.  And  that  city  which  captures  the  next 
largest  amount  of  these  national  activities,  while  at  the  same  time 
being  a  center  of  all  "non-national"  activities,  would  tend  to  be  second 
in  size  and  to  rank  second  in  average  length  (and  volume)  of  popula- 
tion and  commodity  flows,  ceteris  paribus.  And  in  like  fashion  the 
third,  fourth  .  .  .  nth  largest  city  would  tend  to  rank  third,  fourth  .  .  . 
nth.  in  average  length  (and  volume)  of  flows,  ceteris  paribus,  the 
progression  of  activities  from  those  with  national  markets  to  those  with 
major  regional  markets  to  those  with  minor  regional  markets  ...  to 
those  with  only  local  markets  being  duly  taken  into  account.'^  As  a 
consequence,  a  statistically  regular  hierarchy  of  average  length  and 
volume  of  flows  emerges.  Thus  regularity  of  flows  over  distance 
and  regularity  in  the  spatial  patterning  of  cities  can  come  to  be 
associated  with  a  statistically  regular  hierarchy  of  cities,  ceteris 
paribus.^ 

The  ceteris  paribus  clause,  however,  excludes  so  many  differentials 
(such  as  in  the  geographic  distribution  of  mineral  resources)  that  the 
above  argument  not  only  is  open  to  serious  qualification  but  even  may 
be  subject  to  major  restatement.    Nonetheless,  there  is  some  basis,  as 

'^For  development  of  this  classification  of  markets  see  A.  Losch,  Die  rdum- 
liche  Ordnung  der  Wirtschajt,  2nd  ed.,  G.  Fischer,  Jena,  1944,  pp.  70-79,  307-16; 
W.  Christaller,  Die  zentralen  Orte  in  Silddeutschland,  G.  Fischer,  Jena,  1935; 
E.  Ullman,  "A  Theory  of  Location  for  Cities,"  American  Journal  of  Sociology, 
Vol.  XLVI  (May  1941),  pp.  853-64;  and  W.  Isard,  "Some  Empirical  Results  and 
Problems  of  Regional  Input-Output  Analysis,"  in  W.  Leontief,  et  al.,  Studies  in 
the  Structure  of  the  Amencan  Economy,  New  York,  1953,  pp.  148-81. 

8 In  this  regard  also  see  E.  M.  Hoover,  "The  Concept  of  a  System  of  Cities: 
A  Comment  on  Rutledge  Vining's  Paper,"  Economic  Development  and  Cultural 
Change,  Vol.  Ill  (January  1955),  pp.  196-98. 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY 


59 


sapp  JO  jaqranj^ 


60  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Losch  would  maintain,  for  searching  for  statistical  regularities  of 
commodity  and  population  flows  over  distance  and  regularities  in  the 
spatial  patterning  of  cities — the  more  so  if  one  attributes,  as  Zipf 
does,  statistical  regularity  to  the  rank-size  findings  on  cities. 

Among  others,  Christaller  and  Losch  have  studied  the  spatial 
patterning  of  cities,  recognizing  the  numerous  resource  inequalities 
which  tend  to  distort  regularities  inherent  in  the  resistance  of  distance, 
per  se.  Figure  3  is  one  of  the  better  illustrations  of  spatial  regularity 
in  city  patterning.  The  data  which  it  presents  are  consistent  with 
the  reasoning  in  the  above  two  paragraphs  and  with  the  central  place 
theories  of  Christaller  and  Losch.  They  indicate  that  as  one  proceeds 
from  smaller  to  larger  class  sizes  of  cities,  the  distance  separating  cities 
of  like  class  size  increases,  although  with  considerable  variation  about 
any  average.  ^ 

Zipf,  as  have  many  others,  has  intuitively  associated  city  size  with 
market  area  complex.  He  has  searched  for  simple  rectilinear,  and 
presumably  stable,  interactions  over  distance,  although  the  logic 
connecting  his  statistical  findings  on  the  one  hand  and  his  Forces  of 
Unification  and  Diversification  and  principle  of  least  effort  on  the 
other  is  not  at  all  clear.  In  Figs.  4  to  7  some  of  his  findings  are 
presented. 

Figure  4  refers  to  railway-express  shipments  (less  than  carload  lots). 
Since  the  data  are  recorded  for  shipments  between  pairs  of  cities  with 
different  populations  and  since  there  is  a  presumption  that  tonnage  of 
shipment  will  vary  directly  with  the  number  of  originating  and 
terminating   units    (individuals),    Zipf    employs    a   Pi'P2    element. 

9  Christaller's  study  of  settlements  in  South  Germany  (op.  cit.),  most  of  which 
provide  services  (or  central  functions)  for  the  surrounding  population,  also  indi- 
cates that  settlements  of  a  typical  size  tend  to  be  spaced  regularly.  According  to 
his  interpretation  of  the  data,  not  only  do  the  populations  of  the  several  sizes  of 
tj^pical  settlements  tend  to  bear  a  regular  relation  to  each  other  but  also  the 
distances  separating  any  pair  of  settlements  of  hke  size  tend  to  increase  by  the 
Vs  as  one  proceeds  from  a  settlement  of  a  given  size  to  the  settlement  of  next 
higher  size.  Thus  market  hamlets  are  found  to  be  spaced  roughly  7  kilometers 
apart,  township  centers  12  kilometers,  county  seats  21  kilometers,  district  cities 
36  kilometers,  small  state  capitals  62  kilometers,  provincial  head  cities  108  kilo- 
meters, and  regional  capital  cities  186  kilometers.  For  a  full  theoretical  explana- 
tion of  Christaller's  findings,  see  Losch,  op.  cit.,  pp.  70-97;  and  for  an  objective 
evaluation,  see  Ullman,  op.  cit. 

Losch  has  accumulated  additional  empirical  evidence  on  settlement  patterns  as 
well  as  evidence  on  a  host  of  other  significant  relationships  involving  the  distance 
factor,  such  as  the  spatial  distributions  of  various  non-agricultural  activities,  the 
sizes  and  shapes  of  market  areas,  the  variations  of  prices,  wages,  and  interest  with 
distance  from  strategic  geographic  points  of  reference  or  over  space  or  both. 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       61 

(Pi  and  P2  represent  the  populations  of  any  given  pair  of  cities.) 
Accordingly,  weight  of  shipments  between  any  pair  of  cities  and  the 
corresponding  P1P2/D  factor  for  the  given  pair  of  cities  (times  1/10'^) 
are  plotted  in  Fig.  4,  where  D  represents  distance.     If  one  accepts 


10,000 

• 

/ 

oj  1»000 

- 

'O 

•   .        v^  • 

j3 

3 

•     *x 

0 

•                               yf 

\    .yfii^     •• 

0 

mX* 

^      100 

- 

^ 

•             /*• 

M 

x**<* 

s 

.• 

y*^ 

0 

r^  •  •    • 

^ 

y 

• 

10 
1 

/ 

1 

• 

1                        1 

1 

10 


100 

P1P2 


1,000 

1 

107 


10,000 


Fig.  4.  Railway  express.  Movement  by  weight  (less  than  carload  lots)  between 
13  arbitrary  cities  in  the  U.  S.  A.,  May  1939.  (Source:  G.  K.  Zipf,  Human 
Behavior    and    the    Principle    of    Least    Effort,    Addison-Wesley,    Cambridge, 

1949.) 


Zipf 's  Pi  •  P2  element,  then  the  linear  tendency  of  the  data  portrayed 
by  Fig.  4  indicates  a  definite  inverse  relationship  between  tonnage  of 
railway  express  and  distance,  as  is  indeed  demonstrated  by  other 
data.  10 

Figures  5  and  6  refer  respectively  to  telephone  messages  and  bus- 
passenger  movements.  Again  Zipf  introduces,  for  the  same  reason  as 
in  Fig.  4,  a  Pi  •  P2  element.  If  one  accepts  this  element,  the  charts 
indicate  that  the  numbers  of  both  telephone  messages  and  bus  pas- 


'  Zipf,  Human  Behavior 


op.  cit.,  p.  402,  Fig.  9-20(a). 


62 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


sengers  definitely  fall  off  in  linear  fashion  as  the  distance  between  any 
pair  of  cities  increases.  ^ 


• 

• 

100,000 

— 

10,000 

- 

• 

t  0  •. 

f 

1 

• « 

• 

•  • 

•    •    •        X 

s 

, 

•'.;>. .        / 

s 

.• . 

-.  ,          X 

^    1,000 

o 
u 

p 

100 

X  >  • 

•      *     X 

« i».  •*: 

» • 

••»  r-. 

• 

•  ,• 

*  .•• 

•  ,.  • 

10 

1 

1               1 

1 

10 


100 


1,000 


10,000 


P1P9 


i^^_l 


D 


107 


Fig.  5.    Telephone   messages.     Number  of   messages  interchanged  between  311 

arbitrary  pairs  of  cities  in  the  U.  S.  A.,  1940.     (The  hne  has  a  slope  of  1.00.) 

(Source:    G.    K.    Zipf,    Huvian   Behavior   and    the   Principle    oj   Least    Effort, 

Addison-Wesley,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1949.) 


11  That  number  of  messages  falls  off  with  distance  is  directly  depicted  in  Zipf, 
ibid.,  p.  402,  Fig.  9-20 (b). 

Among  others,  Zipf  presents  the  following  interesting  distributions  (although 
at  times  their  rectilinearity  is  questionable) :  on  railway  passengers,  airway  pas- 
sengers, and  the  P1P2/D  factor;  on  number  of  different  news  items  in  The 
Chicago  Tribune,  number  of  obituaries  in  The  New  York  Times,  average  cir- 
culation per  day  of  The  New  York  Times,  and  the  P1P2/D  factor;  on  charge 
accounts  of  Jordan  Marsh  Co.,  Boston,  in  96  cities  and  a,  PID  factor;  on  length 
and  number  of  one-way  trips  for  both  trucks  and  passenger  cars;  and  on  number 
of  marriage  licenses  issued  and  distance  separating  applicants.     For  full  details 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       63 

Figure  7  refers  to  some  limited  data  processed  by  Stouffer  on  internal 
migration  within  Cleveland.  ^^    These  data  as  they  are  chartered  by 


1,000,000 


100,000 


o 

en 

a 

^   1,000 

o 

Xi 


100 


10 


•       •  •    •• 


0.5    1 


10 


100 


1,000 

1 

107 


10,000     100,000 


Fig.  6.    Bus   passengers.     Movement   of   persons  by  highway   bus  between  29 

arbitrary  cities  in  the  U.  S.  A.  during  intervals  in  1933  and  1934.     (The  line  has 

a  slope  of  1.25.)     (Source:  G.  K.  Zipf,  Human  Behavior  and  the  Principle  oj 

Least  Effort,  Addison-Wesley,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1949.) 

Zipf   clearly  suggest  that  the  number  of   families  moving  between 
separated  areas  varies  inversely  with  distance,  and  in  general  the  data 


on  the  nature  of  his  samples  and  on  the  particular  points  of  time  to  which  they 
refer  see  Zipf,  Human  Behavior  .  .  .  ,  op.  cit.,  pp.  386-414. 

12  S.  A.  Stouffer,  "Intervening  Opportunities:  A  Theory  Relating  Mobility  and 
Distance,"  American  Sociological  Review,  Vol.  5  (December  1940),  pp.  845-67, 


64 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


10,000 


5,000 


2,000 


1,000 


500 


200 


100- 


J I     Mill 


LiT] 


5  10  20 

Distance  (thousands  of  feet) 


50 


Fig.  7.    Family   migration.     Number   of   families    (plus   100)    moving   varjdng 

distances  within  or  between  separated  areas  in  Cleveland,  1933-1935.     (Source: 

G.  K.  Zipf,  Human  Behavior  and  the  Principle  of  Least  Effort,  Addison-Wesley, 

Cambridge,  Mass.  1949.    Adapted  from  the  data  of  S.  A.  Stouffer.) 

are  consistent  with  the  reasoning  and  limited  empirical  findings  of 
Ravenstein^^  and  others. ^^ 

13  E.  G.  Ravenstein,  "The  Laws  of  Migration,"  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical 
Society,  Vol.  48  (June  1885),  pp.  167-227,  and  Vol.  52  (June  1889),  pp.  241-301. 

Ravenstein  was  perhaps  first  to  classify  migrants  in  terms  of  distance  spanned 
and  to  show  comprehensively  with  statistical  material  that  the  extent  of  migration 
into  a  given  center  of  absoi-ption  from  any  given  point,  in  general,  varies  inversely 
with  the  distance  separating  the  two. 

Stouffer  has  attempted  to  generalize  the  relationship  between  migration  and 
distance.  His  hypothesis  "assumes  that  there  is  no  necessary  relationship  between 
mobility  and  distance.  ...  It  proposes  that  the  number  of  persons  going  a  given 
distance  is  directly  proportional  to  the  number  of  opportunities  at  that  distance 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       65 

Stewart  has  also  been  inspired  to  search  for  empirical  regularities 
associated  with  the  distance  variable  in  connection  with  his  study 
of  social  physics.  15  Following  Newtonian  physics,  Stewart  has  for- 
mulated new  concepts  to  observe  vital  aspects  of  the  space-economy. 
Stewart  advances  the  thesis:  (1)  that  the  demographic  (gravitational) 
force  F  of  attraction  between  two  groups  of  Ni  and  A^2  average 
Americans  separated  by  r  distance  is  given  hy  F  =  Ni  N^/r^,  where 
F  acts  along  the  line  joining  the  two  groups ;i6  (2)  that  accordingly 
their  demographic  energy  by  virtue  of  this  force  field  is  given  by 
E  =  GNi  N2/r,  where  G  is  a  constant;   (3)  that  the  potential  which 

and  inversely  -proportional  to  the  number  oj  intervening  opportunities"  {op.  cit., 
p.  846). 

Mathematically  Ay/ As  =  aAx/xAs,  where  Ay  equals  the  number  of  persons 
moving  from  an  origin  to  a  circular  band  of  width  As;  x  equals  the  number  of 
intervening  opportunities,  i.e.,  the  cumulated  number  of  opportunities  between 
the  origin  and  distance  s;  and  Ax  equals  the  number  of  opportunities  within  the 
band  of  width  As.  Data  on  residential  mobility  in  Cleveland,  on  net  interstate 
migration  for  the  United  States  in  1930,  and  on  intercounty  migration  in  Sweden 
between  1921  and  1930  tend  to  substantiate  this  hypothesis,  an  hypothesis  which 
conceivably  can  be  further  generalized  to  cover  to  some  extent  movement  of 
commodities  as  well  as  persons.  See  also  M.  L.  Bright  and  D.  S.  Thomas,  "Inter- 
state Migration  and  Intervening  Opportunities,"  American  Sociological  Review, 
Vol.  6  (December  1941),  pp.  773-83;  and  E.  C.  Isbell,  "Internal  Migration  in 
Sweden  and  Intervening  Opportunities,"  A7nerican  Sociological  Review,  Vol.  9 
(December  1944),  pp.  627-39. 

14  See  Stuart  C.  Dodd,  "The  Interactance  Hypothesis:  A  Gravity  Model  Fitting 
Physical  Masses  and  Human  Groups,"  American  Sociological  Review,  Vol.  15 
(April  1950),  pp.  245-256.  For  a  very  interesting  set  of  empirical  tests  of  the  Zipf 
and  Stouffer  hypotheses  as  they  relate  to  migration,  refer  to  T.  R.  Anderson, 
"Intermetropolitan  Migration,"  American  Sociological  Review,  Vol.  20  (June 
1955),  pp. 287-91. 

1^  J.  Q.  Stewart,  "Empirical  Mathematical  Rules  Concerning  the  Distribution 
and  Equilibrium  of  Population,"  Geographical  Review,  Vol.  XXXVII  (July  1947), 
pp.  461-85;  "Demographic  Gravitation:  Evidence  and  Applications,"  Sociometry, 
Vol.  XI  (February-May  1948),  pp.  31-58;  "Potential  of  Population  and  its  Rela- 
tionship to  Marketing,"  Theory  in  Marketing,  ed.  by  R.  Cox  and  W.  Alderson, 
Chicago,  1950,  pp.  19-40;  "The  Development  of  Social  Physics,"  American  Journal 
of  Physics,  Vol.  18  (May  1950),  pp.  239-53;  and  other  studies  cited  in  these  four 
articles. 

1^  Stewart  reduces  the  gravitational  constant  to  unity  by  a  suitable  choice  of 
other  units.  The  molecular  mass  of  the  "average  American"  is  taken  as  unity, 
thus  permitting  this  simple  formulation.  Later,  Stewart  relaxes  this  assumption. 
The  reader  is  referred  to  any  standard  college  physics  textbook  for  explanation 
of  the  concepts  and  equations  used  in  this  paragraph. 

It  should  be  noted  that  Stewart's  concept  of  demographic  force  is  translatable 
into  Reilly's  law  of  retail  gravitation  (W.  J.  Reilly,  "Methods  for  the  Study  of 
Retail  Relationships,"  University  oj  Texas  Bulletin,  No.  2944,  November  1929). 


66  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

the  group  of  A^i  individuals  produces  at  the  point  where  the  second 
group  is  located  is  given  by  V2  =  GNi/r;  and  (4)  that  the  potential 
at  any  point  produced  by  the  entire  population  of  any  given  terrain  is 

given  by  y  =    /  -  DdS,  where  D  is  the  density  of  population  over 

the  infinitesimal  element  of  area  dS,  the  integration  being  extended 
to  all  areas  of  the  plane  where  D  is  not  zero.  The  potential  at  any 
point,  according  to  Stewart,  may  also  be  taken  as  an  inverted  measure 
of  the  proximity  of  the  point  to  people  in  general,  i''' 

Stewart  has  computed  population  potentials  for  various  areas  of  the 
world  for  different  periods  of  time.  1  ^  Since  population  is  reported  not 
for  infinitesimal  elements  of  area  but  rather  for  comparatively  large 
units  of  area,  only  approximations  to  potentials  can  be  achieved.  In 
Fig.  8  are  depicted  equipotential  contour  lines  for  the  United  States 
in  1940.19  It  is  extremely  interesting  to  observe  that  east  of  the 
Sierras  there  is,  in  all  directions,  a  continuous  fall  in  potential  with 
increase  in  distance  from  New  York  City,  the  major  peak  of  the 
country,  except  that  all  other  cities  are  local  peaks  on  the  general 
downhill  slope. 20 

Working  with  approximate  averages  of  potential  for  rural  areas  in 
a  sequence  of  28  states  from  Texas  to  Maine^i  and  using  double  log 

1'^  "Demographic  Gravitation  .  .  .,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  32-36. 

18  See  "Empirical  Mathematical  Rules  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  476-79;  "Potential  of 
Population  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  p.  22;  and  "The  Development  of  Social  Physics,"  op.  cit., 
p.  250. 

19  "Potential  of  Population  .  .  .,"  op.  cit.,  p.  22.  In  this  article  Stewart  does  not 
indicate  the  number  of  areas  in  which  he  divided  the  United  States.  Obviously 
the  larger  the  number  of  areas,  and  hence  control  points,  the  more  precise  the 
computed  potentials,  and  the  more  likely  that  local  peaks  corresponding  to  cities 
will  appear.  See  "Empirical  Mathematical  Rules  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  473-82,  for  a 
discussion  of  some  of  the  problems  in  computing  potentials. 

In  the  construction  of  Fig.  8,  Stewart  weighted  population  in  the  Deep  South 
by  a  factor  of  0.8;  in  the  main  sequence  of  28  states  from  Maine  to  Texas  by 
unity;  and  in  the  Far  West  by  2.  For  his  reasoning  on  this  step,  see  "Potential 
of  Population  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  29-30.  However,  it  should  be  noted  that  if 
population  is  unweighted,  a  similar  contour  map  results  except  that  the  potentials 
in  the  Far  West  are  of  considerably  smaller  value.  See  his  "unweighted"  map  in 
"Concerning  Social  Physics,"  Scientific  American,  Vol.  178  (May  1948),  p.  22. 

20  This  statement,  of  course,  might  require  quahfication  if  a  finer-grained  map 
were  constructed.  Nonetheless,  the  resulting  configuration  of  contours  and  its 
relation  to  the  distance  variable  would  still  be  impressive.  And  it  is  very  likely 
that  all  of  the  contour  lines  in  non-urban  parts  would  close  around  New  York  City. 

According  to  Stewart,  the  major  structure  of  United  States'  potentials  has  not 
altered  much  since  1840  when  New  York  City  was  already  the  principal  peak. 

21  Observations  are  confined  to  these  28  states  because  these  states  exhibit  a  con- 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY 


67 


68  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

paper,  Stewart  claims  to  obtain  fairly  good  linear  relations  by  plotting 
the  data  on  potential  for  these  areas  against  the  data  on  each  of  the 
following:  (1)  density  of  rural  population;  (2)  density  of  rural  non- 
farm  population;  (3)  rents  of  rural  non-farm  dwelling  units;  (4)  value 
of  farmland  per  acre;  (5)  rural  road  mileage  per  square  mile;  and 
(6)  railroad  mileage  per  square  mile.  In  each  case,  as  potential  rises 
from  area  to  area  (the  potential,  in  essence,  measures  the  influence 
upon  any  particular  area  of  people  at  a  distance) ,  each  of  these  items 
tends  to  increase.  Other  still  more  interesting  associations  which 
Stewart  notes  and  judges  to  be  linear  (logarithmic  scales)  are  those: 
(1)  between  potential  and  number  of  wage-earners  in  manufacturing 
for  253  rural  counties ;22  (2)  between  demographic  energy  (a  concept 
related  to  distance)  and  income  for  various  states  (a)  in  the  main 
sequence  of  28  states,  (b)  in  11  western  states,  and  (c)  in  9  southern 
states;  and  (3)  between  potential  produced  at  New  York  City  by  the 
populations  of  various  branch  Federal  Reserve  districts  and  the  daily 
flow  of  bank  checks  for  October  1948,  into  New  York  City  from  these 
districts  when  grouped  according  to  the  above  three  classes  of  states. 2  3 
Human  ecologists — McKenzie,24  Hawley,25  Bogue,26  and  others — 
have  also  closely  studied  spatial  phenomena  and  the  impact  of  distance 
upon  the  interrelations  of  human  beings  in  adapting  to  environment. 
Of  these,  Bogue  has  most  explicitly  considered  the  distance  variable 
within  the  framework  of  metropolitan  regional  analysis.  Figure  9 
depicts  some  of  his  summary  findings  in  a  forceful  manner.  As  Bogue 
has  neatly  stated: 

"On  the  average,  as  the  distance  from  the  metropolis  increases,  the  number 
of  persons  per  square  mile  of  land  decreases.  With  increasing  distance, 
each  square  mile  of  land  area  supports  steadily  decreasing  average  amounts 
of  retail  trade,  services,  wholesale  trade,  and  manufacturing  activities. 
This  finding  is  noteworthy  for  the  following  reasons:  first,  it  is  a  statement 
of  a  set  of  conditions  which  applies  to  the  entire  land  area  of  the  United 
States.  .  .  . 

siderable  degree  of  statistical  homogeneity,  a  homogeneity  which  has  already  been 
noted  to  be  different  from  that  of  the  11  western  states  and  from  that  of  the  9 
southern  states. 

22  Stewart  uses  counties  (in  the  main  sequence  of  28  states)  which  contain  zero 
or  only  relatively  small  urban  populations  in  order  to  avoid  the  local  distortion 
of  potentials  that  is  produced  by  the  influence  of  nearby  cities. 

23  "Demographic  Gravitation  .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  39-51 ;  and  "Potential  of  Popu- 
lation .  .  .  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  27-30 

24  R.  D.  McKenzie,  The  Metropolitan  Community,  New  York,  1933. 

25  A.  H.  Hawley,  Human  Ecology,  New  York,  1950. 

26  D.  J.  Bogue,  The  Structure  of  the  Metropolitan  Community,  University  of 
Michigan,  Ann  Arbor,  1949.  " 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       69 


10  25  50  100  200  500 

Distance  from  the  nearest  metropolis  (miles) 

Fig.  9.    Population    per    square    mile    and    dollar   value    of    selected   sustenance 

activities  per  1/100  sq  mile  of  hinterland,  by  distance  outward  from  the  nearest 

metropolis:  for  67  metropoUtan  communities  in  the  U.  S.  A.,  1939-1940. 


70  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

"Second,  the  distance  pattern  encompasses  the  entire  area  which  has  been 
called  the  'hinterland.'  The  effect  of  distance  from  the  metropolis  does  not 
cease  to  exist  at  the  suburb,  but  continues  throughout  all  distances.  .  .  . 

"Third,  the  distance  patterns  for  the  suburban  and  for  the  most  distant 
zones  are  shown  here  to  be  only  different  aspects  of  the  same  phenom- 
enon. There  is  a  fairly  constant  rate  of  change  between  relative  decreases 
in  land  occupancy  and  relative  increases  in  distance."2  7 

It  should  also  be  noted  that  in  general  these  regularities  with  distance 
hold  for  each  size  class  of  metropolitan  region,  though  with  different 
rates  of  change.  Likewise,  on  a  per  capita  basis,  retail  sales,  receipts 
from  services,  wholesale  sales,  and  value  added  by  manufacture  each 
manifests  a  fairly  regular  pattern  with  distance  from  the  nearest 
metropolis,  for  all  metropolitan  regions,  for  metropolitan  regions 
broken  down  by  size  classes,  and  for  various  types  of  sectors  of 
metropolitan  regions.  In  addition  Bogue  finds  many  other  related 
regularities  with  distance.  2  8 

To  complete  this  brief  survey  of  empirical  material,  we  wish  to 
re-examine  more  carefully  data  on  tonnage  of  commodity  flows  over 
distance,  both  on  an  intranational  and  international  basis.  Fortu- 
nately, data  for  the  United  States  have  recently  become  available, 
recording  for  each  of  261  I.C.C.  commodity  classes  and  for  each  of 
five  consolidated  groups  of  these  classes  state-to-state  Class  I  railroad 
shipments  as  well  as  the  average  short-line  haul  per  ton  (in  miles)  for 
commodities  in  each  class.  These  data  are  probably  the  most  compre- 
hensive commodity-flow  data  currently  available.  ^  9 

As  is  to  be  expected,  the  friction  of  distance  is  of  different  signifi- 
cance for  the  diverse  commodities.  Certain  flows,  such  as  those  of 
cement,  are  extremely  sensitive  to  the  distance  variable;  others,  such 
as  those  of  oranges  and  grapefruit,  extremely  insensitive.  For  our 
purposes,  it  is  sufficient  to  chart  the  data  on  total  commodity  flows. 
Doing  this  tends  to  average  out  the  particular  sets  of  resource,  market, 
transport  rate,  and  other  relations  peculiar  to  any  given  commodity 
flow  and  to  isolate  more  effectively  the  general  impact  of  the  distance 
variable. 

2''' Bogue,  op.  cit.,  p.  31. 

28  Also,  see  the  supporting  material  in  C.  Clark  "Urban  Population  Densities," 
Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  Vol.  CXIV,  Part  IV  (1951),  pp.  490-96, 

-9  The  I.C.C.  data  are  derived  from  a  continuous  representative  1  per  cent 
sample  of  the  carload  waybill  terminations  of  Class  I  railroads  only.  For  our 
purposes  the  data  can  be  used  with  confidence.  Errors  from  omissions  because 
of  the  disclosure  rule,  from  rebilling,  from  double  billing  of  rail- water-rail  move- 
ments, etc.  are  minor.  For  full  details  on  shortcomings  of  the  sample  see  the 
introductory  note  of  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Carload  Waybill  Analyses, 
1949,  Washington,  D.C.,  1950-1951. 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       71 

In  Figs.  10  and  11  are  plotted  the  data  on  tonnage  of  total  com- 
modities moving  over  various  distances,  by  25-mile  zones  and  100-mile 
zones  respectively.  ^0    The  impact  of  the  distance  variable  is  unques- 


400   600  800  1200 

Distance  (miles) 


1600 


2000 


Fig.  10. 


U.  S.  A.  Class  I  railroad  shipments.     Tonnage  of  all  commodities,  by- 
distance  shipped  (25-mile  zones),  1949.    Bar  chart. 


tioned,  whether  the  data  are  recorded  by  25-mile  zones,  or  by  the 
larger  100-mile  zones  in  order  to  smooth  out  some  of  the  irregular- 

30  The  assistance  of  Mr.  Merton  J.  Peck  in  preparing  the  data  for  Figs.  10-14 
is  gratefully  acknowledged. 

The  reader  is  also  referred  to  the  excellent  set  of  charts,  independently  derived, 
in  Vining  op.  cit.,  and  in  R.  Vining,  "Delimitation  of  Economic  Areas:  Statistical 
Conceptions  in  the  Study  of  the  Spatial  Structure  of  an  Economic  System," 
Journal  of  the  American  Statistical  Association,  Vol.  48  (March  1953),  pp.  44-64; 
and  to  Edward  L.  UUman,  Maps  of  State-to-State  Freight  Movement  for  13  States 
of  the  United  States  in  1948,  mimeographed. 


72 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


ities.31  Also,  to  examine  whether  or  not  any  linear  relation  is  present, 
using  double  log  paper,  the  data  for  the  mile  zones  lying  between  75 
and  1400  miles  are  graphed  as  a  set  of  points  in  Fig.  12.32    A  straight 


3500  f- 


3000 


2500 


2000 


1500 


1000 


500 


800 


1200  1600  2000 
Distance  (miles) 


2400  2800  3200 


Fig.  11. 


U.  S.  A.  Class  I  railroad  shipments.     Tonnage  of  all  commodities,  by- 
distance  shipped   (100-mile  zones),  1949.     Bar  chart. 


31  Also  it  is  interesting  to  note  that  each  of  the  four  significant  I.C.C.  major 
groups  of  commodities — products  of  forests,  products  of  agriculture,  products  of 
mines,  and  manufactures  and  miscellaneous — show  shipments  falling  off  fairly 
regularly  with  distance,  though  less  regularly  than  the  aggregate  for  all  commodi- 
ties. Shipments  of  products  of  mines  fall  off  most  precipitously;  those  of  products 
of  agriculture  least.  Shipments  of  the  fifth,  and  by  far  the  least  significant  of  the 
I.C.C.  major  groups,  namely,  animals  and  products,  evidence  no  real  tendency  to 
fall  off  with  distance. 

32  In  Fig.  12  the  tonnage  data  for  the  extreme  zones  are  not  plotted.  For  the 
zones  falling  between  0  and  75  miles  they  have  little  significance  since  rail  transport 
over  relatively  short  distances  is  infeasible  for  so  many  commodities.  For  zones 
falling  beyond  1400  miles,  the  tonnage  of  shipments  is  very  small  and  the  data  not 
only  become  less  reliable  but  also  reflect  shipments  of  commodities  under  special 
conditions.  However,  the  reader  may  still  care  to  plot  the  data  for  the  extreme 
zones  (see  Fig.  10). 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY        73 

line  has  been  drawn  in  freehand.    A  priori,  the  data  seem  to  conform 
well  to  a  linear  pattern. 

On  an  international  level,  there  is,  unfortunately,  a  paucity  of  com- 
prehensive physical  shipment  data.    However,  one  set  of  reliable  and 


3000 
2000 

1000 


500 


200 


o  100 


50 
40 
30 


20 


10  k 


J L 


70   100 


200   300  400  500 
Distance  (miles) 


1000     1500 


Fig.  12.    U.  S.  A.  Class  I  railroad  shipments.    Tonnage  of  all  commodities,  by 
distance  shipped  (25-miIe  zones),  1949.     Point  chart. 


relevant  data  has  been  developed  during  the  1920's  by  the  German 
National  Bureau  of  Statistics.  ^^  The  world  is  divided  into  23  areas 
and  the  total  flow  of  goods  via  water  in  tons  from  any  given  area  to 
itself  and  each  of  the  other  22  is  indicated  for  years  1913,  1924,  and 

33  "Der  GUterverkehr  der  Weltschiffahrt,"  Vierteljahrshefte  zur  Statistik  des 
Deutschen  Reichs,  Erganzungsheft  zu  Heft  1928,  I,  vom  Statistichen  Reichsamt, 
Berlin,  1928.  For  sources  and  adequacy  of  data,  see  the  first  page  of  this  mono- 
graph. 


74 


LOCATION  AKD  SPACE-ECONOMY 


1925.  Upon  the  data  for  1925,  Figs.  13  and  14  are  based;  in  these  the 
distance  between  any  two  areas  is  taken  as  the  distance  between  the 
two  ports,  each  of  which  was  the  most  important  port  in  its  area  in 
1925.3^ 


50 


40 


Q  30 


G 

i  20 


10 


"^L^^-T- 


0     2,500    5,000    7,500   10,000   12,500 
Distance  (miles) 

Fig.  13.    World   ocean-going  freight.     Tonnage,  by   distance  shipped    (500-mile 
zones),  1925. 


34 The  23  areas  and  the  corresponding  ports  of  origin  and  destination  are: 
Baltic  countries  and  Scandinavia  (Stockholm) ;  Germanj^  (Hamburg) ;  Great 
Britain  and  Ireland  (London);  Holland  and  Belgium  (AntAverp);  France  (Cher- 
bourg, and  for  trade  through  the  ^Mediterranean,  Marseilles) ;  Spain  and  Portugal 
(Lisbon) ;  Italy  (Genoa) ;  Eastern  Mediterranean  countries  and  Turkey  (Alex- 
andria) ;  countries  on  the  Black  Sea  (Odessa) ;  North  Africa  excluding  Egj-pt 
(Algiers) :  West  Africa  (Lagos) ;  South  Africa  (Durban) ;  East  Africa  (Zanzibar)  ; 
Arabia,  Persia,  and  British  India  (Bombay) ;  Indo-China,  the  East  Indies,  and 
the  Philippines  (Singapore) ;  Eastern  Asia  including  Asiatic  Russia  (Yokohama) ; 
Austraha,  New  Zealand,  and  Oceania  (Sydney) ;  West  Coast  of  Canada  and  the 
United  States  (San  Francisco) ;  East  Coast  of  Canada  and  the  United  States 
(New  York) ;  Mexico,  Central  America,  and  West  Indies  (Havana) ;  Brazil  and 


140 


120 


ai  100 


CM      80 

o 

g     60 


S     40 


20 


EMPIRICAL  REGULARITIES  OF  SPACE-ECONOMY       75 

Once  again  the  significance  of  the  distance  variable  is  demon- 
strated, ^s  This  is  so  whether  one  observes  the  configuration  by  the 
500-mile  zones  of  Fig.  13  or 
the  more  regular  configura- 
tion by  2000-mile  zones  of 
Fig.  14.  The  latter,  based 
upon  more  aggregative  data, 
tends  to  conceal  the  signifi- 
cance for  international  trade 
of  the  uneven  world  pat- 
tern of  resources  and  of  the 
particular  cultural  and  polit- 
ical institutions  which  have 
evolved  in  the  individual 
nations  participating  in  in- 
ternational trade.  3  6 

In  conclusion,  it  must  be 
recognized  that  significant 
regularities  are  associated 
with  variation  in  the  distance 
factor.  However,  considera- 
ble caution  and  circumspec- 
tion must  be  exercised  in 
attributing  significance  to  particular  sets  of  data  and  related  findings 
which  have  been  presented  here  and  elsewhere.    In  a  number  of  cases 

Northern  South  America  (Rio  de  Janeiro) ;  remainder  of  the  East  Coast  of  South 
America  (Buenos  Aires);  and  West  Coast  of  South  America  (Antofagasta). 

In  selecting  the  chief  port  in  each  area  and  in  deriving  the  distances  between 
ports  the  author  had  to  use  his  best  judgment  in  several  instances.  Other  indi- 
viduals may  have  made  different  choices.  Also,  inaccuracy  creeps  in  because  not 
all  traffic  moves  by  the  shortest  navigable  routes  as  is  assumed  here.  But  adjust- 
ment for  these  factors  would  affect  Figs.  13  and  14  only  in  a  minor  way. 

A  more  serious  shortcoming  is  that  international  trade  within  any  given  area 
was  excluded  because  we  had  no  knowledge  of  the  distances  over  which  such 
trade  moved.  As  a  result  the  volume  of  shipment  over  distances  falling  within 
the  smaller  distance  zones  is  considerably  underestimated  in  Figs.  13  and  14. 

Shortest  navigable  distances  between  ports  in  nautical  miles  were  obtained  or 
estimated  from  U.S.  Navy  Department,  Hydrographic  Office,  Table  of  Distances 
Between  Ports,  Washington,  D.C.,  1942. 

35  Also  see  Losch,  op.  cit.,  pp.  305-07. 

36  The  manner  in  which  the  data  are  aggregated,  of  course,  influences  the 
smoothness  with  which  tonnage  falls  off  with  distance  when  the  aggregated  data 
are  charted.  When  the  data  are  aggregated  by  1500-mile  zones,  tonnage  for  the 
second  zone  is  considerably  less  than  for  the  third.  However,  by  2500-  and  3000- 
mile  zones,  the  "falling-off-effect"  is  regular  as  it  is  by  2000-mile  zones. 


0     2     4      6      8     10    12  14 
Distance  (thousands  of  miles) 

Fig.  14.     World  ocean-going  freight.     Ton- 
nage, by  distance  shipped  (2000-mile  zones), 
1925. 


76  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

the  data  are  inadequate;  and  the  statistical  processing  and  techniques 
are  suspect  or  deficient  or  both.  Nonetheless,  after  an  over-all  view 
of  the  empirical  material,  it  is  undeniable  that  the  friction  of  distance 
manifests  itself  in  a  number  of  important  ways  and  markedly  condi- 
tions the  structure  and  functioning  of  critical  sectors  of  the  social 
system.  The  impact  of  transport,  both  direct  and  indirect,  is  crucial. 
In  at  least  certain  major  analyses  of  the  economy  the  spatial  frame- 
work cannot  be  ignored. 


Chapter 


4 


Transport  Inputs  and 
Related  Spatial  Concepts 


1.     General  Introductory  Remarks 

Having  presented  some  of  the  more  important  statistical  findings  on 
spatial  relations  and  having  established  that  there  are  significant  regu- 
larities associated  with  variation  in  the  distance  factor,  we  are  now 
in  a  position  to  develop  appropriate  concepts  for  theoretical  analysis. 
This  is  not  to  deny  the  usefulness  of  the  approach  of  the  astron- 
omer Stewart  who  advocates  the  methods  of  Tycho  Brahe  and  Kepler, 
namely,  accumulating  extensive  observations  and  condensing  the  volu- 
minous data  into  concise  empirical  rules  before 'formulating  a  general 
theory.  Such  has  been  the  point  of  departure,  in  business  cycle  analy- 
sis, of  the  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research.  Nonetheless,  it 
is  also  valuable  at  this  stage,  given  the  extensive  material  already 
amassed,  to  formulate  operational  and  functional  concepts  for  a  general 
theory  of  space-economy  which  could  facilitate  systematic  and  large- 
scale  observation  and  possibly  abet  the  extraction  of  more  empirical 
rules  from  the  data.i 

As  before  we  must  recognize  the  obvious  fact  that  economic  activity 
takes  place  in  a  time-space  continuum.    In  general,  to  minimize  effort 

1  For  a  thorough  discussion  of  tlie  methodological  issues  involved  see  T.  C. 
Koopmans,  "Measurement  without  Theory,"  Review  of  Economic  Statistics,  Vol. 
XXIX  (August  1947),  pp.  161-72;  and  R.  Vining  and  T.  C.  Koopmans,  "Method- 
ological Issues  in  Quantitative  Economics,"  idem,  Vol.  XXXI  (May  1949),  pp. 
77-94. 

77 


78  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

or  factor  services  in  producing  a  given  social  output  or  to  maximize 
social  output  with  a  given  amount  of  effort  and  factor  services,  is  not 
to  choose  a  path  of  action  with  respect  to  the  time  axis  alone,  or  to  the 
space  axis  alone,  but  rather  with  respect  to  both  axes. 

Aside  from  personal  preferences  and  acquired  interpersonal  behavior 
forms,  there  are,  as  mentioned  above,  at  least  two  major  sets  of  eco- 
nomic factors  which  press  society  into  a  spatial  framework:  one,  de- 
glomeration  forces,  including  the  operation  of  the  law  of  diminishing 
returns;  the  other,  inequality  of  resource  endowment. ^  Viewed  in 
terms  of  a  young  developing  economy,  the  transition  and  growth  of  a 
population  nucleation  from  a  village  into  a  town,  in  general,  involves 
spatial  extension  of  the  agricultural  hinterland.  Obviously,  despite  the 
greater  transport  effort  or  cost  that  may  be  incurred  in  marketing 
the  output  of  the  new,  more  distant  land  brought  under  cultivation,  the 
net  return  from  the  application  of  intramarginal  doses  of  capital  and 
labor  to  that  new  land  is  usually  greater  than  that  from  the  application 
of  additional  doses  to  old,  less  distant  land.  And  obviously  too,  spatial 
bonds  must  be  established  with  other  geographic  points  if  this  nuclea- 
tion is  to  consume  mineral  or  other  products  not  available  locally.  In 
terms  of  the  existing  economy  of  the  United  States,  it  is  inconceivable 
for  these  reasons  that  the  entire  population  be  herded  about  New  York 
City,  and  perhaps  a  few  additional  focal  points, ^  notwithstanding  the 
sharpening  of  the  New  York  peak  implicit  in  Stewart's  *  application  of 
physical  analogues  to  demographic  study. ^ 

2  Space  can  also  be  introduced  through  assumption  as  it  is  by  Losch  {Die  rdum- 
liche  Ordnung  der  Wirtschaft,  Jena,  1944,  Chaps.  8  and  9).  All  economic 
resources  as  well  as  completely  self-sufficient  homesteads  can  be  postulated  to 
be  uniformly  distributed  over  any  given  plain.  Spatial  relations,  however,  do 
not  become  important  until  speciaHzation  and  trade  ensue. 

3  Even  herding  of  population  is  inconsistent  with  a  spaceless  one-point  economy. 

4  "Empirical  Mathematical  Rules  .  ...  ,"  op.  cit.,  pp.  480-81.  Diminishing  returns 
and  inequality  of  resources  in  a  sense  set  in  motion  centrifugal  forces  which 
balance  the  tendency  toward  centripetal  shift  along  the  lines  of  force  in  a  field 
toward  the  peak  of  potential. 

5  Our  interpretation  of  the  factors  at  play  seems  to  be  at  variance  with  Zipf's. 
Zipf  offers  a  theoretical  explanation  of  the  spatial  arrangement  of  the  economy 
as  well  as  of  other  processes  of  human  ecology  in  terms  of  two  major  forces:  the 
Force  of  Diversification  and  the  Force  of  Unification.  The  Force  of  Diversification 
reflects  the  economy  of  moving  "the  population  to  the  immediate  sources  of  raw 
materials  in  order  to  save  the  work  of  transporting  the  materials  to  the  per- 
sons .  .  ."  and  operates  "to  split  the  population  into  a  larger  n  number  of  small, 
widely  scattered  and  largely  autarchical  communities  .  .  ."  The  Force  of  Unifica- 
tion, on  the  other  hand,  reflects  the  economy  of  saving  the  work  of  transporting 
finished  products  to  each  consumer  and  "operates  in  the  opposite  direction  of 
moving  the  materials  to  the  population,  with  the  result  that  all  production  and 


TRANSPORT  INPUTS,  RELATED  SPATIAL  CONCEPTS        79 

It  is  proposed  to  express  some  of  the  complex  spatial  relations  of  an 
economy  in  terms  of  a  simple  common  concept  of  transport  inputs. 
We  define  a  transport  input  as  the  movement  of  a  unit  of  weight  over 
a  unit  distance;  e.g.,  we  may  speak  of  pound-miles,  ton-kilometers,  etc.^ 
In  an  indirect  sense,  transport  inputs  correspond  to  the  exertions  of 
effort  and  other  factor  services  required  to  overcome  resistance  encoun- 
tered in  movement  through  space  where  friction  is  present.  In  a  space- 
economy  we  obviously  wish  to  minimize  these,  ceteris  paribus. 

It  is  imperative  to  think  in  terms  of  some  such  concept  as  transport 
inputs  if  one  is  to  comprehend  fully  the  significance  of  space  in  actu- 
ality.   One  cannot  ignore  transport  cost  and  merely  concentrate  upon 

consumption  will  take  place  in  one  big  city  where  the  entire  population  .  .  .  will 
live"  (op.  cit.,  p.  352).  Only  in  terms  of  the  functioning  of  both  forces  can  the 
actual  location  of  population  be  understood,  according  to  Zipf. 

Though  in  its  present  form  there  may  be  considerable  value  to  Zipf's  theoretical 
framework  for  a  general  study  of  human  behavior,  it  needs  to  be  substantially 
revised  and  extended  for  an  analysis  of  the  space-economy.  Though  his  frame- 
work rightly  points  out  the  essential  factor  of  minimizing  transport  effort  in  terms 
of  probable  distributions  of  raw  materials  in  general,  it  should  in  addition  encom- 
pass the  vital  consideration  of  agglomeration  (and  deglomeration)  economies 
which  consist  of  the  economies  (and  diseconomies)  of  scale  within  the  plant,  the 
economies  (and  diseconomies)  of  localization,  and  urbanization  economies  (and 
diseconomies).  On  the  one  hand,  agglomeration  economies  partially  nulUfy  the 
Force  of  Diversification  acting  toward  scattered  production  and  autarchical  com- 
munities when  a  small  "diversity  of  raw  materials  is  used,  with  an  increased  likeli- 
hood of  finding  them  in  a  restricted  area"  (op.  cit.,  p.  365).  On  the  other  hand, 
deglomeration  economies  prevent  the  economy  from  virtually  collapsing  to  a 
point  as  impUed  by  the  Force  of  Unification  when  the  "diversity  of  needed  raw 
materials  increases,  with  the  decreasing  probability  of  finding  them  in  a  single 
spot"  {op.  cit.,  p.  365). 

Also,  Zipf's  framework  tends  to  minimize  the  major  roles  played  by  certain 
industries  in  our  economy — such  as  iron  and  steel,  aluminum,  and  glass — whose 
chief  raw  materials  are  highly  localized  in  a  relatively  few  places.  The  location 
forces  operating  on  these  industries  in  terms  of  both  factor  immobilities  and 
transport  costs  on  raw  materials  and  products  tend  to  lead  to  large  population 
nuclei  at  places  other  than  Zipf's  least-work  center  which  would  be  the  point 
at  which  the  sum  of  all  "least-work  distances  to  every  person  on  the  terrain"  is 
at  a  minimum.  Nor  need  all  innovations  which  increase  the  diversity  of  materials 
increase  the  Force  of  Unification  as  Zipf  maintains.  For,  by  revaluing  the  attri- 
butes and  resources  of  certain  areas,  as  atomic  energy  has  recently  done,  a  major 
innovation  can  introduce  more  "dispersion"  from  a  least-work  center. 

6  Just  as  we  frequently  use  the  general  term,  man-hours,  when  we  speak  of 
social  aggregates  and  specify  man-hours  of  particular  types  of  labor — skilled,  un- 
skilled, etc. — when  we  speak  of  the  production  process  of  a  particular  firm,  so  with 
transport  inputs  we  shall  speak  of  ton-miles  when  we  think  in  terms  of  aggregates 
and  specify  ton-miles  of  particular  commodities  when  we  deal  with  an  individual 
line  of  production. 


80  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

the  labor,  raw  material,  and  other  costs  which  compose  transport  cost; 
nor  can  one  ignore  transport  inputs  and  merely  concentrate  upon  the 
labor,  capital,  and  other  inputs  which,  as  we  shall  presently  show,  com- 
pose transport  inputs  if  he  is  to  understand  the  full  array  of  dynamic 
spatial  phenomena.''' 

(To  avoid  confusion  with  earlier  writings  of  mine,  it  should  be  noted 
again  that  the  term  transport  inputs  is  being  substituted  for  the  term 
distance  inputs  which  has  been  previously  used.  As  mentioned  in  the 
preface,  distance  inputs  is  inferior  to  transport  inputs  as  a  term  when 
considered  with  respect  to  the  everyday  usage  of  words;  and  also  dis- 
tance inputs  is  misleading  to  non-economists  who  use  the  term  transport 
inputs  with  a  correct  spatial  perspective.  It  is  felt  that  the  non-spatial 
bias  of  traditional  economic  theory  has  by  now  been  sufficiently  over- 
come to  justify  the  employment  in  this  book  of  the  superior  term, 
transport  inputs.) 

■^  A  highly  simplified  example  may  be  illuminating  at  this  point.  Assume  that 
a  society's  iron  manufacture  has  advanced  to  the  stage  where  it  requires  300  lb 
of  coal,  200  lb  of  ore,  and  10  hours  of  direct  labor  to  produce  100  lb  of  iron  (we 
ignore  other  raw  material  and  factor  requirements).  Transportation  of  coal  and 
ore  is  required  if  production  is  at  the  market  site.  A;  of  coal  and  the  finished 
product  if  production  is  at  the  ore  site,  B;  and  of  ore  and  the  finished  product 
if  production  is  at  the  coal  site,  C.  Allow  20  labor-hours  to  transport  the  necessary 
coal  and  ore  to  produce  100  lb  of  iron  at  A,  10  labor-hours  to  transport  the  neces- 
sary coal  per  100  lb  of  iron  to  B  and  100  lb  of  finished  product  from  B  to  A,  and 
7  labor-hours  to  transport  the  necessary  ore  per  100  lb  of  iron  to  C  and  100  lb  of 
finished  product  from  C  to  A.  (We  postulate  that  the  services  of  land  and  capital 
goods  required  in  the  above  transportation  are  negligible.)     Therefore  we  have: 

For  production  at  A :  30/i  +  2r  +  3c  ->  i 

For  production  at  B:  20/i  +  2r  +  3c  ->  i 

For  production  at  C :  17h  +  2r  +  3c  ->  i 
where  h  =  1  labor-hour,  r  =  100  lb  of  ore,  c  =  100  lb  of  coal,  and  i  =  100  lb  of 
iron  delivered  at  A. 

This  formulation,  following  traditional  Unas,  points  out  the  need  for  minimizing 
the  amount  of  labor  inputs.  But  it  conceals  the  real  issue  which  is  to  minimize 
the  effort  at  overcoming  spatial  resistances,  in  a  sense,  to  economize  on  distances 
to  be  traversed  with  appropriate  weighting  for  the  type  and  amount  of  traffic  in 
any  direction.    The  presentation  of  alternatives  should  be: 

For  production  at  A:  20d  +  lOh  +  2r  +  3c  ->  i 

For  production  at  B:  lOd  +  lOh  +  2r  +  3c  ->  r 

For  production  at  C:     7d  +  lOh  +  2r  +  Sc  ^  i 
where  d  =  a  transport  input  so  defined  as  to  require  1  hour  of  effort. 

This  presentation  does  emphasize  exphcitly  that  it  is  transport  inputs  or  effort 
at  overcoming  space  resistance  which  is  to  be  minimized.  It  does  not  leave  implicit 
the  real  problem  which,  if  left  implicit,  becomes  quickly  concealed  as  soon  as  we 
treat  a  modern  economy  with  complex  stages  of  production. 


TRANSPORT  INPUTS,  RELATED  SPATIAL  CONCEPTS        81 

2.     Transport  Inputs  Contrasted  with  Capital  Inputs 

Before  certain  operational  uses  of  transport  inputs  are  demonstrated, 
this  and  related  concepts  should  be  developed  more  fully. 

It  is  instructive  to  contrast  transport  inputs  and  capital ^  inputs. 
Neither  can  be  considered  an  ultimate  factor  of  production.  Both  in 
a  sense  are  derived  even  if  the  analyst  (a  la  Knight)  must  go  back  to 
the  beginnings  of  time  to  justify  this  view.^  As  capital  goods,  and  thus 
services  of  capital  goods,  transport  inputs  stem  from  direct  labor  inputs 
with  or  without  direct  land  inputs  (as,  for  example,  the  services  of  land 
underlying  the  roadbed  upon  which  a  railway  is  constructed) ,  with  or 
without  the  services  of  capital  goods  (as,  for  example,  that  of  rail 
equipment),  and  with  or  without  other  transport  inputs  (as,  for 
example,  the  transport  inputs  required  in  bringing  coal  to  the  loco- 
motive) .  Ultimately,  they  can  be  traced  back  to  direct  labor  and  land 
inputs  only. 

The  same  motive  lies  behind  decisions  respecting  the  use  of  capital 
inputs  and  the  use  of  transport  inputs.  The  motive  in  the  traditional 
sense  is  to  maximize  profit.  Methods  requiring  the  use  of  capital 
goods  or  the  increased  use  of  capital  goods  are  adopted  when  they  are 
found  to  be  more  productive,  given  any  initial  amount  of  labor-hours 
and  other  inputs  to  be  expended.  Or  these  methods  may  enable  the 
production  of  goods  otherwise  unobtainable  and  at  an  expenditure  of 
effort  which  society  is  willing  to  make.  Likewise  with  transport 
inputs.  When  in  a  simple  economy  a  farmer  with  a  given  amount  of 
capital  and  other  resources  chooses  to  apply  his  efforts  at  cultivating 
new  land  on  the  periphery  of  the  hinterland  of  a  growing  town  rather 
than  at  cultivating  intensively  a  more  limited  quantity  of  old  land  near 
the  town,  in  general  he  anticipates  reaping  greater  returns  despite  the 
fact  that  he  applies  less  of  his  available  labor  to  cultivation  and  more 
to  marketing  his  harvest.  In  effect  he  substitutes  transport  inputs 
(indirect  labor  inputs)  for  direct  labor  inputs.    He  finds  it  profitable^o 

s  In  using  the  word  capital,  we  are  thinking  in  real  terms  and  chiefly  of  capital 
goods.  Controversy  over  the  definition  of  capital  is  not  desired.  The  argument 
that  follows  holds,  except  perhaps  for  minor  revisions,  regardless  of  the  particular 
definition  of  real  capital  adopted. 

9  And  even  if  he  must  contrast  capital  with  unskilled  labor  and  virgin  soil. 
Among  others,  see  F.  Knight,  "The  Theory  of  Investment  Once  More :  Mr.  Bould- 
ing  and  the  Austrians,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  50  (November  1935), 
pp.  45-50;  and  K.  Wicksell,  Lectures  on  Political  Economy,  New  York,  1934, 
Vol.  I,  Part  II,  especially  pp.  145-46,  149-51,  185-86. 

10  It  should  be  emphasized  that  just  as  every  investment  for  a  longer  period 
(made  possible  by  the  accumulation  of  additional  capital)  will  not  necessarily 


82  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

to  do  so  in  the  same  way  that  in  using  a  plough  that  he  has  built,  he 
finds  it  profitable  to  substitute  services  of  capital  goods  (indirect  labor 
inputs)  for  direct  labor  inputs. ^  Also,  when  the  United  States  public 
over  the  years  has  chosen  to  consume  coffee  and  at  an  increasing  rate 
rather  than  to  consume  more  of  domestically  produced  commodities, 
there  has  resulted  an  increase  in  the  spatial  extent  of  the  United  States 
economy.  This  resembles  the  increase  in  the  time  extent  of  production 
which  took  place  when  society  decided  to  mine  and  refine  uranium  ore 
(as  well  as  produce  the  requisite  equipment)  partly  with  labor  drawn 
from  unmechanized  agriculture.  12 

Many  economists  think  of  methods  using  the  services  of  capital 
goods  as  roundabout  methods  which  increase  the  time  extent  of 
production,  or  to  be  more  precise,  the  time  period  of  investment.!^  We 
need  not  judge  the  validity  of  such  reasoning. i*  If  one  accepts  it,  one 
can  draw  a  parallel  with  respect  to  the  use  of  transport  inputs. 
Methods  which  use  transport  inputs  are  also  roundabout,  and  they 
tend  to  increase  the  spatial  extent  of  production. 

Further,  if  one  adheres  to  Hayek's  theory  of  capital  and  discards 
the  concept  of  an  average  investment  period,  to  account  for  a  greater 
use  of  capital  "it  is  sufficient  to  say  that  the  investment  period  of  some 


yield  a  larger  product,  so  every  increase  in  the  use  of  transport  inputs  and  in  the 
spatial  extent  of  society  will  not  necessarily  be  desirable.  Only  those  spatial 
lengthenings  of  production  which  are  profitable  will  be  adopted.  Compare  F.  von 
Hayek,  The  Pure  Theory  of  Capital,  London,  1941,  p.  60. 

11  For  a  discussion  of  relations  between  direct  and  indirect  labor  which  is 
designed  to  elucidate  certain  capital  aspects  of  production  but  which  to  a  large 
extent  is  also  applicable  to  spatial  aspects,  see  0.  Lange,  "The  Place  of  Interest 
in  the  Theory  of  Production,"  Review  of  Economic  Studies,  Vol.  Ill  (June  1936), 
pp.  159-70. 

12  In  the  sense  that  both  capital  and  transport  inputs  are  derived,  society  with- 
draws certain  resources  from  immediate  direct  application  in  order  to  exploit, 
or  exploit  more  efficiently,  other  potential  resources.  And  these  potential  re- 
sources, as  they  are  drawn  into  the  production  process,  need  not  be  immediately 
consumed,  but  may  be  employed  to  exploit  still  other  potential  resources  and 
thus  to  increase  further  the  time  and  space  extent  of  production.  In  this  way 
the  process  of  capital  and  spatial  growth  of  the  economy  can  be  cumulative. 

13  As  Hayek  has  pointed  out,  the  concept  of  a  single  or  average  period  of  pro- 
duction may  be  not  only  a  confusing  but  also  a  meaningless  abstraction.  One 
must  think  in  terms  of  periods  for  which  particular  factors  are  invested.  "The 
Mythology  of  Capital,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  50  (February  1936), 
pp.  199-205. 

i^J.  B.  Clark,  Knight,  Nurkse,  Smithies,  and  others  have  attacked  it.  For 
bibhography  on  this  controversy,  see  N.  Kaldor,  "Annual  Survey  of  Economic 
Theory:  The  Recent  Controversy  on  the  Theory  of  Capital,"  Econometrica,  Vol. 
5  (July  1937),  and  Readings  in  the  Theory  of  Income  Distribution,  Blakiston, 
Philadelphia,  1946,  pp.  694-99. 


TRANSPORT  INPUTS,  RELATED  SPATIAL  CONCEPTS         83 

factors  has  been  lengthened  while  those  of  all  others  have  remained 
unchanged;  or  that  the  investment  periods  of  a  greater  quantity  of 
factors  have  been  lengthened  than  the  quantity  of  factors  whose 
investment  periods  have  been  shortened  by  an  equal  amount;  or  that 
the  investment  period  of  a  given  quantity  of  factors  has  been 
lengthened  by  more  than  the  investment  period  of  another  equal 
amount  has  been  shortened. "i^  In  parallel  fashion,  we  need  not  speak 
of  an  average  spatial  extent  of  production,  which  concept  if  meaningful 
could  pose  serious  problems  in  measurement.  But  when  more  transport 
inputs  are  utilized,  and  profitably  so,  we  can  assume  that  the  spatial 
extent  of  production  in  general  is  increased:  (1)  that  the  spatial  dimen- 
sion of  some  production  lines  is  lengthened  (as,  for  example,  through 
the  extension  of  marketing  and  purchasing  areas) ;  (2)  that  the  spatial 
dimensions  of  certain  production  lines  are  lengthened  while  those  of 
others  are  shortened  by  an  equal  amount,  but  that  the  former  group 
is  of  greater  quantitative  significance;  or  (3)  that  of  two  equally 
important  groups  of  production  lines,  the  increase  in  the  spatial 
dimension  of  those  lengthened  is  greater  than  the  decrease  of  those 
shortened.  16 

Connected  with  the  roundaboutness  of  capitalistic  production  one 
frequently  finds  the  concept  of  time  preference  over  which  has  raged  a 
controversy  that  I  do  not  wish  to  discuss. i'''     However,  I  do  wish  to 

15  "The  Mythology  of  Capital,"  op.  cit.,  p.  206.  Also  see  F.  Machlup,  "Professor 
Knight  and  the  'Period  of  Production,' "  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  43 
(October  1935),  pp.  584-93. 

16  To  correspond  to  Knight's  contention  that  increase  in  the  use  of  capital  does 
not  necessarily  entail  an  increase  in  the  period  of  production  [see  F.  Knight, 
"Professor  Hayek  and  the  Theory  of  Investment,"  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  45 
(March  1935),  pp.  79-81],  it  is  difficult  to  visualize  how  a  profitable  absorption 
of  additional  transport  inputs  might  shorten  the  spatial  extent  of  production 
in  general. 

I  am  incHned  to  reject  Knight's  views  that  all  capital  is  normally  conceptually 
perpetual,  that  its  replacement  has  to  be  taken  for  granted  as  a  technological 
detail,  that,  in  consequence  there  is  no  production  process  of  determinate 
length  other  than  zero  or  "all  history,"  and  that,  in  the  only  sense  of  timing  in 
terms  of  which  economic  analysis  is  possible,  production  and  consumption  are 
simultaneous.  (Hayek,  "Mythology  of  Capital,"  op.  cit.,  p.  202.)  It  certainly 
would  be  meaningless  to  use  the  Knightian  emphasis  for  the  development  of 
space  concepts.  It  would  negate  the  very  existence  of  a  space-economy.  There 
could  be  no  space  separating  production  and  consumption.    And  so  forth. 

1'^  For  various  points  of  view,  see,  among  others,  E.  von  Bohm-Bawerk,  The 
Positive  Theory  of  Capital,  1891,  Book  V;  I.  Fisher,  The  Theory  of  Interest,  New 
York,  1939,  especially  Chap.  XX;  F.  Knight,  "Professor  Fisher's  Interest  Theory: 
A  Case  in  Point,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  39  (April  1931),  pp.  176-212; 
and  F.  von  Hayek,  Pure  Theory  of  Capital,  London,  1941,  Chaps.  17  and  18,  and 
Appendix  I. 


84  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

emphasize  that,  if  one  thinks  in  terms  of  time  preference,  there  is 
strong  justification  for  thinking  in  terms  of  space  preference. ^^ 
Psychologists  and  sociologists,  whether  speaking  of  a  gregarious 
instinct  or  of  acquired  behavior  patterns  or  of  both,  have  emphasized 
the  social  nature  of  man  and  his  propensity  to  associate  with  groups 
of  various  sorts. i^  One  can  reason  that  such  a  propensity,  acquired  or 
instinctive,  is  a  manifestation  of  a  positive  space  preference.  In  the 
extreme,  unreal  case,  where  there  are  ubiquitous  resources,  no  diminish- 
ing returns  on  land,  and  no  congestion  problem  that  sets  in  motion 
dispersive  forces,  people  would  aggregate  in  one  or  many  herds  of  dif- 
ferent sizes — a  phenomenon  which  is  biologically  valid. ^o  To  induce 
them  to  separate,  there  would  have  to  be  an  incentive.  In  the  real 
world  the  incentive  for  non-herd  existence,  economically  speaking,  is 
greater  productivity  obtainable  through  (1)  capitalizing  deglomeration 
economies  (such  as  postponing  the  operation  of  the  laws  of  diminishing 
returns)  and  (2)  exploiting  the  uneven  geographic  distribution  of 
resources.  This  incentive  (it  can  be  maintained)  is  analogous  to  that 
which  induces  people  to  defer  present  consumption  of  commodities 
for  the  possession  of  a  greater  amount  at  a  later  date. 

It  should  be  stressed  that  not  all  individuals  need  have  a  positive 
space  preference.  There  are  hermits.  They  exhibit  negative  space 
preference,  being  willing  in  general  to  accept  a  lower  productivity  (a 
lower  standard  of  living)  in  order  to  be  spatially  apart  from  society. 
They  resemble  those  well-to-do  individuals  who  fear  and  exaggerate 
the  insecurities  of  the  future,  who  have  a  negative  rate  of  time 
preference,  and  who  would  be  willing  to  accept  if  necessary  a  negative 
interest  rate. 

Less  extreme  is  the  introvert  whose  need  for  social  contact  is  not 
intense.  He  possesses  a  mild  space  preference.  He  is  easily  induced 
to  lead  a  fairly  isolated  life,  though  in  actuality  he  may  not  do  so. 
Not  so  with  the  extrovert.  His  need  for  social  interchange  is  acute; 
his  space  preference  markedly  high.     He  parallels  the  sailor,  child, 

18  For  this  expression  I  am  indebted  to  Dr.  E.  M.  Hoover. 

19  Refer,  among  others,  to  W.  McDougall,  An  Introduction  to  Social  Psychology, 
Boston,  1926,  pp.  87-90,  175-78,  303-8,  456-60;  L.  L.  Bernard,  Instinct,  A  Study  in 
Social  Psychology,  New  York,  1924,  especially  pp.  357-59,  369-72;  K.  Young,  Source 
Book  for  Social  Psychology,  New  York,  1927,  Chaps.  I-IV;  and  W.  F.  Ogburn 
and  M.  F.  Nimkoff,  Sociology,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1940,  Part  IV. 

20  See  W.  Trotter,  Instincts  of  the  Herd  in  Peace  and  War,  London,  1916;  and 
W.  C.  Allee,  The  Social  Life  of  Animals,  New  York,  1938.  Small  herds  (cities), 
and  not  necessarily  one  huge  herd  (city),  may  be  sufficient  to  satisfy  the  social 
needs  of  man. 


TRANSPORT  INPUTS,  RELATED  SPATIAL  CONCEPTS         85 

savage,  and  spendthrift  whose  positive  rate  of  time  preference  is 
likewise  towering.  21 

On  balance  it  does  seem  that,  despite  the  many  serious  qualifications 
one  must  make  in  generalizing  about  such  psychological  principles  as 
time  preference  and  space  preference  and  despite  the  recent  centrifugal 
tendencies  in  population  movement  (which  we  will  discuss  briefly 
below) ,  individuals  in  society,  in  general,  do  manifest  a  positive  space 
preference  just  as  they  seem  to  manifest  a  positive  time  preference. 

Associated  with  time  preference  has  been  the  procedure  of  discount- 
ing over  time.  The  present  value  of  a  future  product  is  equal  to  its 
expected  future  price  discounted  by  the  prevailing  rate  of  interest. 
The  return  to  an  input  is  equated  to  its  discounted  marginal  produc- 
tivity. And  so  forth.  The  usefulness  of  this  procedure  is  obvious. 
But  there  is  also  a  discounting  over  space,  which  enables  one  to 
compare  values  of  two  or  more  goods,  yields,  or  inputs  spatially 
separated  and  differently  distant  from  any  particular  geographic 
point  of  reference.  The  rate  of  discount  in  space  is  of  course  the 
transport  rate.  Though  economists  have  never  spoken  explicitly  of 
spatial  discounting,  nonetheless  they  have  performed  the  operation. 2 2 
In  doing  so,  they  have  most  frequently  been  considering  a  one-point 
market  served  by  a  surface  producing  area  (as  we  find  in  farming). 
In  such  a  case  the  farther  the  site  of  production  from  the  market  the 
more  the  market  price  is  discounted  to  yield  the  net  price  on  the  output 
of  that  site.  However,  far  more  complex  situations,  involving  all 
types  of  possible  purchasing  areas  and  selling  areas  for  the  relevant 
inputs  and  outputs,  have  been  handled  by  location  analysts. 2 3     The 

21  The  reader  who  is  interested  in  constructing  other  parallels  may  refer  to  the 
various  possible  types  of  time  preference  cited  by  Fisher  (op.  cit.)  and  Bohm- 
Bawerk  (op.  cit.). 

Just  as  we  can  have  different  rates  of  time  preference  for  various  commodities 
(e.g.  see  Hayek,  The  Pure  Theory  of  Capital,  op.  cit.,  pp.  241-42)  we  can  conceive 
of  different  space  preferences  with  respect  to  various  social  activities.  And  cer- 
tainly the  state  of  technology,  the  geographic  environment,  and  the  cultural  milieu 
affect  the  nature  of  one's  space  preference.  Compare  the  age  of  the  automobile 
with  the  age  of  the  horsecar. 

22  As  an  instance,  Alfred  Marshall  states :  "If  in  any  industry,  whether  agricul- 
tural or  not,  two  producers  have  equal  facilities  in  all  respects,  except  that  one 
has  a  more  convenient  situation  than  the  other,  and  can  buy  or  sell  in  the  same 
markets  with  less  cost  of  carnage,  the  differential  advantage  which  his  situation 
gives  him  is  the  aggregate  of  the  excess  charges  for  cost  of  carriage  to  which  his 
rival  is  put.  And  we  may  suppose  that  other  advantages  of  situation,  such  for 
instance  as  the  near  access  to  a  labour  market  specially  adapted  to  his  trade,  can 
be  translated  in  like  manner  into  money  values."  (Principles  of  Economics,  Book 
V,  Chap.  XI,  Sect.  1.) 

23  We  cite  a  few  works:    O.  Englander,   Theorie   des   GUterverkehrs  und  der 


86  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

explicit  use  of  spatial  discounting  can  clear  the  ground  for  a  more 
functional  analysis  of  the  factor  of  situs  in  economic  activities. 

3.     Transport  Rate:  The  Price  of  a  Transport  Input 

In  speaking  of  an  input,  one  also  thinks  in  terms  of  the  price  of,  or 
the  return  to,  that  input.  What  determines  its  reward?  What 
determines  interest,  rent,  wages,  profits,  or  in  Knightian  terms  the 
annual  rate  of  return  in  perpetuity?  What  is  the  return  or  price  cor- 
responding to  a  transport  input?  The  last  question  can  be  partly 
answered  with  a  simple  supply  and  demand  approach  conventionally 
used  to  answer  the  first  two  questions. 

If,  from  the  standpoint  of  society,  we  think  of  a  transport  input  as 
equivalent  to  the  movement  of  a  ton  of  any  commodity  over  1  mile 
and  if,  for  the  moment,  we  put  aside  the  complicated  transport  struc- 
tures of  reality,  then  the  price  of  a  transport  input  is  the  transport 
rate.  From  the  standpoint  of  suppliers,  at  higher  and  higher  trans- 
port rates,  there  will  be  a  tendency  for  more  and  more  transport  inputs 
to  be  furnished.  More  and  more  direct  labor  and  land  services  and 
services  of  capital  and  capital  goods  will  flow  into  the  area  of  transport 
inputs.  The  supply  curve  for  transport  inputs  is  positively  inclined 
(where  transport  rate  is  measured  along  the  vertical  axis  and  quantity 
along  the  horizontal).  On  the  other  hand,  the  demand  curve  for 
transport  inputs,  as  can  be  expected,  is  negatively  inclined.  It  may 
be  claimed  that  such  a  demand  curve  reflects  the  marginal  productivity 
corresponding  to  various  quantities  of  transport  inputs.  It  would  then 
be  anticipated,  given  a  state  of  technology,  tastes,  and  resources,  that 
as  the  spatial  extent  of  production  is  continually  lengthened  through 
the  application  of  more  and  more  transport  inputs, ^-i  the  additional 
product  associated  with  each  successive  lengthening,  after  a  point,  tends 
to  fall  off.  2  5 

Frachtsdtze,  Jena,  1924;  T.  Palander,  Beitrdge  zur  Standortstheorie,  Upsala,  1935, 
especially  Chaps.  VII  and  XII;  E.  M.  Hoover,  Location  Theory  and  the  Shoe 
and  Leather  Industries,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1937;  and  A.  Losch,  op.  cit. 

As  Professor  Haberler  has  suggested,  transport  costs  may  be  compared  with 
storage  costs:  the  former,  in  moving  from  one  point  in  space  to  another;  the 
latter,  from  one  point  in  time  to  another  in  the  future. 

24  Of  course,  for  many  lines  of  production  the  spatial  extent,  like  the  time 
period  of  investment,  increases  by  only  large  jumps. 

25  It  seems  trivial  to  argue  whether  or  not  physical  output  is  to  be  attributed 
to  the  use  of  transport  inputs  and  whether  or  not  a  marginal  physical  product 
can  be  assigned  to  the  use  of  an  additional  dose  of  transport  inputs.  The  farmer 
who  does  use  an  additional  dose  of  transport  inputs,  when  he  finds  it  profitable 
to  shift  his  farming  operations  to  a  location  somewhat  more  distant  from  his 


TRANSPORT  INPUTS,  RELATED  SPATIAL  CONCEPTS         87 

It  is  instructive  to  examine  somewhat  more  thoroughly  the  effect  of 
a  change  in  the  price  of  a  transport  input.  Suppose  an  advance  in 
the  state  of  transport  technology  pushes  the  supply  curve  of  transport 
inputs  to  the  right  and  results  in  a  lower  price.  From  the  viewpoint  of 
industrial  production  there  will  be  both  a  scale  and  a  substitution 
effect.  Historically  we  find  that  reduced  transport  rates  have  tended 
(1)  to  transform  a  scattered,  ubiquitous  pattern  of  production  into  an 
increasingly  concentrated  one,  and  (2)  to  effect  progressive  differentia- 
tion and  selection  between  sites  with  superior  and  inferior  resources 
and  trade  routes. ^^  The  resulting  increase  in  geographic  specialization 
and  in  the  spatial  extent  of  production  in  general  is,  in  essence,  a 
substitution  of  transport  inputs  for  various  other  inputs  (particularly 
for  those  inputs  at  inferior  sites)  as  well  as  a  substitution  of  inputs 
in  general  at  the  favored  sites  for  inputs  in  general  at  the  disfavored 
sites.  As  to  the  scale  effect,  the  tremendous  increases  in  output 
engendered  by  the  cheapening  of  transport  inputs  are  too  well  known 
to  require  discussion. 

Also  with  respect  to  consumer  behavior,  there  are  scale  and 
substitution  effects.  With  a  fall  in  the  time  and  money  cost  of  popu- 
lation movement  (as  realized  with  the  development  of  the  street  and 
electric  railway,  the  automobile,  bus,  and  aircraft),  a  person  in 
general  can  maintain  a  given  level  of  social  contact  (or  space  prefer- 
ence) and  at  the  same  time  consume  more  of  other  products.    He  can, 

market  point,  does  realize  an  addition  to  total  product,  ceteris  paribus.  Also,  in 
the  case  where  a  firm  decides  to  exploit  a  deposit  of  richer  ore  which,  however, 
is  more  removed  from  the  point  of  smelting,  there  corresponds  to  the  increase 
in  transport  inputs  (whether  large  or  small)  an  increase  in  physical  product,  ceteris 
paribus. 

Some  may  contend  that  in  both  cases  the  addition  to  total  product  is  not  the 
result  of  the  additional  use  of  transport  inputs  per  se  but  rather  a  result  of  a  more 
efficient  combination  of  land,  labor,  and  capital  services.  Others  may  insist  that 
just  as  a  (marginal)  productivity  is  attributed  to  capital,  even  though  capital 
inputs  (e.g.  the  services  of  capital  equipment)  are  not  productive  per  se  but 
merely  allow  the  services  of  labor  to  be  more  productive,  so  should  a  (marginal) 
productivity  be  assigned  to  transport  inputs. 

From  our  standpoint,  the  significant  point  is  the  association,  whether  one  inter- 
prets it  causally  or  merely  statistically,  of  greater  physical  product  with  increased 
use  of  transport  inputs,  ceteris  paribus.  This  explains  in  part  the  demand  for 
transport  inputs  and,  for  obvious  reasons,  a  demand  schedule  which  indicates 
that,  at  a  lower  and  lower  price  for  transport  inputs,  there  will  be  a  tendency  for 
more  and  more  of  transport  inputs  to  be  purchased. 

26  See  W.  H.  Dean,  Jr.,  The  Theory  of  the  Geographic  Location  of  Economic 
Activities,  Ann  Arbor,  Mich.,  1938,  especially  Chap.  3;  E.  M.  Hoover,  op.  cit., 
Chap.  3;  and  H.  Ritschl,  "Reine  und  historische  Dynamik  des  Standortes  der 
Erzeugungszweige,"  Schmollers  Jahrbuch,  Vol.  51    (1927),  pp.  813-70. 


88  LOCATION  AKD  SPACE-ECONOMY 

at  the  given  level  of  social  contact,  enjoy  more  of  the  amenities  of  life 
that  come  from  living  in  a  less  congested  area  away  from  the  compact 
urban  mass.  This  scale  effect  which  obviously  requires  a  greater 
consumption  of  transport  inputs  partly  accounts  for  the  process  of 
dispersion  of  urban  populations^  and  the  settlement  of  peripheral 
metropolitan  areas  that  has  taken  place  during  the  last  half-century. 2  8 
But  this  development  is  also  partly  due  to  the  operation  of  the 
substitution  effect.  Consumption  of  transport  inputs  has  been  substi- 
tuted for  the  consumption  of  other  commodities  and  services. 
Expenditures  on  travel,  whether  intraurban  or  other,  appear  to  have 
absorbed  an  increasing  proportion  of  the  consumer's  budget. 

Hitherto  we  have  spoken  of  a  single  transport  rate  as  the  price  of 
a  transport  input.  However,  in  modern  society  there  is  a  multitude 
of  rates  which  vary  with  length  of  haul,  nature  of  haul,  type  of 
commodity,  degree  of  competition,  character  of  topography,  etc. 
Similarly,  although  we  speak  of  a  single  prevailing  interest  rate  as  the 
price  of  capital,  there  is  a  multitude  of  interest  rates  varying  according 
to  the  nature  of  the  risk,  length  of  the  loan,  type  of  region,  etc. 2 9  It 
is  to  be  expected  that  in  the  operation  of  a  complex,  institutionalized 
society  there  will  be  all  types  of  transport  rates  and  discriminations 
in  the  application  of  these  rates.  But  this  does  not  invalidate 
thinking  in  general  terms  of  the  transport  rate  as  a  hypothetical, 
representative  one,  one  that  reflects  the  general  movement  of  the 
multitude  of  actual  transport  rates.  The  basic  analysis  is  essentially 
unaffected  by  such  a  fiction,  ^o 

^■'^  All  income,  classes  have,  in  general,  been  affected.  At  one  extreme  the  lowest 
income  groups  have  gradually  moved  out  of  the  worst  slums  into  somewhat  better 
districts,  generally  somewhat  younger,  less  congested,  and  farther  from  the  core 
of  the  city.  At  the  other  extreme  the  highest  income  groups,  who  though  on 
higher  planes  of  living  do  not  necessarily  possess  different  space  preferences,  in 
general  have  vacated  by  degrees  their  existing  residences  to  construct  new  ones 
more  removed,  although  some  individuals  have  moved  closer  to  the  core.  For 
further  material  see  H.  Hoyt,  The  Structure  and  Growth  of  Residential  Neighbor- 
hoods in  American  Cities  (Federal  Housing  Administration),  Washington,  1939; 
and  U.S.  National  Resources  Committee,  Our  Cities,  Washington,  1937. 

28  Also,  the  mobility  and  flexibility  of  rural  population  has  been  increased. 
Living  apart  from  one's  fellow  creatures,  as  is  involved  in  many  rural  occupa- 
tions, may  require  sacrifice  of  social  contact  for  increased  productivity.  Reduced 
time  and  money  cost  of  movement  allows  greater  social  intercourse  for  a  given 
productivity.  It  may  also  induce  the  individual  with  a  given  space  preference  to 
exploit  resources  which  hitherto  lay  idle  because  of  the  social  isolation  involved. 

29  Refer  to  Fisher,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  IX. 

30  It  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  determination  of  the  transport  rate  and 
spatial  extent  of  production  is  not  independent  of  the  interest  rate  (and  vice 
versa).     Since  an  increase  in  the  potential  availabihty  of  transport  inputs  in  a 


TRANSPORT  INPUTS,  RELATED  SPATIAL  CONCEPTS        89 

4.     Transport  Inputs  and  the  Classification  of  Factors 

A  few  words  should  be  said  about  how  transport  inputs  fit  into  the 
various  classifications  of  productive  agents  or  the  conceptual  classifica- 
tions presented  as  substitutes.  One  might  venture  the  hypothesis  that 
historically,  had  there  been  a  certain  social  class  which  owned  all 
transport  facilities  and  performed  all  transport  services,  the  Classicals 
might  well  have  thought  of  transport  as  a  fourth  factor  of  production 
and  have  been  more  conscious  of  distance  and  the  spatial  aspect  of 
production.  Such  was  not  the  case,  and  in  any  event  a  classification 
based  on  socio-economic  groups  could  not  have  much  meaning  today. 

Perhaps  the  most  salient  feature  of  a  transport  input  is  its  momen- 
tary character.  A  transport  input  is  realized  at  a  given  time  from 
the  performance  of  various  services.  There  can  be  no  stock  of  trans- 
port inputs.  There  can  only  be  a  stock  of  services  which  can  be  used 
to  yield  transport  inputs.  A  particular  individual  engaged  solely  in 
transporting  goods  represents  a  stock  of  potential  labor  services.  It 
would  be  wrong  to  conceive  of  him  as  also  a  stock  of  potential  transport 
inputs  since  in  the  future  his  services  need  not  be  employed  at  rendering 
transport  inputs. 

Or  take  a  piece  of  equipment,  a  locomotive.  It  should  not  be 
considered  a  stock  of  transport  inputs.  Rather  it  represents  a  stock  of 
services  of  a  particular  capital  good,  which  services  when  combined 
with  labor  and  other  services  simultaneously  yield  transport  inputs. 
This,  too,  is  merely  another  way  of  saying  that  a  transport  input  is  an 
indirect  input. 

From  the  standpoint  of  orienting  transport  inputs  within  the  frame- 
work of  other  types  of  inputs,  it  seems  best  to  utilize  the  approach  of 
Walras,^!  which  has  been  well  developed  by  Knight. ^^  There  the 
fundamental  dichotomy  is  between  resources  or  capital  (as  broadly 
conceived  by  Knight)  and  services.  There  is  nothing  of  a  resource  or 
capital  nature  in  the  concept  of  a  transport  input.  Rather  it  is  in  the 
nature  of  a  service  and  has  the  same  time  dimension  as  the  service  of 

modern  society  involves  an  increase  in  capital  investment  in  transport  equipment 
and  facilities,  the  conditions  under  which  capital  is  available  do  influence  the 
nature  of  the  supply  curve  of  transport  inputs  and,  hence,  the  price  of  a  transport 
input  and  the  structure  of  the  space-economy.  In  this  way,  too,  land  values  and 
differential  rents  from  superior  situations  are  affected  by  the  interest  rate. 

31  L.  Walras,  Elements  d'economie  politique  pure,  Lausanne,  1926,  pp.  175-84. 

32  F.  Knight,  "The  Ricardian  Theory  of  Production  and  Distribution,"  Canadian 
Journal  oj  Economics  and  Political  Science,  Vol.  I  (May  1935),  pp.  3-25;  and 
"Capital  and  Interest,"  Encyclopaedia  Britannica,  Vol.  IV,  1946,  pp.  799-801.  Also 
see  the  approach  of  I.  Fisher  {op.  oil.,  Chap.  I). 


90  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

a  given  person,  piece  of  land,  or  capital  good,  though  to  be  sure  there 
are  stocks  which  correspond  to  these  latter  services.  It  flows  indirectly 
from  given  resources  and  capital  and  competes  with  and  substitutes 
for  all  other  types  of  inputs  (services)  in  the  production  process. 

Nonetheless,  one  can  utilize  the  Marshallian  approach,  if  one  follows 
a  functional  analysis.  In  a  production  process  there  are  requirements 
for  labor  at  a  given  place,  capital  at  a  given  place,  land  services, 
organizing  ability,  and  finally  transport  inputs,  i.e.,  the  composite  of 
services  needed  to  move  raw  materials,  equipment,  labor,  and  finished 
product  to  the  appropriate  places.  Expressed  differently,  the  transport 
function  (defined  in  the  broadest  sense  possible)  can  be  singled  out 
as  a  vital  aspect  of  production,  as  vital  perhaps  as  the  functions  of 
labor,  capital,  land,  and  the  entrepreneur.  The  inputs  corresponding 
to  the  transport  function  we  have  called  transport  inputs,  and  by 
paying  attention  to  this  function  and  its  associated  inputs  we  are 
able  to  describe  the  spatial  aspects  of  the  economy.  But  one  need  not 
necessarily  think  of  the  transport  function  as  another  factor  of  produc- 
tion. The  important  thing  is  to  recognize  the  role  that  transport  inputs 
do  play  in  production  and  consumption  processes. 


Chapter 


The  Locational 

Equilibrium  of  the  Firm: 

Transport  —  Orientation 


1.     Some  Definitional  and  Classificational  Remarks 

The  theoretical,  conceptual,  and  empirical  materials  of  the  previous 
chapters  form  a  background  against  which  we  shall  re-examine, 
restate  in  part,  and  attempt  to  extend  existing  location  theories.  In 
doing  so  we  shall  have  as  a  prime  objective  the  synthesizing  of  partial 
location  theories  into  a  more  general  theory  which  yields  any  given 
specific  location  theory  capable  of  being  spelled  out  in  detail  when 
the  appropriate  set  of  conditions  are  postulated. 

In  this  chapter  we  shall  confine  ourselves  to  the  locational 
equilibrium  of  the  firmi  when  the  problem  of  transport-orientation 
obtains.  The  utility  of  the  concept  of  transport  inputs  in  the  determi- 
nation of  the  firm's  geographical  position  will  be  demonstrated.  Also, 
this  concept  will  enable  us  to  fuse  much  of  traditional  Weberian 
locational  doctrine  and  modern  production  theory.  At  the  same  time 
certain  difficulties  which  have  confronted  location  theorists  for  a  long 
time  will  be  resolved. 

1  For  simplicity's  sake  we  shall  speak  of  a  firm  as  consisting  of  one  or  more 
plants  operating  at  one  and  only  one  site  and  of  a  producer  as  managing  one  and 
only  one  firm.  There  is  no  logical  difiiculty  in  extending  the  analysis  to  enter- 
prises which  operate  plants  spatially  separated,  whether  these  plants  correspond 
to  the  same  or  different  stages  of  production.  However,  one  must  then  consider 
transport  inputs  within  the  enterprise  and  consequently  the  analysis  becomes 
more  complex. 

91 


92  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

However,  it  is  advisable,  first,  clearly  to  define  the  problem  of  this 
chapter  and  to  stress  the  various  levels  of  abstraction  at  which 
locational  analysis  is  possible.  This  is  necessary  in  order  to  avoid 
criticism  similar  to  some  which  has  been  directed  at  Weber  but  which 
has  failed  to  appreciate  that  the  interpretation  and  significance  of  the 
Weberian  doctrine  are  different  for  each  of  these  levels. 2  It  is  possible, 
of  course,  to  establish  different  classifications  of  levels  at  which  inquiry 
can  be  conducted.  Although  the  reader  may  prefer  to  adopt  another 
classification,  it  is  satisfactory  for  our  purposes  to  set  up  the  following 
one  which  distinguishes  among  at  least  four  levels  of  inquiry : 

1.  For  the  small,  individual  producer  who  has  a  negligible  influence 
upon  prices  (with  the  exception  of  the  price  of  his  own  product) ,  the 
locus  of  consumption,  the  supply  costs  and  sources  of  factors,  transport 
rates,  agglomeration  economies,  and  other  locational  variables; 

2.  For  the  small  or  large  producer  who  does  influence  these  variables ; 

3.  For  an  industry  as  a  whole  or  for  a  group  of  producers  who  form 
a  meaningful  aggregate  for  analysis  because  they  are  homogeneous 
with  respect  to  certain  characteristics,  or  because,  though  hetero- 
geneous, they  complement  each  other  ;3 

4.  For  a  regional  or  world  economy  (where  general  analysis  should 
account  for  the  determination  of  values  for  all  possible  location 
variables) . 

In  this  chapter  we  shall  confine  ourselves  chiefly  to  the  first  level. 
However,  it  should  be  emphasized  that  the  accepted  dualism  in 
location  theory — viz.,  a  Thiinen  type  of  analysis  for  the  agricultural 
sphere,  a  Weberian  schema  for  the  industrial  sector — ^^and  the  opposition 
to  incorporating  these  two  models  into  one  general  framework  totters 
once  we  recognize  these  levels  of  inquiry.  The  Thiinen  school  confines 
itself  to  an  aggregative  analysis.  Its  problem  is  the  distribution  of 
agricultural  production  over  a  given  region.  It  assumes  away  any 
problems  of  location  for  the  individual  producer  by  assigning  to  him 

2  A  systematic  presentation  and  refutation  (in  many  respects,  valid)  of  these 
criticisms  is  found  in  E.  Niederhauser,  "Die  Standortstheorie  Alfred  Webers," 
Staatswissenschaftliche  Studien,  Vol.  XIV   (Weinfelden,  1944). 

3  Chamberlin  has  pointed  out  the  limitations  of  the  group  concept  for  analyz- 
ing substitution  effects  among  the  products  of  individual  firms  {The  Theory  of 
Monopolistic  Competition,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1933,  especially  pp.  103-4)  and  has 
particularly  criticized  the  industry  in  this  respect.  See  his  "Product  Heterogeneity 
and  Public  Pohcy,"  Papers  and  Proceedings  of  the  American  Economic  Associa- 
tion, Vol.  XL  (May  1950),  pp.  85-92;  and  "Monopolistic  Competition  Revisited," 
Economica,  November  1951.  Our  industry  or  group  of  firms,  however,  may  be 
conceived  in  terms  of  similar  techniques  of  production,  or  inputs,  or  in  terms  of 
a  set  of  external  economies  achieved  by  agglomeration  of  similar  or  dissimilar 
lines  of  production. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION      93 

a  fixed  location,  an  infinite  immobility.  The  Weberian  school,  on  the 
other  hand,  is  primarily  concerned  with  the  locational  problem  of  an 
individual  firm  which  produces  a  given  product.  True,  the  Weberian 
doctrine  frequently  shifts  to  aggregative  analysis  when  it  considers 
agglomeration  economies,  the  various  economic  strata  of  society,  and 
the  like.  But  in  this  type  of  aggregative  analysis  the  Weberian  school 
explicitly  avoids  the  problem  of  the  efficient  spatial  distribution,  both 
qualitative  and  quantitative,  of  the  various  types  of  industrial  produc- 
tion over  a  given  region.  Thus,  the  Thiinen  and  Weberian  schools  have 
carved  out  for  themselves  separate,  non-overlapping  areas  of  inquiry. 
In  real  life,  of  course,  this  clear-cut  line  of  demarcation  in  locational 
decisions  disappears.  No  agricultural  producer  is  perfectly  immobile; 
he  quite  frequently  does  consider  changing  location.  Accordingly,  the 
Thiinen  scheme  is  insufficient  for  explaining  such  an  agriculturalist's 
decision.  Analysis  on  the  individual  level  is  also  required.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  Weberian  dogma  is  grossly  inadequate  for  the  over-all 
regional  type  of  industrial  planning  which  has  been  undertaken  in  the 
last  decade  or  two  by  international,  national,  and  regional  authorities. 
The  Thiinen  methodology  can  be  of  great  service  here.  The  task  ahead 
is  thus  to  conduct  analysis  at  each  level  of  inquiry  and  ultimately  to 
fuse  the  results  into  one  comprehensive  framework. ^  This  task  I  can 
hope  to  accomplish  only  partially  in  this  and  subsequent  chapters. 

It  is  also  desirable  at  this  point  to  consider  the  categories  of 
commodities  (embracing  factor  services)  which  have  grown  out 
of  Weber's  doctrines.  Commodities  have  been  classified  according  to 
mobility,  dispensability,  geographic  occurrence,  and  weight  loss.  We 
frequently  encounter  in  the  literature^  commodities  described  in  terms 
of  the  first  three  of  these  characteristics  and  thus  falling  into  one  of  the 
following  categories: 

1.  Indispensable,  single-source,  immobile  commodities 

2.  Indispensable,  single-source,  mobile  commodities 

3.  Indispensable,  many-source,  immobile  commodities 

4.  Indispensable,  many-source,  mobile  commodities 

5.  Dispensable,  single-source,  immobile  commodities 

6.  Dispensable,  single-source,  mobile  commodities 

7.  Dispensable,  many-source,  immobile  commodities 

8.  Dispensable,  many-source,  mobile  commodities 

This  classification  may  be  useful  for  certain  purposes.     From  our 

4  Compare  0.  Englander,  "Kritisches  und  Positives  zu  einer  allgemeinen  reinen 
Lehre  vom  Standort,"  Zeitschrift  filr  Volkswirtschaft  und  Sozialpolitik,  Neue 
Folge,  Vol.  V  (1926),  pp.  475-79. 

5  See,  for  example,  Dean  (Selections)   op.  cit.,  pp.  8-12. 


94  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

viewpoint,  however,  these  various  categories  can  be  reduced  to  a  series 
of  relations  which  involve  substitution,  both  in  the  large  and  small. 
Category  8  is  the  most  general.  Here,  three  explicit  types  of  substitu- 
tion possibilities  exist:  (1)  substitution  between  transport  inputs  and 
between  various  outlays  and  revenues  associated  with  the  use  of  any 
of  several  different  commodities  or  combinations  of  commodities  in  the 
production  process,  (2)  substitution  associated  with  the  use  of  any 
of  several  sources  of  any  one  commodity,  (3)  substitution  associated 
with  the  various  places  to  which  a  commodity  can  be  transported. 
The  fourth  characteristic  which  Weber  underscored,  namely,  weight 
loss  or  the  degree  to  which  the  weight  of  a  good  does  enter  into  the 
weight  of  the  finished  product,  also  lends  itself  to  a  substitution 
analysis  which  emphasizes  the  desirability  of  various  places  as  the  site 
of  production  according  to  transport  expense. 

Categories  1  to  7  can  be  viewed  as  special  cases  of  category  8,  each 
limiting  in  some  respect  the  range  of  substitution.  Thus,  when  a 
commodity  is  technically  indispensable  for  a  given  production  process 
(though  from  the  social-aggregative  standpoint,  no  commodity  is 
indispensable),  substitution  between  the  transport  inputs  and  outlays 
associated  with  the  location  of  the  given  commodity  and  those 
associated  with  the  location  of  a  potential  substitute  commodity  is 
non-existent.  When  only  one  deposit  or  locality  exists  as  a  source  of  a 
commodity  (as  is  rare  from  a  world-economic  standpoint),  then  the 
substitution  problem  connected  with  diverse  sources  disappears. 
Finally,  when  a  commodity  is  perfectly  immobile,  no  substitution 
problem  arises  in  connection  with  production  at  places  other  than 
sources  (or  points  of  consumption)  of  this  commodity.  Although,  to 
maintain  a  formal,  complete  substitution  framework  we  may,  as 
Englander  has  done,  eschew  from  our  analysis  the  attribute  of  mobility 
by  considering  immobile  commodities  to  be  goods  of  infinite  weight 
entailing  infinite  weight  loss  in  production  (or  consumption). ^ 

No  matter  what  scheme  of  classification  is  selected,  the  whole 
production  process,  as  Predohl  indicated,  may  be  conceived  as  a 
complex  substitution  problem  in  space,  involving  such  spatial  substi- 
tutions in  the  large  and  small  as  implied  by  the  above  classification 

6  A  strategic  and  rare  labor  skill  available  at  only  one  locality  might  in  the 
short  run  be  an  instance  of  a  service  faUing  in  category  1.  Category  2  would 
embrace  those  raw  materials  which  Weber  considers  in  the  early  part  of  his  book ; 
however,  as  soon  as  he  introduces  replacement  deposits,  the  goods  which  he 
treats  come  to  fall  in  category  4.  Categories  3  and  4  have  been  treated  by 
Palander  and  Hoover  in  their  supply  and  market  area  analyses,  and  to  some  extent 
at  least,  categories  5  to  8  in  their  more  generalized  analyses. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION       95 

as  well  as  those  substitutions  ordinarily  conceived  in  the  production 
theory  (and  consumption  theory)  of  a  one-point  economy. ''' 

2.     Transport-oriented  Equilibrium  Under  Simplified  Conditions 

We  commence  the  analysis  of  the  locational  equilibrium  of  the  firm 
under  the  simplifying  assumptions  that:  (1)  its  productive  activities 
do  not  affect  the  locus  of  consumption,  transport  rates,  prices  of  raw 
materials,  labor  and  other  factors  and  products,  and  agglomeration 
economies  and  other  locational  variables;  and  (2)  its  actions  do  not 
provoke  retaliatory  measures  by  other  producers. 

Assume  a  point  C  whereat  are  concentrated  all  consumers  of  the 
product  of  an  individual  firm.  Also  let  point  Mi  be  the  only  source 
of  a  raw  material  indispensable  for  the  production  of  the  good.    Other 

■^  Palander's  criticisms  of  Predohl's  principle  of  substitution  are  in  the  main 
unwarranted — or  at  least  are  unjustified  in  view  of  modern  developments  in  pro- 
duction theory.  (See  Tord  Palander,  Beitrage  zur  Standortstheorie,  Uppsala,  1935, 
pp.  254-61.)  Palander  has  first  of  all  underestimated  the  fruitfulness  of  decom- 
posing the  whole  production  problem  into  a  set  of  substitution  problems  between 
the  various  possible  pairs  of  spatially-defined  inputs  and  outputs — as  well  as  into 
a  set  of  substitution  problems  between  various  pairs  of  groups  of  these  spatially- 
defined  inputs  and  outputs.  Clearly,  Predohl  had  in  mind  the  substitution  prob- 
lems between  groups  of  commodities  (commodities  as  defined  in  our  broad  sense) 
and  those  between  possible  subgroups  when  he  concludes :  "Der  Standort  der  Pro- 
duktion  bzw.  Produktionsstufe  ist  also  bestimmt  durch  ein  System  von  Substi- 
tutionspunkten,  das  derart  gegliedert  ist,  dass  die  Gruppen  einer  ijbergeordneten 
Kombination  untergeordnete  Kombination  in  sich  enthalten"  ("Das  Standorts- 
problem  in  der  Wirtschaftstheorie,"  Weltwirtschaftliches  Archiv,  Band  XXI,  1925, 
pp.  306-7).  Such  substitution  analysis  between  groups,  subgroups,  and  pairs  of 
commodities  has  been  developed  by  Hicks  and  others  and  has  been  generally 
considered  to  be  feasible  and  of  value. 

Secondly,  Palander's  point  that  such  problems  as  scale  of  plant  are  excluded 
from  substitution  analysis  is  also  no  longer  valid.  For,  through  admitting  dis- 
continuities in  the  technical  transformation  function,  as  can  be  done,  variations 
in  scale  can  easily  be  treated,  being  viewed  as  sudden  large  and  jumpy  increases 
in  plant,  equipment,  and  the  like.  This  fact,  too,  overrides  Palander's  objection 
to  substitution  analysis  for  its  restriction  to  cases  of  continuous  variation  and 
its  failure  to  treat  such  important  discontinuous  variations  as  are  involved  in 
shifts  to  labor  locations  (a  problem  which  will  be  fully  discussed  at  a  later  point). 

Thirdly,  there  are  not  two  distinct  substitution  problems  as  Palander  maintains, 
one  between  the  various  factors  where  scale,  location,  and  prices  are  given,  and 
the  other  where  technique  (the  proportion  of  factors)  and  scale  are  fixed,  but 
where  production  is  free  to  adjust  to  the  spatial  variations  in  the  prices  of  factors 
and  products.  Fundamentally  decisions  in  both  of  these  categories  are  inter- 
related and  are  contained  within  the  over-all  substitution  problem  of  the  indi- 
vidual firm.  Further,  on  a  simple  two-dimensional  diagram,  changes  in  prices 
and  other  locational  variables  can  be  treated  together  with  changes  in  the  propor- 
tion of  factors. 


96  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

productive  factors  are  taken  to  be  ubiquitous,  available  everywhere 
in  the  correct  amounts  and  at  the  same  price.  ^    If  the  raw  material 

at  Ml  were  immobile,  such  as  ore  de- 

• — -•       posits,  then  the  productive   activity 

1  (mining)  would  be  at  Mi,  price  and 
Fig.  15.    A  locational  line.  profit    conditions    permitting.      Here, 

however,  we  assume  that  the  indispen- 
sable raw  material  is  mobile,  and,  further,  that  a  straight  line  rail- 
way connects  points  Mi  and  C.  See  Fig.  15.  Where  will  the  firm 
locate? 

Before  we  attempt  to  answer  this  question  it  is  wise  to  make  clear 
our  use  of  the  terms  transformation  function  and  transformation  line. 
We  conceive  the  transformation  function  to  embrace  the  numerous 
technical  substitution  relations  between  any  pair  of  outputs,  any 
input  and  any  output,  and  any  pair  of  inputs.  As  indicated  in  the 
preceding  chapter,  transport  inputs  are  viewed  as  any  other  set  of 
inputs  in  the  transformation-production  process.  They  substitute  for 
other  inputs  and  products. 

In  the  rest  of  this  section  and  in  Sect.  3,  we  reformulate  the  Weberian 
transport  orientation  doctrine.  In  this  doctrine,  the  weights  of  various 
raw  materials  and  the  market  demand  are  assumed  to  be  constant. 
Therefore,  variation  in  the  transport  input  variables  reduces  to 
variation  in  the  distances  over  which  the  raw  materials  and  finished 
product  must  move.  Hence,  a  transformation  relation  between  any 
two  transport  inputs  reduces  to  a  consistent  set  of  variations  in  two 
distance  variables.  In  what  follows  we  shall  view  the  relevant 
consistent  sets  of  variation  in  two  distance  variables  as  a  transforma- 
tion line  between  these  two  distance  variables,  although  the  trans- 
formation line  rigorously  speaking  has  reference  to  variation  in  the 
corresponding  transport  inputs.  The  reader,  however,  need  not  accept 
this  procedure.  He  can  deny  transformation  relations  between  distance 
variables,  and  proceed,  as  in  Sect.  4,  to  state  the  Weberian  dogma  in 
terms  of  transformation  relations  between  the  variable  transport  inputs. 
The  basic  analysis  and  conclusions,  however,  remain  unchanged. 

Returning  to  the  problem  of  Fig.  15,  we  observe  that  in  our  simple 
case  we  have  two  distance  variables,  (1)  distance  from  point  C  and 
(2)  distance  from  point  Mi.  When  we  plot  these  two  variables  on 
Fig.  16  we  obtain  a  straight  transformation  line  with  a  slope  of  —1. 
Of  course  it  is  possible  to  select  a  location  involving  unnecessary 

8  This  implies  that  none  of  the  inputs  and  outputs  of  the  transformation  func- 
tion changes  as  we  move  production  from  site  to  site  except  those  which  will  be 
associated  below  with  the  distance  variables. 


Distance  from  C 


Fig.  16.    A  transformation  line  for  the  line 

case. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION      97 

transportation,  i.e.,  a  point  not  on  line  MiC,  or  in  other  words,  a  set 
of  distances  from  points  C  and  Mj  lying  above  and  to  the  right  of  line 
VW  in  Fig.  16.  But  since  we 
assume  that  the  producer  min- 
imizes costs,  he  will  not  select 
a  location  involving  unneces- 
sary distance,  just  as  he 
will  not  employ  unnecessary 
labor.9 

Let  us  complicate  our  case. 
Production  now  requires  a 
second  raw  material  present 
at  only  one  source,  M2.  If 
this  good  is  both  indispensable 
and  immobile,  the  site  of  pro- 
duction, if  production  is  at  all 
feasible,  will  coincide  with  this 
source.  Where  this  second 
good  is  mobile,  for  each  pos- 
sible  (realistic)   distance  from 

M2,  there  exists  a  transformation  line  between  the  variables,  distance 
from  C  and  distance  from  Mi ;  and  for  each  possible  (realistic)  dis- 
tance from  Ml  there  exists  a  transformation  line  between  the  varia- 
bles, distance  from  C  and  distance  from  M2;  and  finally,  for  each 
possible  (realistic)  distance  from  C  there  exists  a  transformation  line 
between  the  variables,  distance  from  M^  and  distance  from  M2.  The 
exact  nature  of  all  the  transformation  lines  will,  of  course,  depend 
upon  the  relative  positions  of  Mj,  Ma,  and  C.  Take  an  example  where 
the  distances  between  C  and  M2,  C  and  Mi,  and  M2  and  Mi  are  8,  5, 
and  7  units  respectively  (Fig.  17) .  For  any  value,  let  us  say  3  units, 
of  the  variable  distance  from  C,  we  obtain  a  transformation  line  rep- 
resenting the  different  possible  sets  of  the  variables,  distance  from  Mi 
and  distance  from  AI2,  given  by  arc  TS,  the  locus  of  points  constructed 
with  a  radius  of  3  units  from  point  C.  The  transformation  line  turns 
out  to  be  convex  to  the  origin  Q  (Fig.  18) .  Obviously  this  transforma- 
tion line  contains  no  sets  of  variables  represented  by  points  outside 
the  triangle  CM1M2  of  Fig.  17.  That  would  be  covering  unnecessary 
distance. 

9  However,  as  we  shall  see  later,  when  discriminatory  transport  rates  nullify 
the  distance  principle  and  cause  the  cost  between  two  termini  to  be  less  than  that 
between  an  intermediate  point  and  one  of  the  termini,  it  is  quite  possible  for  an 
entrepreneur  to  choose  a  location  involving  unnecessary  distance  in  the  transfor- 
mation sense. 


98 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


Our  problem  becomes  still  more  complicated  when  we  introduce 
additional  indispensable  but  mobile  raw  materials,  each  obtainable 


Fig.  17.    A  locational  triangle. 

at  an  only  source.    Let  M3  represent  the  sole  source  of  a  third  indis- 
pensable but  mobile  raw  material.    Let  M 3  be  7  units  distant  from  C 


S 
T 

\ 

£ 

\ 

g 

\ 

0 

\ 

\ 

*M 

V 

01 

\ 

« 

^^^ 

- 

^--•T 

4^ 

X 

•iM 

Q 

—    1          1          1          1          1          1 

1           1 

Q 


Distance  from  M2 

Fig.  18.    A  transformation  line  for  the  triangle  case. 


and  2  units  from  Mo.  See  Fig.  19.  Here  we  must  pose  the  substitution 
question  somewhat  differently.  Ordinarily  we  would  hold  constant  all 
inputs  and  outputs  but  two  and  observe  the  substitution  relations 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION      99 

between  these  two.  Here,  if  we  assign  fixed  values  to  the  variables, 
distance  from  Mi  and  distance  from  M2,  say  RM^  and  RM2,  respec- 
tively, and  values  which  also  permit  a  location  at  point  R  within  the 
polygon  of  Fig.  19,  then  necessarily  the  values  of  the  other  two 
variables,  distance  from  C  and  distance  from  M3 ,  are  determined,  being 
RC  and  RM^,  respectively.  No  substitution  problem  arises.  The 
situation  would  resemble  one  emerging  under  the  ordinary  non-spatial 
conception  of  the  production  problem,  where  we  examine  the  substitu- 


FiG.  19.    A  four-sided  locational  polygon. 


tion  relations  between  two  factors,  each  for  technical  reasons  bearing 
a  fixed  relationship  to  another  factor  in  the  given  basket  of  commodi- 
ties.   There  would  be  no  possibility  of  substitution. 

However,  a  real  substitution  problem  does  exist  in  the  case  of  our 
polygon  of  Fig.  19.  The  entrepreneur  is  concerned  with  minimizing 
transport  expense.  He  will  move  to  a  new  position  if,  for  example,  the 
shorter  distance  from  C  lessens  his  transport  expense  by  more  than 
the  amount  which  the  increased  distance  from  M3  adds  to  his  transport 
expense,  the  summed  expenses  of  transporting  the  fixed  quantities  of 
raw  materials  from  M^  and  Mo  remaining  constant.  Hence,  given 
the  sum  to  be  expended  on  transport  to  consumption  place  and  from 
all  raw  material  sources  but  two,  what  are  the  technical  substitution 
relations  between  the  distance  variables  from  these  two  points?  Thus 
in  this  formulation  all  distances  are  variables,  although  the  values  of 
all  but  the  relevant  two  are  restrained  by  a  total  cost  condition  and 
although  all  distances  are  subject  to  the  obvious  condition  that  they 


100 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


be  measured  to  a  common  point,  the  production  point.  If,  for  example, 
as  in  Fig.  19,  we  assume  that  transport  cost  is  proportional  to 
distance  and  that  equal  weights  of  raw  materials  from  sources  Mi  and 
M2  are  required^^^  (simple  hypotheses  which  we  later  discard),  we  can 


L^- 


Q 


Distance  from  M3 

Fig.  20.    A  transformation  line  for  a  four-sided  polygon. 


indicate  the  locus  of  possible  sites  by  an  elliptical  curve  at  any  point 
on  which  the  sum  of  distance  from  M^  and  distance  from  M 2 ,  and  thus 
the  amount  expended  on  transport  from  M^  and  M2,  is  constant. 
From  this  curve  we  obtain  the  transformation  line  of  Fig.  20,  which 
represents  the  possible  sets  of  values  for  the  variables,  distance  from 

10  Obviously  in  reality  the  weights  of  raw  materials  to  be  transported  from 
various  sources  are  of  different  magnitude,  and  the  transport  tariffs  vary  from 
raw  material  to  raw  material  as  well  as  for  longer  and  shorter  distances.  But, 
given  any  set  of  real  information,  we  can  construct  theoretically  and  the  entre- 
preneur can  calculate  empirically  a  curve  of  constant  transport  costs  to  or  from 
all  points  but  two. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     101 

C  and  distance  from  M3.11  Similarly,  we  can  obtain  a  transformation 
line  for  these  same  two  variables  if  a  different  total  amount  is  to  be 
expended  on  transporting  the  fixed  quantities  of  raw  materials  from 
Ml  and  M2  respectively.  And  likewise  we  can  obtain  transformation 
lines  for  any  two  of  the  possible  distance  variables,  given  the  sum 
to  be  spent  on  transport  of  given  amounts  of  raw  materials  and  product 
from  other  sources  or  to  the  consumption  place.  This  same  procedure 
can  be  extended  to  the  cases  where  we  have  4,  5,  6,  .  .  .,  n  raw  materials 
and  consumption  places.  12 

Thus  far  we  have  tacitly  assumed  that  transport  facilities  of  uniform 
cost  character  radiate  in  all  directions  from  all  points  and  thus  cover 
the  entire  plane  under  consideration.  We  drop  this  assumption,  and 
for  the  time  being  adopt  a  less  abstract  one.  Within  any  locational 
polygon  transport  facilities  of  uniform  cost  character  are  taken  to 
connect  a  finite  number  of  points  with  all  or  some  of  the  corners  of 
that  polygon.  For  simplicity  we  assume  that:  (1)  on  arc  TS  of  Fig.  17 
only  points  T,  J,  H,  and  S  can  be  considered  as  possible  production 
sites  because  of  the  limited  transport  facilities;  and  (2)  these  points 
are  connected  by  straight  transport  lines  to  each  corner  of  the  triangle. 
We  have  at  once  injected  discontinuity  into  our  spatial  model.  Given 
the  parametric  value  of  3  units  for  the  variable  distance  from  C,  the 
corresponding  transformation  line  for  the  two  variables,  distance  from 
Ml  and  distance  from  M2,  degenerates  into  a  series  of  points  which 
can  be  connected  by  straight  lines  with  different  slopes  and  which  we 
shall  continue  to  call  a  transformation  line.    See  Fig.  21. 

Paralleling  an  established  procedure  in  production  analysis,  we  now 
desire  information  about  the  prices  or  costs  of  every  pair  of  variables. 

11  It  should  be  noted  that  beyond  both  points  K  and  L  the  transformation  Hne 
of  Fig.  20  turns  back  on  itself;  both  variables  increase  as  we  move  respectively  to 
the  right  of  K'  and  to  the  left  of  L'  on  the  elHptical  curve  of  Fig.  19.  Theoretically 
such  movement  involves  unnecessary  distance  and  would  not  happen ;  realistically, 
as  we  shall  see,  this  can  occur. 

12  It  should  be  reiterated  that  the  substitutions  are  subject  to  a  spatial  restraint. 
The  values  assigned  to  the  distances  of  the  production  site  from  the  several  raw 
material  sources  and  from  the  consumption  place  (s)  must  be  spatially  (geometri- 
cally) consistent.  A  change  in  one  of  the  two  distance  variables  in  general  not 
only  involves  a  change  in  the  second  distance  variable  under  consideration  but 
almost  invariably  necessitates  changes  in  the  parametric  values  of  at  least  some 
of  the  other  distances.  Here  then  we  cannot  speak  of  a  "fixed  basket"  of  goods. 
And  in  order  to  obtain  a  meaningful  substitution  relation  between  the  two  variable 
distances  in  question  we  need  to  nullify  the  effects  of  changes  in  the  other  dis- 
tances by  imposing  a  total  cost  restraint  upon  the  transport  of  all  items  over 
these  other  distances. 


102 


LOCATION  AKD  SPACE-ECONOMY 


With  these  prices  and  costs  we  can  derive  the  price-ratio  lines  (a  la 
Hicks)  which  together  with  the  technical  relations  depicted  by  the 
various  transformation  lines  allow  us  to  determine  a  partial  locational 
equilibrium  position. 


Q  G  E  B 

Distance  from  M2 

Fig.  21.    Locational   equilibrium:    discontinuous   transformation   line. 

Before  we  can  identify  the  costs  associated  with  the  two  variables, 
distance  from  Mi  and  distance  from  Mo,  we  must  know:  (1)  the 
weight  of  each  of  the  raw  materials  to  be  transported;  and  (2)  the 
transport  rate(s).  For  the  locational  problem  depicted  in  Fig.  17, 
assume  that  1  ton  of  the  first  raw  material  must  be  transported  from 
source  M^ ,  that  1  ton  of  the  second  raw  material  must  be  transported 
from  source  M2,  and  that  the  transport  rate  on  these  commodities  is 
the  same  and  is  proportional  to  distance.  As  a  consequence,  the  trans- 
port charge  per  unit  of  distance  which  is  associated  with  each  distance 
variable  is  identical.  It  then  follows  that  the  various  price-ratio  lines 
for  these  two  distance  variables  must  be  straight  and  must  have  a 
slope  of  —1.    Two  such  lines  are  EF  and  BD  of  Fig.  21. 

The  transformation  line  of  Fig.  21  and  the  derived  price-ratio  lines 
yield  point  J  as  a  partial  equilibrium  position.  This  follows  since  J 
is  that  realistic  point  on  the  transformation  line  TS  which  lies  on  the 
lowest  possible  price-ratio  (iso-outlay)  line.     This  lowest  line  is  EF. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     103 

Note  that  at  J  the  following  conditions  are  satisfied:  (1)  to  the  right 
of  J  the  price-ratio  line  is  steeper  than  the  transformation  line;  and 
(2)  to  the  left  of  J  the  same  price-ratio  line  is  less  steep  than  the 
transformation  line.^^ 

However,  what  if  we  allow  the  distance  from  C  to  vary?  Taking  as 
fixed  the  distance  from  M2  consistent  with  location  at  point  J,  we  can 
construct  a  transformation  line  for  the  variables,  distance  from  Mi 
and  distance  from  C.  And,  knowing  the  transport  rate  structure, 
which  for  the  present  we  shall  take  to  be  the  simple  one  described 
above,  we  can  construct  price-ratio  lines  and  determine  the  partial 
equilibrium  position  for  these  two  variables.  Presumably,  this  new 
(and  better)  partial  equilibrium  position  will  be  consistent  for  a  value 
of  the  variable  distance  from  C  different  from  that  assumed  in  the 
preceding  paragraph  and  in  Fig.  21.  As  a  consequence,  the  transforma- 
tion line  between  the  variables,  distance  from  M-^  and  distance  from 
M2,  changes,  and  therefore  it  may  be  necessary  to  find  a  new  partial 
equilibrium  position  with  respect  to  these  two  variables.  And  so  this 
process  continues.  We  finally  reach  a  "full"  equilibrium  position 
when  the  three  partial  equilibrium  positions  with  respect  to  (1) 
distance  from  C  and  distance  from  Afi,  (2)  distance  from  C  and  dis- 
tance from  M2,  and  (3)  distance  from  Mj  and  distance  from  M2 
coincide.    Here  there  will  be  no  tendency  to  alter  any  of  the  values 

13  When  the  variables,  distance  from  M\  and  distance  from  M2  (or  more  strictly 
speaking  the  corresponding  two  transport  input  variables),  are  considered  as  com- 
modities r  and  s  (and  as  commodities  are  expressed  as  negative  quantities  since 
they  correspond  to  inputs)  and  when  the  graphical  solution  is  approached  from 
an  origin  from  which  positive  quantities  of  these  commodities  are  measured,  the 
stated  inequalities  have  to  be  reversed.  And  in  mathematical  terms,  we  have:  (1) 
to  the  left  of  the  partial  equilibrium  point,  -prlps  >  —  Ay^/  Ayr]  and  (2)  to  the 
right  of  the  partial  equilibrium  point,  pr/ps  <  —  Ays/  Ayr,  where  Ayr  and  Ays 
are  finite  changes  in  the  quantities  of  the  commodities  r  and  s  when  one  moves 
from  the  partial  equilibrium  point  to  a  point  representing  the  next  possible  site 
of  production  in  the  relevant  direction  along  arc  TS,  and  pr  and  ps  are  respectively 
the  transport  charges  per  unit  distance  on  the  raw  materials  from  Mi  and  M2 
required  for  the  production  of  a  unit  of  output. 

In  this  situation,  where  a  transformation  line  consists  of  only  a  finite  number 
of  points,  twin  partial  solutions  may  be  possible  for  any  pair  of  distance  variables. 
This  possibility  will  occur  if  the  slope  of  the  price-ratio  line  is  the  same  as  that 
of  the  segment  connecting  two  consecutive  points  of  the  transformation  line,  each 
of  which  lies  on  the  lowest  of  the  price-ratio  lines  which  course  through  points 
of  the  transformation  line.  A  certain  degree  of  indeterminacy  is  thus  introduced 
into  the  over-all  solution.  But  this  indeterminacy  is  not  a  major  consideration  in 
view  of  the  analysis  to  come.  The  reader  can  easily  restate  the  graphic  and 
mathematical  conditions  for  a  twin  solution. 

Also  see  Samuelson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  70-74  for  a  treatment  of  discontinuities  in  the 
production  function. 


104  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

of  the  variables.    Each  partial  equilibrium  position  must  satisfy  the 
two  conditions  stated  above. ^^ 

Although  we  have  dealt  with  only  a  triangle  of  raw  material  sources 
and  consumption  place,  this  procedure  is  applicable  to  any  polygon 
of  such  sources  and  place.  In  the  case  of  a  four-  or  more-sided  polygon, 
we  do  not  hold  constant  all  distance  variables  but  two,  but  only  the 
total  transport  expenditure  upon  these  other  distance  variables.  We 
then  find  the  partial  equilibrium  position  with  respect  to  these  two 
variables.  When  there  are  n  distance  variables,  there  are  of  course 
%n(n  —1)  partial  equilibrium  points.  At  a  full  equilibrium  position 
all  of  these  coincide. 

3.     Transport-oriented  Equilibrium  with 
Realistic  Rate  Structures 

Having  described  locational  equilibrium  under  extremely  simple 
conditions,  we  commence  now  to  introduce  various  real  complexities, 
especially  those  dealing  with  transport  rate  structure  and  costs. 

We  abandon  the  postulate  that  equal  weights  of  raw  materials  or 
product  are  transported  from  the  various  sources  and  to  the  consump- 
tion place.  Our  price-ratio  lines  need  no  longer  cut  the  horizontal 
and  vertical  axes  symmetrically ;  they  can  cut  these  axes  at  any  angle 
depending  upon  the  relative  weights  of  the  raw  materials  moved. 
Suppose,  for  example,  that  the  production  of  II/2  tons  of  final  product 
requires  1  ton  of  the  first  raw  material  (from  M^)  and  2  tons  of  second 
raw  material  (from  M2).  Retaining  a  pure  weight  and  distance 
basis  for  computing  the  transport  cost  schedule,  we  obtain  a  new 
series  of  price-ratio  lines  with  different  slope.  Of  this  new  series  line 
GL  in  Fig.  21  is  the  relevant  one  for  the  circumstances  represented 
there.  Point  H  rather  than  point  J  becomes  the  partial  equilibrium 
position  for  the  two  variables,  distance  from  Mi  and  distance  from  M2. 
Similarly,  the  other  partial  equilibrium  points  and  the  final  equilibrium 
position  will  be  altered  by  the  change  in  relative  weights.  ^^ 

i"*  Except  for  qualifications  relating  to  twin  solutions  noted  in  footnote  13. 

We  also  have  assumed  in  our  simple  case  that  the  dynamic  postulates  implied 
by  our  iterative  procedure  do  not  lead  to  an  oscillatory  situation. 

15  Save  in  one  respect  the  problems  of  this  paragraph  resemble  Weber's :  fixed 
points  indicate  the  consumption  place  and  raw  material  sources,  unequal  weights 
are  transported  from  the  several  sources  to  the  production  site  and  from  there  to 
the  consumption  place,  and  transport  tariffs  are  based  solely  on  weight  and  dis- 
tance. His  analysis,  though  later  quahfied  (op.  cit.,  pp.  82-83  and  elsewhere) 
assumes  a  uniform  transport  system  completely  flexible,  i.e.,  uniform  transport 
facilities  radiating  from  all  points  in  all  directions.  His  is  a  case  of  continuous 
variation  of  all  distance  variables.  Ours,  thus  far,  is  one  of  simple  discontinuous 
variation. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION    105 

Of  still  greater  moment  is  the  relaxation  of  our  assumption  that 
transport  rates  are  proportional  to  distance,  an  assumption  which  is 
valid  only  for  areas  where  primitive  transport  mechanisms  still  operate. 
In  industrialized  areas  modern  transport  media  require  large  overhead 
expenditures  and  incur  many  costs  and  offer  many  services  (especially 
terminal)  which  are  unrelated  to  the  distance  covered  in  a  given 
shipment.  Typically,  tariff  per  distance  unit  or  zone  is  steep  for  the 
first  zone  and  falls  abruptly  from  the  first  to  the  second  zone  and 
considerably  less  abruptly  between  each  succeeding  zone  (or  set  of 
zones)  and  the  one  after.  Tariff  structures  are  graduated,  rates  being 
less  than  proportional  to  distance.  ^^ 

One  can  best  demonstrate  the  significance  of  typical  modern  rate 
structures  for  the  spatial  equilibrium  of  the  firm  by  constructing 
appropriate  price-ratio  lines  or  iso-outlay  lines.  We  utilize  the  1945 
standard  maximum  first  class  rates  on  freight  shipments  prescribed 
by  the  I.C.C.  for  railroads  operating  in  the  Eastern  Territory. ^"^  On 
the  basis  of  2  short  tons  of  raw  material  from  source  M2  and  1  ton 
from  source  Mi  per  ton  product,  we  have  constructed,  in  Fig.  22, 
price-ratio  or  iso-outlay  lines  corresponding  to  outlays  of  $24.00, 
$26.40,  and  $30.00.18 

Several  characteristics  of  these  iso-outlay  lines  are  important  to 
note.  First,  in  effect,  they  are  not  lines  but  a  series  of  rectangles  and 
squares  which  have  been  blacked  in.  These  rectangles  and  squares 
border  each  other  or  are  connected  by  dashed  lines.  This  particular 
form  of  iso-outlay  line  results  from  the  zonal  character  of  the  rate 
structure.  For  example,  the  rate  for  a  shipment  of  a  given  weight 
is  the  same  for  all  distances  40  miles  or  less  but  greater  than  35  miles. 
Hence,  if  we  consider  two  shipments  of  different  goods  and  weights, 
we  find  that  total  cost  of  these  shipments  will  not  vary  for  any 
combination  of  distances  for  these  two  shipments  which  can  be 
represented  by  a  point  lying  within  a  square  (such  as  square  A  of 
Fig.  22)  which  is  bounded  on  two  sides  by  two  40-mile  lines  and  on 

16  For  further  details,  see  E.  M.  Hoover,  The  Location  of  Economic  Activity, 
New  York,  1948,  Chaps.  2-4. 

'^'^  As  published  in  I.C.C.  Docket  15879  Appendix  E  and  as  given  in  The  Freight 
Traffic  Red  Book,  New  York,  1945,  pp.  1194^95  in  the  column  Appendix  E  under 
Eastern  Class  Rates. 

18  Along  each  axis  of  Fig.  22  we  measure  mileage  from  the  respective  source 
and  also  cost  of  transporting  over  the  different  distances  the  amounts  of  raw  ma- 
terials required  per  ton  of  output.  The  $30.00  line,  for  example,  shows  the  various 
combinations  of  values  for  distance  from  Mi  and  distance  from  M2  which  would 
occasion  a  total  transport  outlay  on  the  raw  materials  from  Mi  and  M2  of  $30.00 
per  ton  of  product. 


106 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


6         6 

1 

o          o 

i      1     1 

^                    MM 

ts      ^    '-s 

S                bO           bfl 

-s      .a     9 

-g     ^ 

g" 

<u            d         d 

■S             o         O 

§ 

^      t    t 

listi( 

con 
con 

1 

03                      !-i                u, 

1 

S         <2      ^ 

0 

ro          j^ 

/ 

[uilibrii 

for  2  1 

(miles; 
for  1 
(miles; 

/I 

ational  eq 

t  cost  ($) 
from  M2 

t  cost  ($) 
from  Ml 

1        g- 

2.    Loc 

scales : 

ranspor 

istance 

-anspor 

istance 

0/ 

1        » 

<^^.      oHQHfi 

/ 1 
/  1 

6      -^  ,-v  ^-.  ^-v  0 

1 

1 

n 

ft: 

•    • 

Ji 

1       » 

/    1 
/   F 

d     d   : 

/ 

/   m         p 

P     - 

/ 

dJ       ^' 

f       \ 

/ 

^.j 

■'    ,eP'<eP      : 

/i, 

10 

?  rf^ipP 

; 

J  s,  ,  ,  ,  ,  c  wy 

1 , , 

i  1     *l 

,  n  ,  ,  n  ,  , 

- 

(a) 

30.00 
29.20 
28.80 
28.00 
27.60 
26.80 
26.40 
25.60 

11 

iiliiliiii 

iliii 

0^91 

08'SI 
09St 
OSSI 
OOSI 
09-;'I 

ovn 

OOH 
08-SI 
Ot'-EI 
OSEI 
08'ZT 
OVZl 
OO'ZI 
09'II 
OSII 
OOIl 
0801 
0901 
OfOI 
OZOI 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     107 

the  other  two  sides  by  two  lines  approaching  the  limit  of  35  miles. 
Thus  the  producer  may  have  some  leeway  in  choosing  a  rational 
location  and  may  select  a  site  which  compels  him  to  traverse  "unneces- 
sary distance"  (in  terms  of  the  minimum  quantities  hypothesized  in 
the  transformation  function)  without  increasing  his  costs. ^  9 

Second,  because  the  rate  structure  is  graduated,  the  iso-outlay  lines 
tend  to  be  convex  to  origin  Q,  as  in  Fig.  22.  This  fact  has  significant 
implications.  Frequently,  price-ratio  or  iso-outlay  lines  are  taken 
to  be  straight  or  concave  to  the  origin.  One  then  obtains  a  unique 
stable  solution  that  involves  quantities  of  both  inputs,  when,  as  is 
usually  the  case,  the  transformation  curve  is  convex  to  the  origin  from 
which  positive  quantities  of  inputs  are  measured.  If  both  the  trans- 
formation line  and  iso-outlay  line  are  irregularly  convex  to  the  origin, 
particularly  if  the  latter  is  more  convex  than  the  former,  as  it  may 
well  be  with  modern  rate  structures,  then  the  equilibrium  point  is 
likely  to  be  an  "end"  point,  that  is,  a  realistic  point  on  one  of  the  ends 
of  the  transformation  line  and  one  which  also  may  correspond  to  a 
corner  of  the  locational  polygon.  The  equilibrium  point  always  is  an 
end  point  in  the  case  where  the  locational  polygon  collapses  to  a  line, 
e.g.,  where  there  is  only  one  raw  material  used  in  the  production 


process 


20 


Further,  tl\e  likelihood  of  an  end  point  solution  is  considerably 
increased  by  the  fact  that  modern  rate  structures  call  for  a  relatively 
large  increment  in  shipping  charges  from  the  zero  (i.e.,  not  shipping 
at  all)  to  the  first  zone  and  relatively  small  increment  for  any  other 
two  successive  zones.  For  example,  on  the  horizontal  scale  of  Fig.  22 
transport  cost  for  1  ton  of  the  raw  material  from  M^  rises  $6.00  if  one 
decides  to  ship  1  mile  instead  of  zero  miles,  but  rises  only  20  cents  if 
one  decides  to  ship  6  miles  instead  of  5.  As  a  result  price-ratio  or 
iso-outlay  lines  have  "tails"  on  both  ends.  Our  $30.00  and  $26.40  lines 
have  respectively  the  vertical  stretches  LM  and  BG  as  tails  on  the 
left.21     Their  tails  on  the  right  (horizontal  stretches)  are  not  shown 

19  Such  a  minor  degree  of  indeterminacy  also  appears  with  respect  to  the  quan- 
tities of  other  factor  inputs  employed  when  these  inputs  are  sold  in  lot  quantities 
which  are  not  divisible,  as  where  the  services  of  a  machine  are  rented  by  the 
month.  The  analysis  is  not  seriously  qualified,  even  though  the  typical  mathe- 
matical solution  imphes  unique  amounts  of  inputs. 

-^  In  this  case,  the  transformation  line  is  a  straight  line  or  consists  of  a  number 
of  realistic  points  lying  on  a  straight  line.  Compare  Dean,  op.  cit.,  pp.  17-18.  Also 
see  the  Appendix  to  this  chapter  for  some  discussion  of  the  simple  line  case. 

21  In  the  case  of  our  $30.00  line,  a  decision  not  to  ship  the  raw  material  from 
Ml  at  all  instead  of  to  ship  it  to  a  point  within  5  miles  permits  a  saving  of  $6.00 
or  allows  the  movement  of  the  raw  material  from  source  M2  over  an  additional 
90  miles  without  increasing  transport  cost.    Thus,  the  tail  LM. 


108  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

in  Fig.  22,  above,  since  they  extend  beyond  the  limits  of  the  diagram. 

In  Fig.  22  we  have  constructed  the  transformation  line,  BEFDC. 
Point  B  corresponds  to  the  som-ce  of  Mi ;  it  represents  a  zero  value 
for  the  variable  distance  from  M^ .  At  point  D  the  usual  equilibrium 
conditions  are  satisfied  since  to  the  left  of  D  the  arithmetic  slope  of  the 
iso-outlay  line  ($30.00)  is  less  than  that  of  the  transformation  line, 
and,  to  the  right  of  D,  the  arithmetic  slope  of  the  former  exceeds  that 
of  the  latter.  However,  D  is  only  a  relative  minimum  transport  cost 
point.  Only  in  contrast  to  the  points  in  its  own  neighborhood  does  it 
represent  the  most  desirable  combination  of  values  for  the  distance 
variables.  End  point  B,  lying  on  the  tail  GB,  is  still  more  desirable 
for  it  falls  on  the  $26.40  iso-outlay  line  not  on  the  $30.00  one.  In  the 
given  situation  and  for  this  pair  of  values  for  the  distance  variables, 
B  represents  the  position  of  stable  equilibrium. 

Thus,  our  technique  clearly  demonstrates  the  strategy  of  locating 
at  corners  of  the  locational  polygon,  given  modern  transport  rate 
structures.  2  2  It  is  consistent  with  the  emphasis  that  Palander, 
Hoover,  and  others^s  have  given  to  such  location  and  the  minor 
importance  they  have  attached  to  locations  intermediate  between  raw 
material  sources  and  market  centers.  It  implies  that  the  individual 
producer  must  not  be  content  with  an  equilibrium  position  arrived  at 
by  the  usual  substitution  operations  conceived  in  production  theory, 
but  must  compare  the  spatial  equilibrium  so  obtained  with  each 
possible  relative  minimum  transport  cost  position  which  corresponds 
to  a  zero  value  for  one  of  the  distance  variables.  2-± 

We  pause  to  consider  a  significant  aspect  of  our  technique.  One 
of  the  most  devastating  shortcomings  of  the  Weberian  model  has  been 
its  inability  to  encompass  realistic  transport  rate  structures  less  than 

22  In  situations  where  neither  one  raw  material  nor  the  market  is  dominant  (in 
Weber's  sense)  so  that  locational  polygons  are  meaningful  constructs,  it  should 
not  be  inferred  that  relative  minimum  points  will  never  exist  at  corners  of  these 
polygons  unless  there  is  a  large  initial  increment  followed  by  relatively  small 
increments  in  the  rate  structure.  Palander  (op.  cit.,  pp.  314-16)  has  demonstrated 
that  relative  minima  may  occur  at  corners  of  polygons  when  a  tariff  structure 
mildly  graduated  from  beginning  to  end  is  in  vogue.  However,  the  advantage  of 
corner  location  is  generally  not  so  pronounced  with  such  a  structure. 

23  Palander,  op.  cit.,  pp.  198-99,  330-33;  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  pp.  52-57;  and  B.  Ohlin, 
Interregional  and  International  Trade,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1933,  pp.  185-202. 

24  Making  this  comparison  is  not  so  difficult  as  might  appear.  When  any  distance 
variable  is  assigned  a  zero  value,  the  values  of  the  other  distance  variables  are 
uniquely  determined.  Thus  the  producer  need  only  calculate  the  total  transport 
cost  for  each  comer  of  his  locational  polygon  and  for  whatever  relative  minimum 
cost  points  (in  the  usual  case,  only  one)  which  may  be  determined  through  spatial 
substitution  within  the  locational  polygon. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     109 

proportional  to  distance.  Weber  proposed  to  take  account  of  such 
rate  structures  by  using  fictitious  distances.  Distances  should  not  be 
stated  in  their  geographic  length,  but  in  proportion  to  the  decreasing 
rate  scale.  In  general  the  longer  the  distance,  the  more  it  should  be 
shortened  for  geometrical  analysis.  ^  5  Bortkiewicz  early  showed  that 
such  a  procedure  is  inconsistent  with  the  construction  of  a  locational 
polygon. 2  6  For,  how  can  we  know  how  much  to  shorten  the  distance 
of  any  corner  of  the  locational  polygon  from  the  given  site  of 
production  and  thus  be  able  to  calculate  the  relative  distances  between 
the  various  corners  of  the  locational  polygon  until  the  actual  location  of 
the  production  site  is  determined;  whilst  on  the  other  hand  the  very 
location  of  the  production  site  is  dependent  upon  the  relative  distances 
between  the  various  corners  of  the  locational  polygon? 

It  is  just  this  Weberian  dilemma  that  our  present  technique  cuts 
through.  We  need  not  speak  of  fictitious  distances  nor  are  we  bound 
to  a  geometrical  technique  applicable  only  to  situations  where  rates 
are  proportional  to  distance,  ^'i'  Further,  our  technique  brings  out  the 
critical  importance  of  terminal  and  loading  charges  which  the  Weberian 
analysis  essentially  sidesteps. 

25  We  quote  Weber:  ".  .  .  Die  sinkenden  Staffelungen  der  Siitze  mit  wachsender 
Entfernung  machen  dabei  keine  Schwierigkeiten  ....  Man  hat  sich  zu  sagen,  dass 
kartenmassige  Entfernungen  bei  Vorhandensein  solcher  Staffelungen  nicht  mit 
ihrer  tatsachlichen  Lange  in  die  Rechnung  einzustellen  sind,  sondern  unter  Reduk- 
tion  derselben  entsprechend  den  sinkenden  Staffeln.  Wird  also,  wie  beim  deu- 
tschen  Stiickguttarif  der  allgemeinen  Klasse,  fiir  50  Kilometer  ein  Satz  von  11 
Pfg.,  fiir  die  nachsten  150  km  einer  von  10,  fiir  weitere  100  km  von  9  Pfg.  usw. 
berechnet,  so  ist  dabei  eine  Strecke  von  100  km  nicht  mit  ihrer  vollen  Lange, 
sondern  mit  50  +  (50  —  50/11)  km,  also  mit  95,4  km  einzustellen  .  .  ."  {o-p.  cit., 
pp.  43-44). 

26  L.  Von  Bortkiewicz,  "Eine  geometrische  Fundierung  der  Lehre  vom  Standort 
der  Industrien,"  Archiv  fiir  Sozialwissenschaft  und  Sozialpolitik,  Vol.  XXX  (1910), 
pp.  769-71.  On  this  point  Niederhauser's  defense  of  Weber  {op.  cit.,  pp.  173-75) 
is  not  convincing. 

^"^  In  one  sense  Weber  should  not  be  criticized  too  severely  for  failing  to  realize 
the  inconsistency  in  his  geometrical  construction.  At  the  time  of  his  writing  the 
German  rate  structure  (although  not  the  French,  British,  United  States,  and  Bel- 
gian, among  others)  was  proportional  to  distance,  save  for  small  consignments 
and  a  few  bulky  goods,  and  was  quite  uniform  (refer  to  M.  Colson,  Transports 
et  Tarijs,  3rd  ed.,  1907) ;  and  Weber,  as  he  frequently  stated,  was  preoccupied 
with  conditions  of  the  German  economy.  On  the  other  hand,  Weber  was  explicitly 
attempting  to  erect  a  pure  theoretical  model  applicable  to  all  times  and  all  regions. 

We  should  mention  that  when  the  transport  rate  structure  is  not  proportional 
to  weight,  it  is  perfectly  admissible,  though  we  do  not  do  so,  to  make  adjustments 
as  Weber  does  {op.  cit.,  pp.  44-46).  A  rate  per  ton-mile  greater  than  normal  for 
a  given  good,  whatever  the  reason,  implies  an  "ideal"  weight  greater  than  actual; 
a  rate  below  normal  implies  an  "ideal"  weight  less  than  actual. 


110  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Returning  to  the  main  thread  of  the  argument,  we  find  it  also  possible 
to  account  for  the  effects  of  breaks  in  transport  routes,  which  charac- 
teristically occur  at  transport  junctions  where  the  direction  of 
movement  has  to  be  changed,  where  the  shipment  has  to  be  unloaded 
and  reloaded  onto  another  transport  medium  or  system,  or  where 
another  scale  of  transport  charges  becomes  effective,  and  so  forth. 
To  pass  over  such  breaks  entails  sudden  large  increments  in  transport 
cost,  whether  due  to  switching,  to  loading,  or  to  other  charges.  Industry 
often  locates  at  such  breaks  in  order  to  avoid  these  large  increments. 
This  is  borne  out  by  Fig.  23.  Here  we  assume  a  break  in  a  given 
transport  route  100  miles  from  each  of  the  two  sources  M^  and  M2. 
Along  each  axis  is  measured  the  cost  of  transporting  over  various 
distances  the  amount  of  raw  material  from  the  respective  source 
which  is  required  to  produce  1  ton  of  finished  product.  If  there  were 
no  break  in  the  transport  route  we  would  have  a  cost  scale  along  each 
axis  similar  to  that  on  Fig.  22.  But  a  break  does  exist,  and  to  pass 
over  it  involves  an  added  cost  of  50  cents  per  ton  of  raw  material 
from  M2  and  60  cents  per  ton  of  raw  material  from  Mi .  Accordingly 
we  have  added  another  scale  (the  outer  one)  of  transport  charges  for 
various  distances  along  each  axis  after  the  hundred-mile  mark.  At 
point  F,  the  graphic  position  of  the  break,  the  raw  materials  can  be 
assembled  from  both  sources  Mj  and  ilf  2  without  either  one's  bearing 
the  added  expense  of  passing  over  the  break.  The  total  transport  cost 
is  $33.60,  and  we  have  constructed  the  iso-outlay  line  of  $33.60.^8 
We  have  also  inscribed  a  transformation  line  GFJEH.  If  no  break 
existed,  the  equilibrium  point  would  be  G  where  the  transformation 
line  would  meet  the  tail  end  of  the  iso-outlay  line  of  $32.80.  But 
because   there   is    a    break,   which   necessitates   additional   transport 

28  In  constructing  this  iso-outlay  line  we  have  assumed  that  to  reach  points 
other  than  the  break  itself  one  of  the  raw  materials  must  pass  over  the  break. 
Obviously  the  other  must  travel  less  than  100  miles  in  this  case  since  the  line 
goes  through  the  break  itself  and  since  we  have  taken  it  to  be  regular  in  its  course. 

For  the  case  where  both  materials  traverse  distances  greater  than  100  miles  to 
any  place  where  they  are  assembled,  we  need  to  know  for  each  potential  site 
whether  both  pass  over  the  break  or,  if  only  one  does  so,  which  one.  However, 
complications  arise  as  soon  as  we  introduce  alternative  routes  from  raw  material 
sources  to  any  potential  site,  or  to  alternative  transshipment  points  varying  in 
distance  from  each  source,  or  to  both.  Then  the  iso-outlay  Hues  tend  to  be  highly 
irregular  and  tend  to  criss-cross  one  another.  We  can  avoid  considerable  irregu- 
larity by  excluding  from  the  analysis  certain  potential  sites  which  are  known  to 
be  inferior  for  any  number  of  reasons — such  perhaps  as  those  involving  unneces- 
sary distance.  Or,  alternatively,  we  can  derive  the  best  equilibrium  position  for 
each  transshipment  point  or  route  or  both  and  then  compare  these  sites  and  select 
the  optimum  one. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     111 


- 

(D              03 

(B 

(D 

! 

O               O 

1 

a 

fl         d 

fj 

j3 

ci           d 

-u          -ij 

S2 

-2 

22 

22 

";      1 

>i 

^         ^ 

t3 

t3 

i   ^ 

tc 

bC          bC 

bC 

bO 

-u 

fl         .9 

_d 

d 

1 

O 

^         t3 

'5 

"5 

H 

d         d 

d 

d 

03 

o         o 

o 

o 

1 

&        & 

& 

1 

U 

<U              CD 

<D 

(U 

!-                  H 

S-, 

tH 

1 

d 

o         o 

O 

"^ 

o          o 

o 

s 

-^ 

!-,               !- 

j^ 

.^ 

»              l-s^ 

S 

^             ^ 

o 

o 

CD 

S-. 

J2 

a 

3      § 
3      3 

J 

d 

o 

1 

0) 

2- 

1^ 

^ 

3            / 
-           / 

p^ 

s  .  s 

^-s^ 

s 

^          4 

J 

"cS 

-to    3   +:. 

_   -^  M 

_^ 

p 

~ 

•2 

g  g  s 

2 

8 

^ 

^            / 

J 

cS 

-to 

J 

i 

d  -^   d 

J    d  J 

1 

a>                        /     F 

a 

d 

o3 

:S 

1                      /i 

?5 

o 

£« 

qhS 

H 

^ 

5          "=]  1 

d 

S        /r^ 

f£! 

^ 

5      S 

S  3 

-3 

K> 

/ 

^ 

y 

F 

- 

y^ 

1 
P 

o 

^ 

/^ 

1 

r 

_j 

/^ 

» 

1 

,       -^ 

>    1    1 

p 



^ 

0861 


08il    0I'-8I 


0f'-9I 

OOil 

08-91 

ofr-ei 

09SI 

0Z-9I 

OZSI 

08-SI 

OOSI 

09BI 

osn 

02BI 

ovn 

OOSI 

con 

09M 

08£l 

Ot-fl 

OKEl 

oon 

OZEI 

08EI 

08'SI 

0t'-£I 

orzi 

OOEI 

oo-zi 

09SI 

091 1 

OZSI 

oett 

GO- 1 1 
0801 
0901 
0*01 

osot 

50  OOOO  O  < 


009 

oo  O* 


112  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

expense,  G  lies  on  the  tail  end  of  an  iso-outlay  line  of  $33.80.  Point  F, 
which  satisfies  the  equilibrium  conditions  when  both  distance  variables 
have  positive  values,  lies  on  the  iso-outlay  line  of  $33.60.  It  is  the 
preferred  position. 

There  are  numerous  other  deviations  from  a  pure  weight  and 
distance  rate  structure.  Most  of  these  can  be  encompassed  by  a  set 
of  iso-outlay  lines.  When  different  ton-mile  rates  apply  to  different 
commodities— whether  because  one  is  more  bulky  than  the  other,  more 
valuable,  more  fragile  or  perishable,  more  difficult  to  handle,  closer 
to  the  stage  of  finished  product,  better  able  to  bear  a  high  transport 
charge,  etc. — one  can  account  for  these  differences  in  rate  structure 
by  adjusting  the  transport  scale  on  the  appropriate  axis.  Different 
rates  are  frequently  set  for  different  directions  of  movement  because 
one  is  uphill  and  the  other  downhill,  because  one  encounters  more 
severe  topographical  obstacles,  because  one  bears  a  greater  volume  of 
traffic,  because  greater  speeds  are  attainable  in  one  direction,  etc.  By 
changing  the  transport  cost  scales  on  the  respective  axes  one  can 
incorporate  these  rate  differences  into  the  analysis  so  long  as  the 
direction  of  movement  of  each  raw  material  and  finished  product 
remains  the  same  for  all  realistic  points  on  the  transformation  line. 
If  this  condition  does  not  hold,  then  for  the  movement  of  any  particular 
good  it  is  necessary  to  use  several  different  transport  cost  scales  along 
the  axis  relevant  for  such  movement.  And,  accordingly,  in  constructing 
any  iso-outlay  line  on  which  a  given  realistic  point  on  the  transforma- 
tion line  lies,  we  must  use,  for  each  raw  material  and  finished  product, 
that  transport  cost  scale  which  is  relevant  for  the  direction  in  which 
the  good  moves  to  reach  the  realistic  site  under  consideration. 

Again,  if  different  types  of  transport  facilities  are  used  in  any  one 
journey  or  if  alternative  types  of  transport  facilities  are  available  for 
reaching  the  various  possible  production  sites,  we  must  construct 
several  transport  cost  scales  along  the  relevant  axis  or  axes  and  use 
the  appropriate  one  in  deriving  the  iso-outlay  line  upon  which  a  given 
realistic  point  on  the  transformation  line  lies.  ^  9  It  is  also  necessary 
to  adjust  the  transport  cost  scales  when  various  types  of  import  and 
export  duties,  or  special  levies  or  transport  expenses,  are  incurred 
at  different  points  along  a  given  route.  Where  there  are  alternative 
routes  with  various  special  charges  and  duties  along  them,  alterna- 
tive transport  cost  scales  must  be  set  up.^o 

29  See  Palander,  o-p.  cit.,  pp.  333-58,  for  a  full  discussion  of  substitution  possi- 
bilities between  various  types  of  transport  media  and  between  cheaper  and  dearer 
facilities. 

30  It  should  also  be  mentioned  that  eccentricities  in  transport  rate  structures 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     113 

4.     Transport-oriented  Equilibrium  Further  Extended 

The  analysis  of  the  preceding  sections  has  emphasized  distance  as  a 
variable.  This  initial  emphasis  has  been  pm^sued  partly  to  counteract 
the  traditional  bias  toward  consideration  of  spatial  relations.  For  a 
complete  analysis  of  transport-orientation,  however,  change  in  more 
variables  than  merely  distance  must  be  examined.  Clearly,  the 
amounts  of  the  raw  materials  used  may  vary  with  the  location  of 
the  plant,  particularly  if  alternative  sources  of  different  quality  are 
exploitable.  Also,  in  any  true  transport-orientation  problem  the 
variations  from  site  to  site  in  other  costs  such  as  labor  and  power 
must  not  be  assumed  away.  They  must  be  explicitly  introduced  as 
possible  deviational  forces,  even  though  they  turn  out  to  be  dominated 
by  variations  in  transport  outlay.  To  comprehend  better  the  inter- 
action of  these  variables,  a  transport-orientation  framework  less 
restrictive  than  the  one  already  developed  (which  has  reference  to 
variations  in  distances  alone)  is  desired.  Further,  a  more  general 
framework  is  imperative,  as  will  be  seen  below,  in  order  to  establish 
connections  among  the  several  types  of  location  theories  and  to  uncover 
principles  common  to  all.  Moreover,  such  a  framework  would  facilitate 
the  fusion  of  location  theory  and  production  theory. 

We  now  propose  to  employ  the  concept  of  transport  inputs  as  defined 
in  Chap.  4.  To  repeat:  a  transport  input  represents  the  movement  of 
a  unit  weight  over  a  unit  distance.  It  may  be  expressed  in  such  terms 
as  a  hundredweight-kilometer  and  a  ton-mile.  We  therefore  encounter 
transport  inputs  in  the  shipment  of  any  raw  material  to  the  production 
site  and  in  the  shipment  of  the  finished  product  from  the  production 

which  run  counter  to  transport  cost  as  a  monotonically  increasing  function  of  dis- 
tance are  reflected  in  eccentricities  of  iso-outlay  Hues.  For  example,  the  histori- 
cally important  practice  in  the  United  States  of  levying  a  smaller  total  charge  for 
movement  between  two  nodal  termini  served  by  two  or  more  competing  railways 
than  for  movement  between  one  of  these  termini  and  an  intermediate  point  or 
between  two  intermediate  points  on  one  of  the  alternative  routes  causes  the  iso- 
outlay  lines  to  criss-cross.  If,  for  instance,  the  raw  material  from  M2  could  be 
moved  from  its  source,  a  terminal,  to  another  terminal  210  miles  distant  on  a 
special  rate,  then  point  K  in  Fig.  22,  which  may  represent  a  combination  of 
values  of  210  miles  for  distance  from  M2  and  100  miles  for  distance  from  Mi, 
would  he  on  a  lower  iso-outlay  line  than  point  /.  Obviously  such  eccentricity 
enhances  the  attraction  of  terminal  sites,  particularly  when  these  sites  are  raw 
material  sources  or  consumption  places.  As  a  consequence,  a  commodity  may 
travel  an  unnecessary  distance,  that  is,  to  a  site  lying  outside  the  locational  poly- 
gon. Similarly  this  occurs  when  back  hauls  and  roundabout  hauls  take  place 
because  of  the  rigidities  of  the  transport  net,  especially  in  water  and  water-rail 
transport. 


114 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


site  to  the  market.  Since  the  distance  variable  as  well  as  the  weight 
variable  is  encompassed  by  the  concept  of  transport  inputs,  all  the 
relations  among  distance  variables  discussed  above  may  be  translated 
into  relations  among  transport  inputs.    To  demonstrate  this,  reconsider 


Transport  inputs  on  raw  material  M2 


Fig.  24.    Shift    of   transformation    curve    and    equilibrium    site   with    change    in 

weights. 


.  17  we  substitute  for  the  three 
distance  from  M2,  and  distance 
(1)  transport  inputs  on  the  raw 


the  minimum  transport  cost  solution  for  the  locational  triangle  of 
Fig.  17. 

In  the  problem  associated  with  Fi§ 
distance  variables  (distance  from  M^ , 
from  C)  three  new  variables,  namely: 
material  from  source  M^ ;  (2)  transport  inputs  on  the  raw  material 
from  source  Af  2 ;  and  (3)  transport  inputs  on  the  product  to  the  market. 
Relations  among  these  new  variables  can  be  presented  in  terms  of 
meaningful  transformation  lines.  For  the  situation  where  we  consider 
as  a  possible  production  site  each  point  along  arc  TS  of  Fig.  17,  we 
obtain  a  transformation  line  between  transport  inputs  on  the  raw 
material  from  M^  (which  we  shall  henceforth  designate  transport 
inputs  on  raw  material  Mj )  and  transport  inputs  on  the  raw  material 
from  Mo  (which  we  shall  designate  transport  inputs  on  raw 
material  M2).     This  transformation  line,  SHJT,  plotted  in  Fig.  24 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     115 

resembles  the  transformation  line  of  Fig.  18.  The  only  difference 
between  the  two  charts  thus  far  is  that  in  one  case  distance  variables, 
in  the  other  transport  inputs,  are  measured  along  the  axes. 

It  should  be  noted  that  the  transformation  line  is  drawn  as  a 
continuous  curve.  Although  in  reality  it  should  be  a  finite  number  of 
points,  as  in  Fig.  21,  we  present  it  as  a  curve  in  order  to  facilitate 
the  analysis  and  the  synthesis  of  transport-orientation  theory  and 
production  theory.  The  latter  in  its  more  familiar  form  utilizes  curves 
rather  than  a  finite  number  of  points  and  continuous  production 
functions  rather  than  discontinuous  ones. 

If  transport  rates  are  proportional  to  distance  and  if  they  are  the 
same  for  both  raw  materials,  then  the  relevant  set  of  price-ratio  lines 
are  straight  lines  which  cut  both  axes  symmetrically.  The  prices 
involved  are  the  rates  per  ton-mile  transportation  of  the  two  raw 
materials.  In  this  case  the  prices  are  different  from  those  in  the 
situation  depicted  in  Fig.  21.  There  each  price  was  the  cost  of 
moving  1  mile  the  weight  (tonnage)  of  a  given  raw  material  required 
per  weight  unit  (1  ton)  of  the  product.  Hence,  when  the  weight 
requirements  of  raw  materials  were  altered,  so  were  the  slopes  of  the 
price-ratio  lines,  the  transformation  line  expressed  in  terms  of 
the  distance  variables  remaining  unchanged.  Here  in  the  situation 
depicted  in  Fig.  24,  the  prices  are  rates  on  the  movement  of  a  weight 
unit  over  a  unit  of  distance  (e.g.  rates  per  ton-mile) .  When  weight  re- 
quirements of  raw  materials  change,  the  price-ratio  lines  remain  the 
same.  The  requirements  of  transport  inputs,  however,  change.  A  new 
transformation  line  between  transport  inputs  becomes  relevant.  For 
example,  suppose  we  assume  as  previously  that  the  production  of  1^/^ 
tons  of  finished  product  requires  1  ton  of  the  raw  material  from  Mi 
and  2  tons  of  the  raw  material  from  Mo .  These  new  weight  relations 
yield,  for  the  locational  figure  of  Fig.  17,  a  transformation  line 
S'H'J'T'  between  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  M-i  and  transport 
inputs  on  raw  material  M2.  See  Fig.  24.  The  point  S"  on  the  dashed 
transformation  line  refers  to  the  identical  geographic  location  as  does 
S;  iy  as  does  H';  J  as  J';  and  T  as  T\  However,  although  the 
transformation  line  rather  than  the  price-ratio  line  shifts  in  this  new 
formulation,  the  equilibrium  point  of  location  is  unaffected.  Before 
the  change  in  weight  relations,  both  the  old  and  the  new  formulation 
of  the  problem  yielded  a  location  at  or  in  the  vicinity  of  J  in  Fig.  17. ^1 

31  When  the  transformation  hne  is  a  series  of  points,  as  in  Fig.  21,  the  partial 
equilibrium  point  is  at  J.  When  the  transformation  line  is  assumed  continuous, 
as  in  Fig.  24,  the  partial  equilibrium  point  is  somewhat  to  the  left  of  J  in  the 
direction  of  H  at  the  point  K  where  the  transformation  line  is  tangent  to  a 
price-ratio  line. 


116  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

After  the  change  in  weight  relations,  both  formulations  yield  a  location 
at  H  in  Fig.  17. 

As  indicated,  the  new  formulation  of  the  problem  in  terms  of 
transport  inputs  is  superior  to  the  first  one  in  several  respects. 
However,  in  at  least  one  basic  respect  it  is  inferior  to  a  formulation 
in  terms  of  distance  variables.  In  the  first  formulation,  shifts  of  the 
transformation  line  can  take  place  only  when  the  distance  variable 
from  C  assumes  another  value  or  when  new  sources  of  raw  materials 
are  utilized  with  a  consequent  alteration  of  the  locational  triangle. 
In  the  new  formulation,  shifts  of  the  transformation  line  can  take 
place  as  well  when  weight  relations  change.  Hence,  in  the  new  formu- 
lation it  becomes  impossible  to  identify  the  cause  of  a  shift  from  mere 
observation  of  the  transformation  lines  and  to  know  whether  or  not 
a  change  of  location  (geographic  position)  is  entailed.  The  new 
formulation  hence  loses  the  spatial  perspective  which  the  first  formu- 
lation permits.  (Since  the  new  formulation  is  much  more  in  line 
with  orthodox  economic  analysis,  this  is  consistent  with  the  weak 
spatial  perspective  of  orthodox  economic  thinking.)  To  reiterate,  it  is 
for  this  reason  that  the  less  elegant  formulation  in  terms  of  distance 
variables  has  been  presented  first  for  emphasis. 

Returning  to  the  problem  of  partial  locational  equilibrium  which 
is  achieved  when  the  geographic  point  of  production  lies  within  the 
locational  triangle  and  corresponds  to  the  point  on  the  transformation 
line  which  lies  on  the  lowest  price-ratio  line  (and  hence  incurs  least 
total  transport  cost) ,  we  note  two  necessary  conditions.  One,  the  first 
order  condition,  is  that  the  geographic  point  of  production  corre- 
spond to  a  point  of  tangency  between  a  price-ratio  line  and  the  trans- 
formation line.  This  signifies,  in  general,  that  the  rate  of  substitution 
at  the  margin,  or  the  marginal  rate  of  substitution,  between  any  two 
transport  inputs  be  equal  to  the  reciprocal  of  their  prices  (the  cor- 
responding transport  rates).  Two,  the  second  order  {or  stability) 
condition,  is  that  at  the  point  of  tangency  the  transformation  line 
be  more  convex  to  the  origin  than  the  price-ratio  line.  Since  in  Fig. 
24  the  transformation  lines  SHJT  and  S'H'J'T  are  convex  throughout, 
whereas  the  price-ratio  lines  are  straight,  this  stability  condition  is 
fulfilled  at  any  point  which  may  prove  to  be  a  point  of  tangency. 
The  convexity  of  the  transformation  lines  to  the  origin  signifies  a 
diminishing  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  the  two  transport 
inputs.  It  should  be  noted  that  at  both  points  K  and  H',  these  two 
necessary  conditions  are  satisfied.  Since  throughout  its  course  each 
transformation  line  is  convex  to  the  origin,  no  other  points  of  tangency 
occur,  and  K  and  H'  each  represents  the  partial  locational  equilibrium 
position  for  its  particular  situation. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION    117 

As  before,  a  "full"  equilibrium  position  is  attained  when  the  three 
partial  equilibrium  positions  with  respect  to  the  three  pairs  of  variables 
[here:  (1)  transport  inputs  on  product  and  transport  inputs  on  raw  ma- 
terial Ml ;  (2)  transport  inputs  on  product  and  transport  inputs  on  raw 
material  M2  ;  and  (3)  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  Mi  and  trans- 
port inputs  on  raw  material  M2  ]  coincide. 

Just  as  we  have  converted  the  locational  triangle  problem  of  Figs. 
19  and  20  into  a  problem  of  substitution  among  transport  inputs,  so 
we  can  convert  the  other  locational  problems  depicted  in  the  previous 
sections.  The  set  of  possible  sites  of  production  in  the  locational  line 
case  (see  Figs.  15  and  16)  can  be  presented  in  terms  of  a  transforma- 
tion line  for  two  transport  input  variables  rather  than  for  two  distance 
variables.  In  the  case  of  the  four-sided  polygon  (see  Figs.  19  and 
20),  transformation  lines  for  pairs  of  transport  inputs  substitute  for 
transformation  lines  for  pairs  of  distance  variables.  Along  the  axes 
of  a  diagram  similar  to  Fig.  20,  we  measure  transport  inputs  rather 
than  distances.  Again,  in  the  identification  of  the  path  of  substitu- 
tion between  any  pair  of  transport  input  variables,  the  same  restraint 
obtains  as  in  the  formulation  with  distance  variables:  the  sum  of 
transport  costs  associated  with  all  other  variables  (here,  transport 
inputs)  must  remain  constant.  Once  again,  the  over-all  location 
equilibrium  involves  the  positional  coincidence  of  more  than  one 
partial  equilibrium  between  pairs  of  variables.  ^  2 

When  we  inject  realistic  rate  structures  and  discontinuities  in  the 
transformation  function,  we  can  (though  we  need  not)  construct 
for  a  locational  triangle  problem  figures  somewhat  comparable  to 
Figs.  22  and  23.  The  scales  along  the  axes,  however,  would  be 
different.  Scale  b  of  the  figure  corresponding  to  Fig.  22  and  scale  c 
of  the  figure  corresponding  to  Fig.  23  would  measure  transport  inputs 
on  raw  material  M2  in  ton-mile  units,  and  would  be  numerically 
twice  as  large  as  the  existing  scale.  Scale  d  of  the  figure  correspond- 
ing to  Fig.  22  and  scale  /  of  the  figure  corresponding  to  Fig.  23 
would  measure  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  Mi  in  ton-mile 
units  and  would  be  numerically  the  same  as  the  existing  scale.  The 
other  scales  would  be  transport  cost  scales  as  in  Figs.  22  and  23, 
respectively,  but  would  be  designated  somewhat  differently.  The 
transformation  lines  would  correspond  respectively  to  the  transforma- 
tion lines  of  Figs.  22  and  23,  but  would  of  course  refer  to  transport 
inputs  rather  than  distance  variables.  The  equilibrium  analysis  and 
statement  of  equilibrium  conditions  would  essentially  parallel  that 
presented  for  Figs.  22  and  23. 

32  See  Chap.  10  for  a  full  statement. 


118  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Before  this  chapter  is  brought  to  a  close  stress  should  be  placed  on 
this  important  point.  The  two  necessary  (the  first-  and  second-order) 
conditions,  as  stated  above  for  a  partial  locational  equilibrium,  when 
generalized  to  consider  for  any  transport-orientation  problem  sub- 
stitution among  any  pair  of  transport  inputs,  are  no  different  from 
those  formulated  by  Allen,  Hicks,  and  other  production  theorists 
when  the  problem  of  substitution  between  two  inputs  or  factors  of 
production  is  posed. ^^  At  an  equilibrium  point,  in  Hicks'  words, 
the  "price-ratio  between  any  two  factors  [inputs]  must  equal  their 
marginal  rate  of  substitution,"  and  for  ''the  substitution  of  one  factor 
(input)  for  another,  'diminishing  marginal  rate  of  substitution' " 
must  hold. 3  4 

Even  when  the  transformation  line  is  taken  as  a  finite  number  of 
points,  the  necessary  conditions  for  transport-oriented  equilibrium 
are  essentially  the  same  as  those  stated  by  Samuelson  for  a  firm  given 
a  discontinuous  production  function.  ^  5  Further,  when  realistic  rate 
(transport  price)  structures  are  introduced,  the  necessary  conditions 
again  resemble  those  which  can  be  derived  from  Samuelson's  statements. 

Thus,  it  is  along  these  lines  that  by  using  the  concept  of  transport 
inputs^e  we  are  able  to  fuse  much  traditional   (Weberian)   doctrine 

33  R.  G.  D.  Allen,  Mathematical  Analysis  for  Economists,  New  York,   1939, 
Chaps.  XIV  and  XIX;  and  J.  R.  Hicks,  Value  and  Capital,  Oxford,  1939,  Chap.  VI. 
34 /bid.,  pp.  86-87.    Italics  are  mine. 

35  Samuelson,  op.  cit.,  Chaps.  Ill  and  IV. 

36  In  order  to  illustrate  the  general  applicability  of  the  concept  of  transport 
inputs,  let  us  refer  to  a  transport-oriented  production  process  such  as  iron  and 
steel.  The  United  States  Steel  Corporation  recently  constructed  1.8  million  tons 
of  steel  capacity  immediately  below  Trenton  for  serving  the  Eastern  seaboard 
market  centering  around  New  York  City  with  steel  produced  from  Venezuelan 
ore.  Of  the  suitable  waterfront  sites,  this  was  probably  the  closest  to  New  York 
City.  In  choosing  a  site  at  Trenton  rather  than  one  farther  from  the  market 
but  closer  to  coal,  the  corporation  substituted  transport  inputs  on  coal  from  the 
coal  source  for  transport  inputs  on  product  to  the  market.  Considering,  first, 
the  possible  combinations  of  quantities  of  these  two  transport  inputs,  given  the 
quantity  of  transport  inputs  on  ore  from  Cerro  Bolivar,  Venezuela,  which  for 
practical  purposes  remains  constant  for  all  Middle  Atlantic  seaboard  points,  and 
second,  considering  the  quantities  of  coal  and  scrap  that  might  be  used  per  ton 
steel,  the  ton-mile  transport  charges  on  these  items,  and  as  a  consequence  the 
significantly  higher  price  of  a  transport  input  on  product  to  the  market  than 
of  a  transport  input  on  coal  from  the  coal  source — one  can  easily  portray  the 
Trenton  site  as  the  point  of  locational  equilibrium  in  the  given  situation.  In 
making  this  statement  we  also  consider  variation  in  the  quantity  of  transport 
inputs  on  ore  from  Cerro  Bolivar,  for  the  given  requirement  of  ore  per  ton  steel. 
A  meaningful  larger  quantity  of  this  input  would  involve  an  inland  location 
which,  in  view  of  the  significant  cost  of  transshipment  to  rail  and  of  the  geography 
of  ore,  coal,  and  market  sites,  would  not  be  an  over-all  locational  equilibrium 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     119 

on  transport-orientation  and  production  theory  for  the  firm,  thereby 
extending  both.^'^  Restatement  of  the  problem  of  transport-orienta- 
tion in  terms  of  substitutions  among  transport  inputs  automatically 
establishes  a  point  of  connection  with  other  substitutions  among  the 
diverse  inputs  (and  outputs)  of  a  firm  and,  hence,  allows  improve- 
ment in  any  statement  on  transport-orientation.  At  the  same  time, 
inclusion  of  transport  inputs  in  the  transformation  function  of  the 
firm  adds  a  spatial  dimension  to  production  theory  and  allows  this 
theory  to  embrace  the  situation  of  transport-orientation.  ^^ 


Appendix  to  Chapter  5 

Transport  Inputs  and  Some  Formulations  of  the 
Transport-orientation  Problem 

In  this  chapter,  the  general  transport-orientation  problem  has  been  essen- 
tially restated.  In  Chap.  10  the  transport-orientation  problem  is  presented 
in  more  rigorous  mathematical  terms.  Nevertheless,  it  may  be  helpful  to 
some  readers  to  translate  some  of  the  more  famihar  formulations  of  the 
transport-orientation  problem  into  substitution  relations  among  transport 
inputs  in  a  way  which  is  simple  and  direct. 

We  may  begin  with  the  line  case  already  alluded  to  at  the  beginning  of 
Sect.  2  of  this  chapter.  Suppose  1  ton  of  raw  material  from  source  M-^  is 
required  to  produce  1  ton  of  product  which  is  consumed  at  point  C.  Let  C 
be  connected  by  a  straight  line  railway  to  M-^^.  See  Fig.  15.  It  then  follows 
that  the  various  combinations  of  the  variables,  transport  inputs  on  raw 
material  M-^  and  transport  inputs  on  product,  corresponding  to  the  innumer- 
able efficient  locations  possible  along  line  CM-^^  are  given  by  a  transformation 
line  with  a  slope  of  — 1.  Such  a  transformation  line  is  given  by  Fig.  16  when 
we  appropriately  measure  along  the  axes  transport  inputs  rather  than 
distances. 

If  we  now  posit  that  transport  rates  on  both  product  and  raw  material  are 
identical  and  proportional  to  weight  and  distance,  we  obtain  a  set  of  price- 
ratio  lines  whose  slopes  are  also  — 1.  When  we  superimpose  such  a  set  of 
lines  upon  Fig.  16,  we  find  that  the  transformation  line  and  one  and  only 

point  when  translated  into  the  relevant  sets  of  transformation  and  iso-outlay 
lines.  Neither  would  a  location  in  the  Southern  Atlantic  seaboard,  which  would 
involve  a  smaller  quantity  of  this  input.  See,  in  this  connection,  W.  Isard  and 
J.  Cumberland,  "New  England  as  a  Possible  Location  for  an  Integrated  Iron  and 
Steel  Works,"  Economic  Geography,  Vol.  26  (October  1950),  pp.  245-59. 

37  This  fusion  is  more  rigorously  demonstrated  in  Chap.  10. 

38  It  is  perhaps  unnecessary  to  reiterate  the  point  in  the  final  paragraph  of 
Chap.  4,  namely,  that  the  extension  of  production  theory  to  include  transport 
inputs  as  another  set  of  inputs  does  not  commit  a  person  to  the  acceptance  of  the 
transport  function  as  another  factor  of  production,  if  he  is  not  inclined  to  do  so. 


120  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

one  of  the  set  of  price-ratio  lines  coincide  completely.  This  fact  signifies  that 
each  of  the  innumerable  possible  locations  along  line  CM^  incurs  the  same 
total  transport  cost.  The  locational  equilibrium  problem  is  therefore  indeter- 
minate, as  Weber  noted.  Any  point  on  the  transformation  line  corresponds 
to  as  good  a  site  of  production  as  any  other. 

Determinacy  is  immediately  introduced  if  an  ubiquity  which  enters  into  the 
weight  of  the  product  plus  a  pure  material  from  source  M^  are  required  for 
production.  In  this  instance,  the  relevant  transformation  line  will  fall  off 
less  rapidly  than  the  transformation  line  of  Fig.  16.  When  price-ratio  lines 
with  slope  of  —1  are  superimposed  upon  this  new  transformation  line,  the 
point  of  the  transformation  line  which  lies  on  the  lowest  price-ratio  line  will 
correspond  to  an  end-point  solution,  specifically  to  location  at  the  market,  as 
Weber  indicated. 

Determinacy  can  also  be  introduced  if  we  assume  that  the  raw  material  is 
weight-losing  and  that,  as  a  consequence,  more  than  a  ton  of  raw  material  is 
required  per  ton  product.  In  this  case  the  new  transformation  line  falls  off 
more  rapidly  than  the  transformation  line  of  Fig.  16.  When  price-ratio  lines 
of  slope  — 1  are  superimposed,  that  combination  of  transport  inputs  on  raw 
material  and  finished  product  which  corresponds  to  location  at  M-^  lies  on  the 
lowest  price-ratio  line. 

Most  of  the  indeterminacy  of  the  first  case  is  eliminated  if  graduated 
(Staff el)  transport  tariff  structures  obtain.  For  the  price-ratio  lines  are  no 
longer  straight  fines  with  slope  of  — 1,  but  curved  lines  as  indicated  in  the 
discussion  pertaining  to  Fig.  22.  As  a  consequence,  those  two  combinations 
of  the  two  transport  input  variables  which  correspond  to  location  at  the 
market  and  location  at  the  raw  material  source  lie  on  the  same  price-ratio 
line;  all  other  combinations  fie  on  higher  price-ratio  lines. 

Essentially,  ubiquities  which  enter  into  the  final  product  increase  transport 
inputs  on  the  finished  product  for  any  location  away  from  the  market;  and 
the  occurrence  of  weight-loss  in  the  use  of  a  localized  raw  material  increases 
transport  inputs  on  the  raw  material  for  any  location  away  from  the  source. 
Further,  the  appfication  of  different  transport  rates  to  the  movement  of 
finished  product  and  raw  material  can  be  incorporated  into  the  problem 
either:  (1)  indirectly  by  the  use  of  "ideal"  weights,  in  which  case  price- ratio 
hues  are  unaffected  and  the  relative  values  of  transport  input  variables  change ; 
or  (2)  directly  by  changing  the  appropriate  transport  scales  along  the  axes, 
in  which  case  the  slopes  of  the  price-ratio  lines  change,  and  the  values  of  the 
transport  input  variables  remain  unaffected.  With  these  considerations  in 
mind,  it  is  easily  perceived  how  the  various  correct  propositions  which  have 
been  advanced  for  the  line  case  by  Weber  and  others  are  translatable  into 
transformation  lines  with  respect  to  transport  inputs  and  price-ratio  lines. 

We  pass  on  to  the  use  of  weight  triangles  for  the  solution  of  the  transport- 
orientation  problem  when  a  locational  triangle  is  given.  Dean  has  expounded 
this  type  of  solution  most  precisely,  and  we  shall  have  reference  to  his 
formulation. 

Let  us  consider  first  the  case  where  the  weight  triangle  does  not  exist. 
This  would  obtain,  for  example,  if  Weber's  material  index  were  less  than  unity 
(and  his  locational  weight,  less  than  two).  In  this  situation  the  ideal  weight 
of  the  product  exceeds  the  combined  ideal  weights  of  locahzed  raw  materials, 
the  weight  of  the  product  being  the  dominant  weight.  When  transport  inputs 
are  based  on  ideal  weights,  the  price  of  every  type  of  transport  input  is  the 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     121 

same  regardless  of  which  raw  material  or  finished  product  is  being  moved; 
and,  accordingly,  the  problem  is  to  minimize  total  transport  inputs.  Hence, 
if  the  material  index  is  less  than  unitj^  and  if  we  consider  a  location  away 
from  the  locus  of  consumption,  it  is  always  feasible  to  shift  toward  the  locus 
of  consumption,  until  that  locus  is  reached.  For,  with  any  such  shift,  the 
total  of  transport  inputs  diminishes,  since  any  increase  in  transport  inputs  on 
localized  raw  materials  is  always  less  than  the  decrease  of  transport  inputs  on 
the  finished  product.  In  efi"ect  such  a  shift  corresponds  to  one  or  more 
movements  along  one  or  more  transformation  lines  which  involves  one  or 
more  substitutions  of  fewer  transport  inputs  of  one  type  for  more  transport 
inputs  of  another  type.  This  process  entails  a  concomitant  movement  to  lower 
price-ratio  lines,  whose  slopes  by  definition  are  — 1. 

When  transport  inputs  are  more  meaningfully  based  on  actual  weights  rather 
than  ideal  weights,  again  it  follows  that  if  the  material  index  is  less  than 
unity,  it  is  not  economic  to  locate  at  a  site  other  than  the  locus  of  consumption. 
For,  with  any  shift  from  a  location  not  the  locus  of  consumption  toward  the 
locus  of  consumption,  any  increase  in  the  costs  of  transport  inputs  on  localized 
raw  materials  (because  of  the  increase  in  the  amounts  of  such  transport 
inputs)  will  always  be  smaller  than  the  decrease  in  the  costs  of  transport 
inputs  on  finished  product  (because  of  the  decrease  in  the  amount  of  such 
transport  inputs).  Once  more  such  a  shift  involves  substitutions  among 
transport  inputs  which  correspond  to  movements  along  transformation  lines 
on  to  lower  price-ratio  lines  whose  slopes  are  ordinarily  different  from  — 1. 

The  weight  triangle  does  not  exist  when  Dean's  generalized  index  yields 
a  value  less  than  unity.  [In  Dean's  generalized  index  test  the  denominator  is 
either:  (1)  the  largest  localized  raw  material  or  group  of  spatially  localized 
raw  materials,  or  (2)  the  product,  whichever  is  the  larger  by  weight.]  If,  for 
example,  the  weight  of  a  locaUzed  raw  material  is  dominant  (the  generalized 
index  will  then  be  less  than  unity)  and  if  the  site  of  production  is  not  at 
the  site  of  this  locahzed  raw  material,  it  is  always  feasible  to  shift  toward 
this  site.  With  such  a  shift,  either:  (1)  total  transport  inputs  on  localized 
raw  materials  and  finished  product  will  decrease,  when  these  transport  inputs 
are  based  on  "ideal"  weights;  or  (2)  the  decrease  in  the  costs  of  transport 
inputs  on  the  localized  raw  material  (because  of  the  decrease  in  the  amount  of 
such  transport  inputs)  will  be  greater  than  any  increase  in  the  costs  of 
transport  inputs  on  other  localized  raw  materials  and  finished  product 
(because  of  an  increase  in  the  amount  of  such  transport  inputs) . 

Let  us  now  turn  to  the  general  case  where  the  weight  triangle  does  exist. 
Here,  the  generalized  index  test  gives  values  always  greater  than  unity. 
Also,  Weber's  material  index  yields  a  value  greater  than  unity.  However,  it 
does  not  follow  that  location  cannot  be  at  an  end  point  (a  corner  of  the 
locational  triangle),  and  for  that  matter  at  a  source  of  a  pure  material.  The 
problem  is  one  of  the  equilibrium  of  forces  in  which  relative  weights  and 
relative  distances  are  the  basic  factors. 

The  w^eight  triangle  is  a  geometric  device  used  to  obtain  the  point  at  which 
the  several  locational  forces  are  in  equilibrium.  Its  counterpart  in  the  physical 
world  is  a  mechanical  model  such  as  Varignon's  which  was  designed  to  demon- 
strate the  parallelogram  of  forces,  and  the  use  of  which  Pick  describes  in  an 
appendix  to  Weber's  book.  But  what  are  the  locational  fo7'ces  in  a  transport- 
orientation  problem? 

If  we  base  transport  inputs  on  ideal  weights,  as  Weber  and  Dean  tend  to 


122  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

do,  the  three  locational  forces  in  a  locational  triangle  are  the  ideal  weights 
of  the  finished  product  and  the  two  raw  materials.  They  pull  against  each 
other  in  a  maimer  wliich  minimizes  total  transport  inputs  at  the  point  of 
equilibrium  when  that  point  lies  within  or  on  the  locational  triangle.  When 
the  point  of  equilibrium  lies  outside  the  locational  triangle,  transport  inputs 
are  minimized  when  location  is  at  that  corner  of  the  locational  triangle  whose 
exterior  angle  is  less  than  the  corresponding  angle  of  the  weight  triangle. 
This  holds  whether  the  corner  corresponds  to  a  pure  or  a  weight-losing  raw 
material. 

If  we  base  transport  inputs  on  actual  weight,  as  is  done  in  the  mathematical 
statement  in  Chap.  10,  the  three  locational  forces  in  a  locational  triangle  are 
the  three  costs  involved  in  moving  one  at  a  time  the  respective  three  actual 
weights  a  unit  of  distance.  These  three  forces,  each  of  which  is  expressed  in 
terms  of  transport  costs  per  unit  of  distance,  interact  to  determine  a  point 
of  equilibrium.  If  such  a  point  lies  within  or  on  the  locational  triangle,  it 
corresponds  to  a  point  of  minimum  total  transport  cost.  If  it  hes  outsicle  the 
locational  triangle,  the  corner  of  the  locational  triangle  whose  exterior  angle 
is  less  than  its  corresponding  angle  in  the  weight  triangle  is  the  point  of 
minimum  total  transport  cost. 

Again,  one  easily  perceives  that  any  shift  from  a  location  which  is  not  a 
point  of  equilibrium  within  or  on  a  locational  triangle  toward  such  a  point, 
or  toward  the  appropriate  corner  of  the  triangle  when  the  point  of  equilibrium 
hes  outside  the  triangle,  entails  substitutions  among  transport  inputs  which 
involve  movements  along  transformation  lines  on  to  lower  price-ratio  lines. 

In  essence,  the  weight  triangle  solution  shortcuts  the  process  of  determining 
the  site  of  locational  equilibrium.  Likewise  does  the  somewhat  similar  geo- 
metric construction  which  is  based  upon  the  use  of  the  "pole  principle," 
which  Launhardt  first  sketched  and  Palander  later  amplified.  However,  in 
doing  so,  both  the  weight  triangle  and  the  pole  construction  fail  to  point  up 
explicitly  the  interaction  of  the  basic  economic  forces,  namely,  the  several 
transport  costs  per  unit  distance.  More  satisfactory  in  this  regard  is  the 
Varignon  mechanical  model  (which  can  be  employed  for  locational  polygons 
of  more  than  three  sides),  even  though  it  is  oriented  to  "ideal"  weights  rather 
than  "economic"  weights. 

A  third  approach  to  the  solution  of  the  transport-orientation  problem  rehes 
upon  the  use  of  isodapanes.3  9  An  isodapane,  as  used  by  Palander  and  Hoover, 
is  a  locus  of  points  at  each  of  which  the  location  of  the  production  process 
would  incur  the  same  over-all  (combined)  transport  costs  in  the  movement 
of  both  raw  materials  and  finished  product.  Typically,  to  derive  a  set  of 
isodapanes,  in  which  each  isodapane  refers  to  a  different  value  for  total 
(combined)  transport  costs,  one  constructs  isovectors  (a  la  Palander)  or 
isotims  (a  la  Hoover)  about  each  raw  material  source  and  finished  product. 
An  isovector  is  a  line  which,  in  the  case  of  a  localized  raw  material,  connects 
points  to  which  the  required  quantity  of  localized  raw  material  may  be  shipped 
from  a  point  source  at  the  same  transport  cost.     Hence,  around  each  raw 

39  The  isodapane  technique  is  more  flexible  than  the  weight  triangle  method. 
It  can  encompass  graduated  tariff  structures  and  transport  nets  composed  of  dif- 
ferent media,  avoid  adjustment  to  an  "ideal"  weight  basis,  and  relate  to  loca- 
tional polygons  of  more  than  three  comers.  It  is  however  a  much  more  cumber- 
some technique. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     123 

material  source,  a  set  of  isovectors  may  be  drawn;  to  each  isovector  we  may 
assign  a  transport  cost  which  generally  rises  with  distance  from  the  raw 
material  source.  (See  Figs.  48  and  49,  Palander,  op.  cit.,  and  Fig.  15,  Hoover, 
op.  cit.)  In  the  case  of  a  finished  product,  an  isovector  is  a  line  wliich 
connects  points  from  which  the  finished  product  may  be  shipped  to  a  specified 
market  point  at  the  same  transport  cost.  Here,  too,  a  set  of  isovectors  may 
be  drawn,  where  each  represents  a  different  level  of  transport  cost  which 
generally  rises  with  distance  from  the  market  point. 

Once  a  set  of  isovectors  is  constructed  about  each  raw  material  source  and 
market  point  relevant  in  a  locational  problem,  isodapanes  may  be  drawn  by 
connecting  all  those  points  wliich  as  a  location  for  production  would  incur 
the  same  sum  of  the  several  transport  costs  on  the  raw  materials  and  finished 
product.  The  procedure  of  employing  maps  of  isovectors  to  derive  isodapanes 
is  discussed  by  Palander  in  coimection  with  liis  Fig.  52,  and  Hoover  in 
connection  with  his  Fig.  15. 

Essentially,  isodapanes  are  contour  lines  of  a  total  transport  cost  surface. 
Such  a  surface  is  precisely  treated  in  Chap.  10,  and  is  briefly  described  in 
Pick's  Appendix  (Weber,  op.  cit.,  pp.  244-5).  Once  the  contour  lines  are 
mapped,  the  identification  of  the  minimum  transport  cost  point,  the  point  of 
locational  equihbrium  in  the  transport-orientation  problem,  is  a  matter  of 
course.  See,  for  example,  the  situation  depicted  by  Palander,  op.  cit.,  in  Figs. 
53  to  68,  and  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  in  Figs.  15  and  20. 

As  already  intimated,  both  the  process  of  substitution  among  transport 
inputs,  as  discussed  in  this  chapter,  and  isodapanes  refer  to  the  identical 
transport  cost  surface.  Our  substitution  process  refers  to  a  path  of  movement 
along  the  transport  cost  surface  in  a  direction  toward  the  trough  point  of  the 
set  of  isodapanes  (the  minimum  point  of  the  surface).  An  isodapane,  in 
contrast,  refers  to  a  path  of  movement  around  a  trough  point.  As  such  our 
substitution  process  and  an  isodapane  represent  merely  two  different  paths 
of  journey  along  the  same  surface. 

That  (1)  the  process  of  substitution  among  transport  inputs  and  (2)  the 
movement  along  an  isodapane  and  from  isodapane  to  isodapane  can  involve 
the  same  basic  considerations  is  clearly  demonstrated  by  reference  to  Palan- 
der's  method  of  constructing  isodapanes  when  three  or  more  commodities  are 
to  be  moved.  Imagine  a  locational  triangle  such  as  Fig.  17.  About  each  raw 
material  source  and  market  Palander  advises  as  a  first  step  the  construction 
of  a  set  of  isovectors.  As  a  second  step,  any  two  of  the  three  sets  of  isovectors 
are  used  to  derive  a  subset  of  isodapanes  (partial  isodapanes)  which  refer 
to  the  sum  of  only  two  transport  costs.  As  a  third  step,  the  subset  of 
isodapanes  are  combined  with  the  third  set  of  isovectors  to  obtain  the  desired 
set  of  isodapanes  which  refer  to  the  sum  of  three  transport  costs. 

For  the  moment  consider  ( 1 )  the  subset  of  isodapanes  derived  in  the  second 
step  and  (2)  the  third  set  of  isovectors,  which,  let  us  posit,  centers  around 
the  market  point.  Suppose  we  select  that  isovector  which  corresponds  to 
three  distance  units  from  C  in  Fig.  17  and  thus  to  arc  TS.  Suppose  also  we 
select  any  one  isodapane  from  the  subset  of  isodapanes  which  intersect  this 
isovector.  As  we  proceed  along  this  isovector  in  one  direction  we  ^vill  be 
moving  on  to  subset  isodapanes  of  greater  and  greater  values;  and  in  the 
other  direction  to  subset  isodapanes  of  lower  and  lower  values.  Such  move- 
ment necessarily  involves  a  substitution  between  transport  inputs  on  the  raw 
material  from  M-^  and  transport  inputs  on  the  raw  material  from  Mg,  since 


124  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

distances  from  M-^^  and  ikfg  change  while  weights  remain  constant.  A  move- 
ment in  the  former  direction  is  identical  with  a  movement  along  the  trans- 
formation hne  ST  of  Fig.  24  to  higher  and  higher  price-ratio  (iso-outlay) 
lines;  and  in  the  latter  direction,  to  lower  and  lower  price-ratio  hnes.  This 
is  so  because  we  are  holding  constant  transport  inputs  on  finished  product  to 
C,  and,  hence,  the  transport  cost  on  finished  product  to  C  (since  the  transport 
rate  is  given) .  The  desirability  of  moving  along  any  isovector  until  the  subset 
isodapane  of  lowest  value  is  reached  (which  wiU  be  at  a  point  of  tangency) 
is  clear.  This  is  equivalent  to  substituting  between  transport  inputs  and 
moving  along  the  transformation  line  ST  of  Fig.  24  until  point  K  is  reached. 
Of  all  points  on  the  transformation  line,  K  lies  on  the  lowest  price-ratio  line 
and  is  also  a  point  of  tangency.  K  represents  a  partial  locational  equilibrium 
point. 

We  proceed  further.  Having  identified  the  point  which  would  be  K  in 
Fig.  17  and  which  is  the  point  of  tangency  of  the  isovector  of  the  previous 
paragraph  with  the  lowest  value  isodapane  of  the  subset  isodapanes  having 
a  point  in  common  with  the  isovector,  let  us  select  that  isovector  of  the  set 
of  isovectors  centering  around  raw  material  source  M2  which  passes  through 
what  would  be  point  K  in  Fig.  17.  Also,  construct  another  subset  of  isoda- 
panes based  upon  the  sum  of  transport  costs  on  raw  material  from  M^  and 
finished  product  to  C.  Once  again,  we  move  along  the  isovector  until  we 
reach  that  isodapane  of  the  new  subset  which  has  the  lowest  value;  it  will 
be  tangent  to  the  isovector.  Once  again,  we  are  substituting  between  trans- 
port inputs — this  time  between  transport  inputs  on  the  raw  material  from 
i¥i  and  on  the  finished  product  to  C.  Or,  to  put  it  otherwise,  we  are  moving 
along  a  transformation  line  on  to  the  lowest  price-ratio  line.  We  reach 
another  point  of  partial  locational  equilibrium,  partial  since  we  hold  fixed  the 
value  for  the  variable,  transport  inputs  from  Mg- 

Next  we  (1)  select  either  that  isovector  centering  around  C  or  that  isovector 
centering  around  M^  which  passes  through  this  new  partial  equihbrium  point 
and  (2)  construct  still  another  subset  of  relevant  isodapanes.  As  before 
we  move  along  the  isovector  to  lower  and  lower  subset  isodapanes,  etc.,  etc. 

We  can  continue  this  procedure  until  we  reach  that  point  where  it  is  no 
longer  possible  to  move  on  to  any  lower  subset  isodapane  along  any  of  the 
three  isovectors  which  can  be  constructed  through  this  point.  That  is,  it  is 
no  longer  economic  to  substitute  between  any  pair  of  transport  inputs.  In 
essence,  we  have  a  coincidence  of  three  partial  locational  equilibrium  points. 
We  are  at  the  point  around  which  all  the  isodapanes  center.  We  are  at  the 
trough  of  the  transport  cost  surface. 

Thus,  it  is  clear  that  on  a  transport  cost  surface  (1)  economic  movement 
from  isodapane  to  isodapane  and  (2)  economic  movement  which  corresponds 
to  substitution  between  any  pair  of  transport  inputs  in  our  transformation 
sense  differ  in  direction  only.  They  aim  at  the  same  goal.  And,  in  fact, 
when  the  former  movement  is  restricted  to  paths  along  isovectors  on  to  subset 
isodapanes  of  lower  and  lower  value,  they  are  identical  and  translatable  one 
into  the  other.4  0 

40  In  the  above  discussion  we  have  implicitly  assumed  that  one  and  only  one 
minimum  point  exists.  Actually,  for  most  problems,  more  than  one  exists.  How- 
ever, this  does  not  qualify  our  basic  analysis.  Following  Palander  and  Hoover, 
the  reader  can  easily  reword  the  above  statements  to  cover  cases  with  several 
minimum  points. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  TRANSPORT— ORIENTATION     125 

In  this  appendix  an  attempt  has  been  made  to  translate  some  of  the  better 
formulations  of  the  transport-orientation  problem  into  substitution  relations 
among  transport  inputs.  It  has  not  been  the  intention  to  treat  and  translate 
each  formulation  comprehensively.  The  discussion  has  not  covered  all  the 
refinements  of  the  several  doctrines  which  are  presented  in  Launhardt,  Weber, 
Palander,  Dean,  Losch,  Hoover,  and  elsewhere;  rather,  it  has  sought  to  relate 
and  restate  only  the  basic  threads.  From  here  the  reader  can  easily  proceed 
further. 


Chapter 


The  Locational  Equilibrium 

of  the  Firm: 
Labor  and  Other  Orientation 


1.     Introductory  Remarks 

In  the  previous  chapter,  we  have  examined  the  conditions  for  the 
locational  equilibrium  of  transport- oriented  processes,  postulating 
that  among  sites  differentials  (except  those  arising  from  different 
transport  costs  on  raw  materials  and  finished  product)  either  do  not 
exist  or  are  insignificant.  Each  productive  factor  and  service,  other 
than  a  transported  raw  material  or  finished  product,  was  considered 
to  be  available  everywhere  in  correct  amounts  and  at  the  same  price. 
When  a  raw  material  was  present  at  several  sources,  it  was  taken  to  be 
adequately  available  at  the  same  price  for  all  sources.  When  more 
than  one  market  point  for  a  finished  product  existed,  at  each  the 
revenue  potential  or  the  ruling  price  on  the  finished  product  was 
posited  to  be  identical. 

We  now  relax  some  of  these  assumptions  and  introduce  differentials 
in  factor  costs  and  revenue  potentials,  i  To  incorporate  such  differen- 
tials into  general  locational  analysis  for  the  firm,  it  is  necessary  to 
think  in  terms  of  substitution  between  outlays,  between  revenues, 
and  between  outlays  and  revenues.  It  is  insufficient  here  to  speak 
of  substitution  between  the  commodities  encompassed  by  our  trans- 

1  We  consider  differentials  in  revenue  potential  since  a  firm  may  consider  several 
production  locations  which  may  serve  directly,  or  be  gateway  points  to,  different 
markets  where  different  prices  and  demand  elasticities  for  the  firm's  product (s) 
obtain. 

126 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      127 

formation  function,  for  it  is  the  variations  from  site  to  site  in  the 
prices  of  these  inputs  and  outputs  which,  along  with  other  forces, 
influence  location.  For  example,  Weber  discusses  the  phenomenon 
of  labor  orientation  where  a  firm  does  not  locate  at  the  transport 
optimum  point  representing  the  best  combination  of  transport  inputs 
but  rather  at  a  cheap  labor  point.  When  these  two  points  are  not 
identical,  the  firm  thereby  consumes  more  transport  inputs  and  in- 
creases its  transport  outlays  while  it  simultaneously  holds  constant 
(or  even  increases)  its  labor  inputs  but  reduces  its  labor  outlays, 
ceteris  paribus.  We  do  not  have  substitution  between  transport 
inputs  and  labor  inputs  but  rather  between  transport  outlays  and 
labor  outlays. 

2.     Labor  Orientation 

It  is  possible  to  develop  conceptual  schemes  to  treat  substitutions 
between  outlays,  between  revenues,  and  between  outlays  and  revenues. 
Suppose  within  the  typical  Weberian  framework  we  allow  first  in- 
equalities in  labor  resources  among  sites  and  consequent  differentials 
in  labor  costs.  To  every  realistic  point  on  the  transformation  line  for 
a  pair  of  transport  input  variables,  we  can  assign  not  only  a  necessary- 
transport  outlay  as  given  by  the  iso-outlay  line  which  passes  through 
it  but  also  a  labor  outlay.  Thus,  if  we  take  the  realistic  points 
G,  F,  J,  E,  and  H  on  the  transformation  line  in  Fig.  23  and  assume 
that  labor  outlay  per  ton  of  product  is  $20.00  at  each  of  the  sites 
represented  by  these  points,  except  the  cheap  labor  site^  represented 

2  The  term  cheap  labor  is  employed  here  in  a  broad  sense.  A  site  where  cheap 
money  wages  are  paid  to  labor  is  not  necessarily  a  cheap  labor  site  if  the  labor 
is  inefficient;  on  the  other  hand,  a  site  where  high  money  wages  are  paid  can  be 
a  cheap  labor  site  if  the  efficiency  of  labor  more  than  counterbalances  the  high 
money  wages.  The  fundamental  concept  is  the  wage  per  labor  service  of  a  given 
quality  or  per  efficiency  unit. 

Cheap  labor  areas  or  sites  arise  from  a  number  of  circumstances.  Often  rela- 
tively low  wage  payments  are  found  to  be  characteristic  of  a  surplus  agricultural 
region.  Such  payments  reflect  the  relatively  small  transport  cost  for  food  and 
drink  consumed  by  the  laborer  and  his  family.  A  relatively  low  wage  payment 
permits  a  satisfactory  content  of  living.  However,  if  one  considers  food  and  drink 
for  laborers  as  raw  materials  in  the  production  process,  which  conceptually  is  a 
consistent  procedure,  then  surplus  agricultural  regions,  which  contain  good  assem- 
bly points  for  these  raw  materials,  need  not  be  locationally  classified  as  cheap 
labor  areas. 

As  Ohlin,  Hoover,  and  others  have  noted,  differences  in  wages  which  are  attrib- 
utable to  differences  in  transport  costs,  and,  therefore,  total  costs  of  the  same 
basket  of  consumer  goods  (budget  materials)  at  different  places  may  be  classified 
as  "equalizing"  differences.  These  contrast  with  "real"  differences.  Since  equaliz- 
ing differences  arise  from  transport  cost  differentials,  they  represent  part  of  the 


128  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

by  J  where  it  is  only  $16.00/^  we  can  depict  the  respective  transport 
and  labor  outlays  incurred  at  these  sites  by  corresponding  points 
in  Fig.  25.  In  this  figure,  labor  outlays  and  transport  outlays  are 
measured  along  the  vertical  and  horizontal  axes,  respectively.  As 
in  Fig.  23,  point  F  is  taken  to  be  the  optimum  transport  point. 

Also  in  Fig.  25,  we  have  plotted  the  points  L,  M,  N,  and  R,  which 
represent  other  cheap  labor  sites.  These  additional  positions  do  not 
have  corresponding  realistic  points  on  the  transformation  line  of 
Fig.  23.  But,  in  the  light  of  all  possible  variations  in  all  transport 
inputs  (transport  inputs  on  raw  material  ilfi,  on  raw  material  M2, 
and  on  finished  product),  such  additional  positions  correspond  to 
realistic  points  on  transformation  lines  when  the  quantity  of  transport 
inputs  on  the  finished  product  to  C  is  different  from  that  assumed 
in  Fig.  23.  Other  realistic  points  which  may  or  may  not  be  cheap 
labor  sites  can  also  be  plotted,  but  plotting  them  is  not  necessary 
to  elucidate  the  argument. 

When  two  or  more  points  incur  the  same  labor  outlay,  we  consider 
only  the  one  which  involves  the  least  transport  outlay;  and  when, 
in  Fig.  25,  we  connect  these  points  in  order  according  to  transport 
outlay,  we  obtain  the  line  FJLMNR,  which  may  be  called  an  "outlay- 
substitution"  line.    It  presents  the  meaningful  substitution  possibilities 

transport  orientation  problem  and  should  be  treated  as  such.  Their  inclusion  in 
the  transport  orientation  problem  is,  however,  more  complex  than  is  often  realized. 

Major  industrial  centers  based  upon  coal  mining,  iron  and  steel  manufacture, 
and  other  primary  economic  activities  which  engage  the  chief  breadwinners  of 
families  frequently  have  supplies  of  secondary  labor  available,  i.e.,  labor  which 
is  surplus  to  the  primary  industries  yet  immobile  because  the  location  of  the 
chief  breadwinner  determines  the  location  of  the  secondary  labor  supplied  by  the 
family.  Like  any  other  surplus  commodity,  this  labor  can  usually  be  purchased 
at  bargain  rates.  Parasitic  industry  is  attracted  by  it.  But  it  is  important  to 
recognize  that  this  kind  of  attraction  is  fundamentally  conditioned  by  a  site's 
attraction  for  dominant  industries;  it  can  be  explained  only  in  terms  of  the  total 
situation.  Basically,  such  parasitic  industry  is  not  a  case  of  labor  orientation. 
Differentials  in  regional  development  of  secondary  industry  must  be  stated  in 
terms  of  differentials  in  regional  development  of  different  primary  industries. 

Cheap  labor  sites  are  most  often  attributable  to  cultural  factors  such  as  are 
found  in  poverty  stricken  regions  where  long-run  immobility  of  labor  obtains. 
Frequently,  the  laborer  may  be  willing  to  forego  leisure  and  to  sell  his  services  at 
a  low  price  in  order  to  supplement  his  other  income  and  thus  obtain  the  purchas- 
ing power  requisite  for  minimum  subsistence  living. 

For  full  discussion  of  these  and  related  points,  refer  to  Dean  (Selections),  op.  cit., 
pp.  22-30;  Ohlin,  op.  cit.,  pp.  212-20;  and  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  pp.  60-74. 

3  We  repeat :  Weber  assumes  that  the  wage  levels  of  labor  at  the  several  loca- 
tions are  fixed  and  that  the  labor  supply  available  at  each  location  is  unlimited. 
(Friedrich,  o-p.  cit.,  p.  101.) 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      129 

between  transport  outlays  and  labor  outlays,  just  as  the  transformation 
line  does  for  two  inputs.  We  also  construct  a  new  set  of  iso-outlay 
(transport  plus  labor  outlay)  lines  which  are  straight  and  obviously 
have  a  negative  slope  of  unity  when  the  same  scale  is  used  along 
both  axes.  TU  and  CD  are  two  such  lines  representing  (on  transport 
and  labor)  combined  outlays  of  $56.00  and  $50.00  respectively. 


Q       30 

Fig.  25.    An  outlay-substitution  line  in  a  case  of  labor  orientation. 


40  50      W    U         60 

Transport  outlay  ($) 


Of  all  points  on  the  outlay-substitution  line,  J  lies  on  the  lowest 
iso-outlay  line.  It  indicates  location  at  a  cheap  labor  site  rather 
than  at  F,  the  minimum  transport  cost  point,  and,  hence,  a  substitution 
of  transport  outlays  for  labor  outlays  if  location  were  initially  at  F. 

If  the  reader  cares  to,  he  may  state  formal  conditions  for  equilibrium 
with  respect  to  these  two  outlays.  These  conditions  might  almost 
parallel  those  stated  in  the  preceding  chapter.  With  Q  as  origin 
(Fig.  25) ,  to  the  left  of  the  equilibrium  point  when  it  is  not  an  end 
point,  the  outlay-substitution  line  between  transport  outlay  and 
labor  outlay  must  be  steeper  than  the  relevant  iso-outlay  line;  and, 
to  the  right  of  the  equilibrium  point  when  it  is  not  an  end  point,  either 


130  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

the  iso-outlay  line  must  be  steeper  than  the  outlay-substitution  line 
or  else  the  outlay-substitution  line  must  have  a  positive  slope.  ^ 

Incidentally,  the  approach  illustrated  in  Fig.  25  does  away  with  the 
unnecessarily  complex  Weberian  technique  for  determining  whether 
or  not  an  operation  will  be  labor  oriented  and,  if  so,  to  which  labor 
site.  According  to  Weber,  one  must  construct  the  critical  isodapane^ 
for  each  cheap  labor  site,  consider  only  those  sites  which  fall  within 
their  critical  isodapanes,  and  select  that  site  which  in  terms  of  "ideal" 
distance  lies  farthest  from  its  critical  isodapane.  Using  the  above 
graphic  technique,  one  needs  to  observe  whether  or  not  any  points 
representing  cheap  labor  sites  lie  on  lower  iso-outlay  lines  than  does 

4  Along  certain  stretches,  the  slope  of  an  outlay-substitution  line  may  well  be 
positive.  For,  in  moving  from  one  cheap  labor  site  to  another,  from  left  to  right 
along  the  outlay-substitution  line  of  Fig.  25,  not  only  will  transport  outlay  rise 
but  also  labor  outlay  will  increase  if  at  the  second  cheap  labor  site  labor  is  some- 
what more  dear.  In  contrast,  when  dealing  with  transformation  lines  for  two 
transport  inputs  (or  distance  variables)  where  only  a  finite  number  of  points  can 
be  considered  as  location  sites,  one  would  encounter  positive  slopes  only  when 
"unnecessary  distance"  is  traversed,  e.g.,  where  a  firm  locates  outside  the  locational 
polygon.  This  possibility  has  been  logically  excluded  from  our  analysis  except 
for  the  case  where  there  is  a  particular  type  of  irregularity  in  the  transport  rate 
structure. 

Also,  the  above  conditions,  as  in  the  previous  chapter,  may  be  satisfied  by  more 
than  one  point.  It  becomes  necessary  to  select  the  best  from  among  such  points. 
For  example,  in  Fig.  25  both  J  and  N  meet  the  requirements  stated  above.  Obvi- 
ously J,  lying  on  the  lowest  iso-outlay  line,  is  the  more  desirable  site  of  the  two. 

Again  it  is  worthy  to  note  the  extent  of  discontinuity  involved  in  reality. 
Usually  the  possibihties  of  substitution  do  not  permit  a  gradual  geographic  shift 
through  sites  in  turn  necessitating  less  and  less  labor  outlay  and  more  and  more 
transport  outlay  until  the  optimum  combination  is  reached.  Rather,  as  Weber 
states,  the  problem  is  one  of  an  alternative  attraction  (Alternativattraktion)  not 
an  approaching  attraction  (Annaherungsattraktion).  It  does  no  good  to  move 
from  the  optimum  transport  point  to  a  site  nearer  the  cheap  labor  location.  In 
such  a  shift,  labor  outlays  are  not  usually  significantly  affected.  To  derive  the 
benefits  of  cheap  labor,  one  has  to  migrate  to  the  cheap  labor  site  itself.  Spatially 
speaking,  there  is  no  continuity  in  this  migration.  It  involves  in  the  typical  case 
a  discrete  geographic  jump. 

5  In  contrast  to  Palander  and  Hoover,  Weber  uses  the  isodapane  concept  in  a 
marginal  sense  rather  than  in  the  total  sense  as  defined  in  the  Appendix  to  Chap.  5. 
Thus  according  to  Weber,  whom  we  follow  in  this  and  subsequent  chapters,  an 
isodapane  is  a  curve  connecting  points  representing  locations  involving  the  same 
increases  of  transport  cost  over  the  cost  incurred  at  the  transport  optimum  point. 
The  critical  isodapane  for  any  cheap  labor  site  is  the  one  which  represents  an  addi- 
tional transport  outlay  equivalent  to  the  saving  in  labor  outlay  at  the  cheap  labor 
site.  If  the  site  lies  anywhere  within  the  area  bounded  by  the  critical  isodapane, 
it  becomes  eligible  for  attracting  the  production  process  under  consideration 
(Weber,  op.  cit.,  pp.  102-04). 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      131 

the  point  representing  the  transport  optimum  site.  If  none  does, 
there  will  be  no  deviation  to  a  labor  location.  If  more  than  one  do, 
then  the  firm  will  shift  to  a  cheap  labor  site  and  to  that  one  which 
lies  on  the  lowest  iso-outlay  line.    In  Fig.  23  such  a  site  is  J.^ 

The  above  presentation  of  the  labor  orientation  problem,  however, 
is  inadequate.  For,  assuming  still  that  all  other  factors  are  ubiquitous 
and  available  everywhere  at  the  same  cost,  it  is  reasonable  to  expect 
another  type  of  adjustment,  specifically,  a  tendency  for  substitution 
at  the  cheap  labor  site  of  cheap  labor  for  transport  inputs,  provided 
production  coefficients  and  other  technical  relations  are  not  fixed.  This 
might  take  the  form  of  reduction  in  bulk  of  the  product,  in  weight,  in 
perishability,  and  so  forth.  And,  if  the  cheap  labor  site's  advantage 
lay  in  the  exploitability  of  a  special  class  of  labor,  let  us  say  un- 
skilled labor,  we  might  face  the  additional  substitution  problem  of 
skilled  labor  vs.  unskilled  labor.''  This  is  the  type  of  substitution 
problem  within  a  substitution  problem  that  Predohl  had  in  mind. 
The  adjustment,  however,  would  not  affect  the  conditions  to  be  met 
by  an  equilibrium  point.  Cheap  labor  points  would  lie  on  lower 
iso-outlay  lines  above  and  to  the  left  of  their  respective  positions  on 
Fig.  25.  This  adjustment,  of  course,  might  involve  a  change  of  the 
equilibrium  site. 

3.     Some  Other  Forms  of  Orientation 

In  the  above  section  we  have  relaxed  the  assumption  that  the  costs 
of  an  efficiency  unit  of  labor  at  all  locations  were  alike.  Differentials 
in  labor  costs  were  introduced,  while,  by  assumption,  differentials  in 
other  costs  (except  transport)  were  precluded.  We  now  proceed  to 
preclude  differentials  in  labor  cost,  while  allowing  differentials  in 
transport  costs  and  in  just  one  other  cost  item,  let  us  say  power. 

It  is  clear  that  in  this  new  situation  a  procedure  paralleling  that 
of  the  preceding  section  may  be  utilized.  To  every  realistic  point  on 
the  transformation  line  for  a  pair  of  transport  inputs,  we  can  assign 
not  only  a  necessary  transport  outlay  as  given  by  the  iso-outlay  line 
which  passes  through  it  but  also  a  power  outlay.    For  each  point,  the 

^  Also,  the  above  graphic  approach  provides  a  simpler  framework  when  adjust- 
ments need  to  be  made  for  transport  savings  from  the  use  of  replacement  deposits 
in  Weber's  sense.  However,  logically  the  use  of  a  replacement  deposit  signifies  a 
shift  from  the  supply  area  of  one  source  of  the  raw  material  in  question  to  the 
supply  area  of  a  second  source.  Such  use  is  therefore  more  appropriately  consid- 
ered as  a  phase  of  supply  area  analysis  to  be  treated  below. 

'^  Since  for  the  present  all  other  factors  are  considered  ubiquitous  and  available 
everywhere  at  the  same  cost,  there  would  also  tend  to  be  a  substitution  of  cheap 
labor  for  these  factors  at  cheap  labor  sites. 


132  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

associated  transport  outlay  and  power  outlay  can  be  plotted  on  a  graph 
along  whose  horizontal  and  vertical  axes  transport  and  power  outlays 
are  measured  respectively.  Also,  for  every  realistic  point  on  other 
transformation  lines  for  any  pair  of  transport  inputs,  both  transport 
and  power  outlays  can  be  derived  and  plotted  on  the  same  graph. 
When  we  view  the  entire  set  of  points  depicted  on  this  graph  and, 
of  two  or  more  points  incurring  the  same  power  outlay,  consider  only 
the  one  which  involves  the  least  transport  outlay,  and  when  we  con- 
nect these  points  in  order  according  to  transport  outlay,  we  obtain 
another  type  of  outlay-substitution  line.  This  type  presents  the 
meaningful  substitution  possibilities  between  transport  and  power 
outlays,  just  as  the  type  of  outlay-substitution  line  in  Fig.  25  presents 
the  meaningful  substitution  possibilities  between  transport  and  labor 
outlays.  We  can  also  construct  a  new  set  of  iso-outlay  (transport  plus 
power  outlay)  lines,  which,  like  the  iso-outlay  lines  in  Fig.  25,  are 
straight  and  have  a  negative  slope  of  unity  when  the  same  scale  is 
used  along  both  axes. 

Given  the  iso-outlay  lines  and  the  outlay-substitution  line,  it  would 
be  easy  to  identify  in  our  assumed  situation  the  optimum  location. 
This  location  would  correspond  to  that  point  on  the  outlay-substitu- 
tion line  lying  on  the  lowest  of  the  iso-outlay  lines.  Formal  condi- 
tions of  locational  equilibrium  could  be  stated.  Allowance  could  be 
made  for  the  substitution  at  cheap  power  sites  of  power  inputs  for 
transport  inputs  and  other  inputs,  technological  and  economic  condi- 
tions permitting.  This  substitution  would  be  in  addition  to  the  sub- 
stitution associated  with  locational  shift  which  takes  place  along  the 
outlay-substitution  line. 

In  this  way,  the  significance  which  variation  in  power  cost  has  for 
locational  equilibrium  can  be  evaluated  under  our  given  set  of  assump- 
tions. When  the  point  on  the  outlay-substitution  line  which  lies  on 
the  lowest  iso-outlay  line  (after  adjustment  has  been  made  for  sub- 
stitution among  inputs)  corresponds  to  a  cheap  power  point,  we 
have  the  familiar  case  of  power  orientation.  According  to  Weber's 
terminology,  the  cheap  power  point  lies  within  the  critical  isodapane; 
or,  according  to  Dean's  terminology,  there  are  deviational  economies, 
and  the  largest  possible  deviational  economies,  in  shifting  to  this 
particular  cheap  power  point  in  our  assumed  situation. ^ 

In  similar  fashion,  it  is  possible  to  consider  formally  the  variation 

8  Paralleling  the  concept  of  labor  coefficient  and  the  ratio  of  labor  savings  to 
additional  transport  outlays  (which  are  discussed  in  the  Appendix  to  this  chapter), 
one  can  construct  a  power  coefficient  and  the  ratio  of  power  cost  savings  to  addi- 
tional transport  outlays  and  use  them  as  we  use  the  labor  coefficient  and  corre- 
sponding ratio. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      133 

in  the  costs  of  other  input  items  resulting  from  diverse  inequalities 
in  mineral  and  human  resources  and  from  differences  in  cultural  and 
political  institutions.  Along  with  variation  in  transport  outlays,  the 
variation  of  the  interest  rate  among  sites  and  regions  might  be  con- 
sidered in  isolation.  We  could  construct  outlay-substitution  lines 
(referring  to  the  variation  at  different  sites  in  outlays  on  interest 
and  on  transport)  and  relevant  iso-outlay  lines  to  determine  which 
(if  any)  cheap  interest  point  might  deviate  the  location  of  production 
from  the  minimum  transport  cost  point.  In  this  problem,  at  least 
implicit  consideration  would  have  to  be  given  to  the  alternatives  in 
the  use  of  different  types  of  venture  and  other  capital  and  to  the 
entire  set  of  input  substitution  points  associated  with  the  width 
and  depth  of  capital  structure. 

Or  we  might  consider  in  isolation  variation  in  transport  outlays 
and  tax  outlays ;  or  in  transport  outlays  and  rent  outlays ;  or  in  trans- 
port outlays  and  in  general  production  outlays  where  differences  in 
general  production  outlays  obtain  because  of  differences  among  sites 
in  climatic  and  other  environmental  features,  in  union  restrictions 
and  diverse  social  burdens,  in  agglomeration  and  industrial  and 
population  density,  and  so  forth. 

Another  differential  that  may  confront  the  individual  producer  may 
be  in  the  price  of  raw  materials  at  different  sources,  whether  owing 
to  differences  in  fertility,  richness  of  ore,  processing  costs,  etc.,  or  to 
imposed  competitive  differences.  As  before,  assuming  all  other  factor 
costs  geographically  uniform,  one  can  measure  transport  outlay  along 
one  axis  and  outlay  (at  the  source)  on  raw  material  A  along  the  other. 
One  can  then  plot  the  respective  outlays  for  any  possible  site.  How- 
ever, only  those  sites  are  relevant  which  involve,  for  each  possible 
source  of  the  raw  material  under  consideration,  the  least  transport 
outlay  for  assembling  all  the  raw  materials  required  in  production 
and  carrying  the  finished  product  to  the  market.  There  will  be  a 
deviation  from  the  site  involving  the  least  aggregate  transport  outlay 
of  all  (i.e.,  the  best  of  the  several  relative  minimum  points  with 
respect  to  transport  cost)  to  an  optimum  position  with  respect  to  the 
cheaper  raw  material  source  if  the  saving  from  the  lower  price  of  raw 
material  more  than  counterbalances  the  increased  outlay  on  transport 
occasioned  by  the  shift.  The  new  site  would  lie  on  an  iso-outlay 
(transport  plus  raw  material  A  outlay)  line  lower  than  the  first. 
Usually  the  shift  would  involve  a  discrete  spatial  jump,  except  in  the 
case  of  agricultural  raw  materials  or  the  like  for  which  there  are 
large  supply  areas.  And  similarly  with  sources  of  other  raw  materials, 
each  in  turn. 

Again  one  might  consider  differentials  in  price  received  per  unit 


134 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


of  product  at  various  consumption  places  for  the  case  where  a  firm 
confronts  a  geographic  pattern  of  market  prices  upon  which  it  has 
httle,  if  any,  infiuence,  and  where  the  differential  aspects  of  this  pattern 
are  unrelated  to  the  given  firm's  transport  outlays.     In  Fig.  26,  one 


Transport  outlay 


Fig.  26.    A  revenue-outlay  substitution  line. 


measures  total  transport  outlay  on  inputs  and  output  along  the 
horizontal  axis  and  revenue  from  sale  of  product  along  the  vertical, 
all  other  outlays  and  revenues  being  held  constant.  Here,  one  is 
concerned  with  iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines,  i.e.,  constant  product 
revenue  less  transport  outlay  lines,  with  the  result  that  of  two  such 
lines  a  position  on  the  one  to  the  left  is  more  desirable.  These 
straight  iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines,  unlike  those  involving  two  kinds 
of  outlays,  have  positive  slopes.  In  Fig.  26,  point  S  is  that  site  which 
incurs  the  least  transport  outlay.  However,  positions  R,  N,  and  M, 
being  "higher-price"  markets  or  being  gateway  points  to  higher-price 
consumption  places,  all  offer  larger  revenue  from  sale  of  the  product 
than  does  point  S.  In  the  case  of  point  R,  the  additional  revenue 
more  than  counterbalances  the  additional  transport  outlay  required 
for  assembling  raw  materials  at  R  and  for  shipping  the  product  to  the 
corresponding  consumption   place.     R   then   is   a   preferred  position 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      135 

lying  on  a  higher  iso-revenue-less-outlay  line  than  does  S,  N,  or  M.^ 
If  more  than  one  output  is  produced,  we  can  construct  a  similar 
chart  for  each.io 

This  sort  of  partial  analysis,  however,  where  all  costs  and  revenues 
but  two  are  held  constant,  is  inadequate  and  of  little  pragmatic  value. 
Weber  recognized  this  fact  when,  speaking  of  shifts  to  labor  locations, 
he  took  into  consideration  the  economies  to  be  gained  by  replacement 
of  material  deposits,  that  is,  by  utilization  of  new  raw  material  sources 
closer  to  labor  locations  rather  than  those  sources  which  were  more 
favorably  situated  in  relation  to  the  market  to  be  served  and  the 
optimum  transport  point.  Without  doubt,  if  a  plant  does  find  it 
expedient  to  shift  to  a  cheap  labor  site,  a  cheap  power  site,  or  a  site 
better  able  to  serve  a  higher  revenue  consumption  place,  other  out- 
lays and  revenues  besides  transport  outlay  do  change  in  the  usual 
case.  We  thus  require  a  substitution  analysis  which  can  treat  differen- 
tials in  all  types  of  costs  and  revenues  at  one  time,  not  just  differentials 
in  two  types  alone. 

An  extension  of  the  analytical  technique  to  meet  this  requirement 
can  be  forced  along  familiar  lines.  When  one  attacks  the  problem  of 
choosing  correct  quantities  of  physical  inputs  and  outputs,  he  may  first 
consider  the  substitution  point  relating  any  two  commodities,  the 
basket  of  all  other  commodities  being  given.  Then  in  turn  he  may 
derive  the  substitution  point  for  a  second  pair,  a  third  pair,  and  so  on. 
During  these  latter  operations,  if  the  derived  quantity  of  any  com- 
modity is  inconsistent  with  the  quantity  previously  assigned  to  the 
same  commodity  within  the  fixed  basket  of  goods  when  the  substitution 
relations  between  a  first  pair  of  goods  was  being  considered,  then  one 
changes  the  composition  of  the  basket  to  make  it  consistent  with  the 
new  quantity.  In  turn,  this  change  is  likelj^  to  lead  to  a  new  sub- 
stitution point  for  the  first  two  commodities  and  a  change  in  the 
quantities  desired.  And  this  change  in  the  first  pair  of  values  is  likely 
to  alter  the  substitution  relations  between  other  pairs  of  goods,  and 
different  quantities  of  these  other  goods  might  then  be  desirable.  This 
process  continues  until  finally  a  consistent  set  of  substitution  points 

9  Note  also  that  the  formal  partial  equilibrium  conditions  can  be  stated.  They 
are  met  in  this  situation.  Viewed  with  point  Q  as  origin,  to  the  left  of  point  R 
the  iso-revenue-less-outlay  Hne  has  a  slope  less  steep  than  that  of  the  revenue- 
outlay  substitution  hne  (SRNM) ;  and  to  the  right  of  point  R  the  revenue-outlay 
substitution  line  has  a  negative  slope.  R  would  still  be  an  equilibrium  point  if 
to  its  right  the  slope  of  the  revenue-outlay  substitution  line  were  positive  so 
long  as  it  were  less  than  the  slope  of  the  iso-revenue-less-outlay  line. 

10  The  substitution  analysis  centering  upon  the  relation  between  the  location 
of  a  firm  and  its  scale  of  operations  is  considered  in  Chap.  8. 


136  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

is  obtained,  wherein  the  equilibrium  conditions  are  satisfied  for  every 
meaningful  pair  of  commodities. 

At  the  start  one  may  be  inclined  to  approach  the  problem  in  the  same 
fashion  when  differentials  in  several  types  of  costs  and  revenues  exist 
between  sites.  One  takes  two  outlays  which  are  different  at  several 
sites  that  in  other  respects  possess  similar  price  and  cost  structures 
and  finds  the  best  combination  of  these  outlays,  as  in  Fig.  25  above. 
Similarly  with  another  pair  of  outlays  until  all  possible  pairs  are 
considered.  However,  one  finds  that  different  sets  of  sites  pertain  to 
different  pairs  of  outlays.  This  finding  means  that  the  above  pro- 
cedure, though  logical  for  certain  equilibrium  analyses,  overlooks  one 
important  aspect  of  the  location  problem.  Sites  are  often  unlike 
with  respect  to  more  than  tvv^o  outlays.  Where  all  sites  differ  in  at 
least  three  outlays,  the  above  process  is  inappropriate.  But  by  lump- 
ing together  two  or  more  outlays,  so  that  two  or  more  sites  are  alike 
except  with  respect  to  two  groups  of  outlays,  one  can  still  utiHze  this 
analytical  technique. 

It  is  important  to  recognize  that  this  is  essentially  no  different  from 
the  procedure  where  two  or  more  commodities  are  used  in  fixed  pro- 
portions. If  the  consumption  of  commodity  j,  belonging  to  a  group 
of  commodities  used  in  fixed  proportions,  is  increased  to  replace  some 
of  commodity  m  which  is  not  included  in  the  group,  we  cannot 
construct  a  transformation  line  between  commodities  j  and  m,  the 
basket  of  all  other  commodities  being  fixed.  For,  as  the  quantity  of  ; 
varies,  so  vary  the  quantities  of  those  commodities  used  in  fixed 
proportion  to  commodity  ;.  As  a  consequence,  the  basket  of  all  com- 
modities other  than  ;  and  m  cannot  be  given.  The  only  method  of 
attack  is  to  consider  as  a  whole  the  commodities  used  in  fixed  pro- 
portions and  to  inquire  into  the  substitutability  of  this  group  for 
commodity  m,  the  basket  of  other  commodities  being  given. 

When  one  lumps  together  two  or  more  outlays  to  derive  an  outlay- 
substitution  line  between  any  two  groups  of  outlays,  he  is  using  this 
same  technique.  Here  he  has  no  such  explicit  constraints  on  the 
variation  in  quantities  of  commodities  as  those  given  by  the  trans- 
formation function.  He  has  only  a  geographic  pattern  of  resources 
and  facilities  resulting  in  price-cost  differentials.  But  this  does  not 
preclude  using  an  identical  procedure.  He  can  construct  outlay- 
substitution,  revenue-outlay  substitution,  and  revenue-substitution  lines 
between  all  possible  pairs  of  outlays  and  revenues  or  groups  of  outlays 
and  revenues.  If  all  sites  manifest  price  differentials  with  respect 
to  only  three  outlays — transport,  labor,  and  interest — one  can  con- 
struct an  outlay-substitution  line,  measuring  transport  outlay  along 
one  axis  and  labor  plus  interest  outlay  along  the  other.    The  relevant 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      137 

price-ratio  lines  would  be  iso-outlay  (transport  plus  labor  plus  in- 
terest outlay)  lines.  11  If  sites  exhibit  differences  among  four  items — 
whether  they  be  outlays  or  revenues — measuring  along  the  first  axis 
either  one  or  the  aggregate  of  two  items  and  along  the  second  axis 
the  aggregate  of  respectively  three  or  two  items,  one  can  derive  a 
substitution  line  from  plotting  the  values  associated  with  each  site  to 
contrast  with  appropriately  derived  iso-lines.  And  in  similar  fashion 
one  can  treat  the  situation  where  differences  among  sites  exists  among 
five  or  more  items.  12 

If  there  are  differentials  among  all  sites  with  respect  to  each  cost 
and  revenue,  then,  the  above  procedure  being  followed,  the  problem  of 
optimum  location  would  reduce  to  a  simple  substitution  relation  be- 
tween two  groups  of  outlays  and  revenues.  At  this  juncture,  however, 
cloaking  the  analysis  in  terms  of  substitution  would  be  of  little  value. 
A  forthright  comparison  of  total  costs  at  each  site  will  achieve  the 
desired  result  more  readily.  Likewise,  the  site  of  production  being 
given,  the  substitution  technique  degenerates  when  all  inputs  and 
outputs  fall  into  two  groups,  the  commodities  within  each  group  being 
used  in  fixed  proportions.  In  this  situation  there  is  only  one  sub- 
stitution relation,  namely,  between  the  two  groups  of  commodities. 
In  reality,  however,  the  various  constraints  to  the  transformation 
function  usually  leave  room  for  many  substitution  relations  between 
the  different  commodities.  Likewise,  potential  sites  for  a  production 
process  do  not  manifest  major  price  differentials  in  many  categories 
of  costs  and  revenues.  The  fewer  constraints  to  the  transforma- 
tion function  and  the  fewer  major  price  differentials  among  all  sites, 
the  more  pertinent  is  substitution  analysis  (except  for  the  extreme 
case). 

11  And  a  la  Weber,  he  might  be  incHned  to  compute  "labor-interest  coefficients." 
However,  he  would  soon  discover  extreme  difficulties  in  the  use  of  such  a 
coefficient. 

12  An  alternative  to  this  procedure  is  to  divide  sites  into  groups,  each  group 
containing  sites  which  differ  with  respect  to  two  items  only  (when  sites  in  general 
differ  in  at  least  three  items),  or  with  respect  to  three  items  only  (when  sites  in 
general  differ  in  at  least  four  items),  or  with  respect  to  four  items  only  (when  sites 
in  general  differ  in  at  least  five  items),  and  so  forth.  For  each  group  of  sites  the 
optimum  one  can  be  obtained  through  the  above  substitution  analysis  where  along 
each  axis  one,  or  the  aggregate  of  two  or  more  items,  is  measured.  The  total 
revenue  and  cost  situation  for  each  of  the  resulting  "partial"  optimum  sites  can 
be  directly  compared  to  yield  the  over-all  optimum  location.  Or  the  over-all  opti- 
mum location  may  be  derived  by  a  division  of  all  the  differential  revenue  and 
cost  items  into  two  groups,  and  by  a  plot  for  each  of  the  "partial"  optimum 
points  of  the  aggregate  of  each  group  (upon  a  chart  along  whose  axes  the  two 
aggregates  are  measured)  in  order  to  yield  a  substitution  hne  to  contrast  with 
an  appropriately  derived  iso-line. 


138  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

4.     A  Re-examination  of  the  Substitution  Framework  for 
Spatial  Analysis 

It  is  appropriate  at  this  juncture  to  evaluate  the  substitution  ap- 
proach developed  in  this  and  the  preceding  chapter.  As  already  inti- 
mated, it  may  be  contended  that  at  least  to  some  degree  the  substitution 
framework  has  been  pushed  to  undesirable  length.  Such  a  view  stems 
from  a  consideration  of  the  spatial  setting  within  which  various  types 
of  costs  and  revenues  vary. 

For  certain  purposes  it  is  convenient  to  classify  location  factors 
into  three  groups.  These  groups,  though  generally  valid  for  our 
purposes,  overlap  to  some  degree  and  cannot  be  precisely  delineated. 
In  the  first  group  may  be  included  transport  costs  and  certain  other 
transfer  costs.  The  distinguishing  feature  of  these  transport  and  trans- 
fer costs  is  that  they  vary  regularly  with  distance  from  any  given 
point  of  reference,  usually  increasing  in  step-by-step  fashion  as  dis- 
tance increases.  Hence,  given  a  relevant  set  of  reference  points, 
whether  they  be  raw  material,  service,  nodal,  or  market  points,  we 
find  systematic  variation  of  these  costs  over  space.  The  structure  of 
transport  rates  and  the  tariff  structures  for  other  transfer  costs  which 
are  a  function  of  distance  being  given,  the  systematic  variation  of 
these  costs  over  space  becomes  predictable. 

This  is  not  to  deny  that  exceptions  to  this  systematic  variation 
exist.  Such  exceptions  in  the  transport  rate  structure  have  already 
been  alluded  to  in  the  previous  chapter,  and  the  necessary  techniques 
to  incorporate  these  irregularities  into  the  main  body  of  rates,  without 
jeopardizing  the  system  of  this  body,  have  already  been  indicated.  In 
similar  ways,  exceptions  in  tariff  structures  for  other  transfer  costs 
which  are  a  function  of  distance  can  be  handled  without  destroying 
the  general  systematic  variation  of  these  costs  over  space. 

A  second  group  of  location  factors  comprises  the  several  costs 
associated  with  labor,  power,  water,  taxes,  insurance,  interest  (as 
payment  for  the  services  of  capital) ,  climate,  topography,  social  and 
political  milieu,  and  a  number  of  other  items.  The  geographic  cost 
pattern  of  many  of  these  items  may  be  said  to  be  relatively  stable. 
However,  in  contrast  to  the  first  group,  it  cannot  be  said  that  the 
costs  of  any  of  these  items  generally  vary  systematically  with  dis- 
tance from  any  given  reference  point.  Rather,  they  tend  to  vary 
haphazardly,  independently  of  direction  and  distance,  i^    Yor  example, 

13  On  the  surface,  there  appear  to  be  exceptions  to  this  statement.  Power  rates, 
for  example,  may  rise  regularly  with  distance  from  a  generating  station.  Once 
beyond  the  feasible  transmission  range,  however,  the  variation  of  power  rates  is 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      139 

cheap  labor  points  generally  occur  around  any  given  reference 
point  in  an  unpredictable  fashion.  There  is  no  reason  to  anticipate 
that,  given  any  set  of  spatial  co-ordinates,  cheap  labor  points  will 
be  some  function  of  distance  and  direction  from  that  defined  position. 
Hence,  in  this  sense,  analysis  of  labor  costs,  as  well  as  the  other 
costs  which  fall  in  this  second  group,  seeks  in  vain  for  any  meaningful 
general  spatial  framework. 

A  third  group  of  location  factors  comprises  the  diverse  elements 
which  give  rise  to  agglomeration  and  deglomeration  economies.  In- 
cluded in  agglomeration  economies  are:  (1)  economies  of  scale;  (2) 
localization  economies;  and  (3)  urbanization  economies. i*  Degiom- 
erative  forces  embrace  chiefly:  (1)  diseconomies  within  a  firm  as  its 
scale  of  operation  becomes  too  large;  (2)  the  rise  of  rents  and  costs 
of  urban  services  as  increase  in  the  intensity  of  land  use  and  population 
settlement  leads  to  congestion;  and  (3)  the  rise  in  the  cost  of  food 
supply  as  the  increase  in  the  size  of  population  settlement  compels 
resort  to  surplus  agricultural  areas  farther  and  farther  afield.  ^^ 

It  is  clear  from  an  analysis  of  agglomerative  and  deglomerative 
forces  that  their  operation  is  independent  of  geographic  position. 
Their  associated  economies  and  diseconomies  are  functionally  de- 
pendent  upon  the   magnitude   of   activities.     These   economies   and 

not  subject  to  regularity,  except  insofar  as  the  variation  reflects  differences  in  the 
transport  cost  of  fuel.  Essentially,  where  power  transmission  or  transportation 
of  fuel  is  possible,  a  regularity  may  ensue;  where  power  transmission  and  fuel 
transportation  are  infeasible,  irregularity  is  characteristic.  It  is  thus  transport 
cost  which  imparts  to  the  geographic  variation  of  power  rates  any  regularity 
which  it  possesses,  both  intraregionally  and  interregionally.  There  is  no  inherent 
regularity  in  the  geographic  distribution  of  energy  and  power  resources. 

Likewise  with  labor  costs.  To  some  degree,  regularity  in  the  variation  of  wage 
rates  over  space  may  be  said  to  have  existed  historically  and  to  persist  in  current 
times.  As  already  intimated,  such  regularity  is  for  the  most  part  related  to 
differences  in  transport  cost  in  obtaining  the  goods  in  the  laborer's  market  basket. 
For  a  given  content  of  living,  the  variation  in  wages  resulting  from  these  differ- 
ences in  transport  cost  have  already  been  referred  to  as  "equalizing"  differences 
in  money  wages.  They  are  to  be  distinguished  from  "real"  differences  in  money 
wages  which  do  not  exhibit  any  spatial  regularity.  Again,  it  is  the  transport 
element  which  imparts  a  regularity  to  the  spatial  cost  pattern  of  an  input,  which 
otherwise  does  not  possess  any  such  regularity.  Compare  Hoover,  Location 
Theory  and  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Industries,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1937,  Chap  IV. 

!•*  See  Chap.  8  for  full  discussion  of  them. 

15  To  the  extent  that  agglomerative  and  deglomerative  forces  are  associated  with 
the  increase  and  decrease  of  transport  cost,  or  of  any  other  cost  item  falling  in 
the  second  group,  to  the  same  extent  these  categories  of  location  forces,  as  already 
suggested,  overlap.  However,  such  an  overlap  does  not  seriously  interfere  with 
our  argument. 


140  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

diseconomies  obtain  regardless  of  the  locality  at  which  any  given 
magnitude  and  situational  interaction  of  activities  occur  (though,  to 
be  sure,  elements  of  the  physical  setting,  such  as  topography  and 
bedrock  conditions  can  influence  to  some  extent  the  intensity  with 
which  agglomerative  and  deglomerative  forces  operate).  These  forces 
are,  for  the  most  part,  spatially  passive.  They  are  adaptive,  and 
they  materialize  at  localities  where  other  considerations  either  dictate 
or  hinder  location.  Their  geographic  pattern  is  a  derived  one,  and  it 
reflects  the  regularities  and  irregularities  of  spatial  pattern  associated 
with  other  location  factors. 

Hence,  we  are  led  to  conclude  from  our  general  consideration  of 
these  three  groups  of  location  forces  that  only  the  transport  factor 
and  other  transfer  factors  whose  costs  are  functionally  related  to 
distance  impart  regularity  to  the  spatial  setting  of  activities.  Sub- 
stitution analysis  among  various  transport  inputs,  of  the  type  dis- 
cussed in  Chap.  5,  is  vital  for  understanding  the  spatial  configuration 
of  economic  activities  and  its  inherent  order  and  for  unearthing  the 
pervasive  impact  of  the  friction  of  distance.  On  the  other  hand, 
substitution  analysis  which  is  more  elaborate  than  the  sort  sketched 
in  the  preceding  sections  and  which  particularly  treats  at  one  time 
several  factors  that  either  haphazardly  distort  or  intensify  the  sys- 
tematic spatial  arrangement  imposed  by  the  transport  factor,  may  be 
judged  to  be  less  significant.  Such  analysis  possesses  less  value  at  this 
stage  where  we  are  concerned  with  the  development  of  equilibrium 
analysis  for  the  firm  as  an  integral  part  of  a  general  theory  of  space- 
economy  which  is  independent  of  any  particular  cultural,  institutional, 
or  geographic  frame  of  reference.  ^^ 

16  For  example,  it  may  be  maintained  by  some  that,  where  a  particular  process 
is  not  transport-oriented,  i.e.,  where  transport  cost  differentials  among  sites  are 
not  the  dominant  ones,  it  is  best  in  ascertaining  the  maximum  profit  location 
merely  to  recognize  that  substitutions  do  take  place  among  outlays  and  revenues 
and  to  focus  attention  upon  the  more  important  substitutions.  To  be  specific,  the 
indirect  shift  of  textile  capacity  from  New  England  to  the  cheap  labor  point  of 
Puerto  Rico  involved  a  substitution  of  transport  outlays  for  labor  outlays.  The 
cheap  labor  point,  however,  was  in  no  way  generally  related  to  a  distance  factor. 
It  could  have  existed  elsewhere.  This  arbitrariness,  it  may  be  contended,  weakens 
any  attempt  at  stating  general  formal  equihbrium  conditions  regarding  substitu- 
tion in  analyzing  the  spatial  equilibrium  of  this  case.  This  effect  is  even  greater, 
it  may  be  held,  when  tax  outlays  and  other  outlays  are  introduced  into  the  picture. 


LOCATION  EQUILIBRIUM:  LABOR  ORIENTATION      141 

Appendix  to  Chapter  6 
The  Labor  Coefficient  and  a  Related  Ratio 

Since  Weber's  concept  of  labor  coefficient  has  considerable  significance  for 
location  analysis,  it  is  useful  to  present  briefly  some  of  the  connections 
between  this  concept  and  a  related  ratio  directly  obtainable  from  substitu- 
tion between  transport  and  labor  outlays. 

In  considering  the  feasibility  of  the  shift  of  production  processes  from  their 
transport  optimal  points  to  cheap  labor  locations,  Weber  emphasizes  two 
industrial  characteristics:  (1)  locational  weight  (based  upon  "ideal"  instead 
of  actual  weights)  and  (2)  index  of  labor  costs  (i.e.,  average  labor  costs  per 
ton  product).  Also,  he  considers  of  primary  significance  three  environmental 
conditions:  (1)  geographic  position  of  locational  figures  and  labor  locations, 
(2)  transport  rates,  and  (3)  actual  percentage  of  compression  of  the  labor 
cost  index.  If  we  combine  locational  weight,  geographic  position  of  locational 
figures  and  labor  locations,  and  transport  rates,  we  obtain  the  set  of  addi- 
tional transport  outlays  associated  with  any  pattern  of  shift  from  the  transport 
optimal  site.  [These  outlays  may  be  comprehensively  depicted  by  a  set  of 
isodapanes.  Obviously  the  smaller  (greater)  the  locational  weight  and  the 
lower  (higher)  the  transport  rate,  the  farther  apart  (the  closer)  do  consecu- 
tive isodapanes  lie  and  the  greater  (less)  is  the  likelihood  of  deviation  to  a 
labor  location.  Unless  the  locational  figure  for  a  production  process  is 
symmetric  and  unit  weights  apply  to  all  corners,  there  will  not  be  an  equal 
tendency  to  deviate  in  all  directions.  Isodapanes  will  not  be  circular;  and, 
ceteris  paribus,  they  will  be  pulled  toward  the  corners  with  heaviest  weight. 
For  possible  deviations  over  short  distances,  this  distortion  of  circular  form 
may  be  significant.  As  the  distance  of  possible  deviation  increases,  the 
isodapanes  tend  to  approximate  more  and  more  a  set  of  concentric  circles, 
and  the  distorting  effect  of  any  asymmetric  locational  figure  and  pattern  of 
weights  can  be  increasingly  neglected.] 

Likewise,  if  we  combine  the  index  of  labor  costs  and  actual  percentages 
of  compression,  we  obtain  the  set  of  savings  in  labor  outlays  associated  with 
existing  labor  locations.  [Obviously  the  higher  (lower)  the  index  of  labor 
cost  and  the  percentage  of  compression,  the  greater  (smaller)  the  hkelihood 
of  deviation  to  a  labor  location,  ceteris  paribus.] 

To  measure  quantitatively  the  extent  to  which  different  industries  may  be 
deviated  to  labor  locations,  Weber  develops  the  concept  of  labor  coefficient. 
The  labor  coefficient  of  an  industry  is  defined  as  the  ratio  of  its  labor  cost 
per  ton  product  to  its  locational  weight,  or  labor  cost  per  locational  ton.  If 
only  deviations  over  significant  distances  are  considered  so  that  the  distorting 
effects  upon  isodapanes  of  any  particular  locational  figure  and  its  set  of  forces 
can  be  ignored,  then,  according  to  Weber,  the  higher  the  labor  coefficient  the 
more  likely  that  an  industry  will  be  labor  oriented,  given  a  fixed  transport 
rate  structure  proportional  to  weight  and  distance  and  after  due  allowance  is 
made  for  savings  from  replacement  deposits  which  tend  to  become  increasingly 
significant  with  increase  of  deviational  distance.  Weber's  labor  coefficient  is 
also  useful  in  establishing  priorities  for  different  types  of  industries  which 
might  be  induced  to  locate  at  a  cheap  labor  location.  Ceteris  paribus,  the 
higher  the  coefficient,  the  higher  the  economic  priority. 


142  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

If  we  consider  a  specific  labor  location  and  if  we  multiply  the  numerator 
of  the  labor  coefficient  for  an  industry  by  the  relevant  percentage  of  compres- 
sion and  the  denominator  by  the  transport  rate  and  distance  between  the  labor 
location  and  the  transport  optimal  point,  we  obtain  a  ratio  of  outlays — of  labor 
savings  per  locational  ton  to  additional  transport  expense  per  locational  ton. 
So  long  as  this  ratio  is  greater  than  unity  for  any  given  industrial  process 
and  environmental  situation,  the  labor  location  lies  within  the  critical  isoda- 
pane  and  attracts  the  industry  in  question.  It  pays  to  substitute  transport 
outlays  for  labor  outlays.  The  greater  the  ratio,  the  greater  the  savings 
achieved  in  shifting  to  a  labor  location. 

Compared  to  the  labor  coefficient  from  which  it  is  derived,  the  ratio  per 
locational  ton  of  labor  savings  to  additional  transport  outlays  has  the  virtue 
of  being  able  to  indicate  directly  whether  or  not  a  shift  to  a  labor  location  is 
feasible.  Further  it  can  yield  more  directly  answers  to  questions  like  these: 
By  how  much  must  labor  costs  be  compressed  to  attract  a  specific  industrial 
process  to  a  given  location,  ceteris  -paribus'!  By  how  much  must  the  transport 
rate  be  cut  to  allow  an  industrial  process  to  be  attracted  to  a  cheap  labor 
location,  ceteris  paribus  f  To  which  of  several  labor  locations  will  an  industrial 
process  be  attracted?  In  contrast,  the  labor  coefficient  has  the  major  advan- 
tage of  having  more  general  applicability.  It  indicates  relative  tendency  of 
various  industrial  processes  to  shift  to  labor  locations  and  is  generaUy  inde- 
pendent of  the  percentage  of  compression,  transport  rate,  or  distance  relations 
in  any  particular  situation.  (In  still  other  contexts,  another  ratio  might  be 
useful,  namely,  one  which  is  derived  through  multiplying  the  numerator  of 
the  labor  coefficient  by  a  relevant  percentage  of  compression  and  the  denomi- 
nator by  the  transport  rate.    This  ratio  is  independent  of  spatial  situation.) 


Chapter 


7 


Market  and  Supply 

Area  Analysis  and  Competitive 

Locational  Equilibrium 


1.     Market  Area  Analysis 

Hitherto  we  have  treated  the  firm  as  serving  for  the  most  part  a 
one-point  market.  We  now  relax  this  simplifying  postulate  and  con- 
sider the  market  as  an  area.  Further,  with  the  use  of  the  concept 
of  transport  inputs  it  is  easily  shown  how  production  analysis  for 
a  one-point  consumption  place  may  be  viewed  as  a  special  case  of 
production   analysis  for  a  market   area.i 

In  Chap.  2  we  have  briefly  sketched  Losch's  conception  of  the 

1  Incidentally,  for  a  long  time,  location  theorists  treated  separately  the  problems 
of  production  for  a  one-point  consumption  place  and  production  for  a  market 
area.  Launhardt,  who  presented  the  first  significant  treatment  of  industrial  loca- 
tion theory,  distinguished  between  the  partial  problem  of  determining  the  site 
of  production  within  or  at  the  corners  of  a  locational  polygon,  where  the  corners 
represented  raw  material  sources  and  a  one-point  consumption  place  ["Die 
Bestimmung  des  zweckmassigsten  Standortes  einer  gewerbhchen  Anlage,"  Zeit- 
schrift  des  Vereines  Deutscher  Ingenieure,  Bd.  26  (March  1882)],  and  the  partial 
problem  of  supplying  a  consuming  area  from  a  given  point  of  production  {Malhe- 
matische  Begrundung  der  Volkswirthschaftslehre,  Leipzig,  1885,  Part  III).  Al- 
though he  handled  both  problems  comprehensively  for  his  time,  he  made  no 
attempt  to  put  them  together.  Weber,  in  his  analysis,  treated  only  the  first  of 
these  problems.  Englander,  perhaps  the  first  to  recognize  that  these  two  prob- 
lems are  fundamentally  one  and  the  same  (in  his  caustic  criticism  of  Weber, 
"Kritisches  und  Positives  .  .  .,"  op.  cit.),  nevertheless  did  not  adequately  synthe- 
size them  in  this  and  his  other  works.  The  later  writings  of  Palander,  Hoover, 
and  Losch  are  much  more  satisfactoiy  in  this  respect. 

143 


144  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

space-economy  built  upon  the  elements  of  a  market  area,  a  net  of 
market  areas,  and  a  system  of  nets  of  market  areas.  We  nevertheless 
need  to  start  over  again  in  order  to  investigate  thoroughly  the  concept 
of  market  area  and  to  relate  it  to  the  theoretical  structure  thus  far 
developed. 2  In  Chaps.  10  and  11  we  shall  attempt  an  integration  of 
market  area  analysis  with  supply  area  analysis  to  be  discussed  in  the 
next  section  and  with  other  location  doctrine. 

Imagine  that  a  producer  secures  each  of  his  raw  materials  and  inputs 
at  the  site  of  his  factory  (hence  at  zero  transport  cost)  but  serves  a 
spatial  array  of  consumers.  If  consumers  come  to  one  and  only  one 
particular  site  and  make  their  purchases  there,  or  arrange  trans- 
portation from  that  site  on  the  item  purchased,  then  to  the  producer 
of  this  item,  that  site  is  the  market.  For  that  individual  producer, 
whom  for  the  present  we  take  to  be  an  isolated  monopolist  in  the 
Chamberlinian  sense, ^  our  spatial  equilibrium  analysis  need  not  be 
extended.  From  the  standpoint  of  society,  however,  when  consumers 
are  actively  responsible  for  the  transportation  of  the  item,  another 
set  of  transport  inputs  may  be  involved.  If  the  consumers  are  other 
producers  farther  along  in  the  stage  of  manufacture,  then  this  trans- 
portation appears  as  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  from  a  point 
source  in  these  producers'  calculations ;  and  again  no  extension  of  our 
analysis  is  required.  On  the  other  hand,  if  consumers  are  households, 
we  are  not  able  thus  far  to  account  for  the  transport  inputs  for 
which  they  are  actively  responsible. *     However,  once  we  make  the 

2  In  this  section  we  shall  cover  only  the  more  important  theoretical  aspects  of 
market  area  analysis.  For  supplementary  details,  graphic  illustrations,  and  more 
extensive  discussions  refer  among  others  to  W.  Launhardt,  Mathematische  Be- 
grundung  .  .  .  ,  op.  cit.;  F.  A.  Fetter,  "The  Economic  Law  of  Market  Areas," 
Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  38  (May  1924),  p.  525;  Tord  Palander, 
Beitrdge  zur  Standortstheone,  Uppsala:  Almqvist  and  Wiksells,  1935,  Chap.  IX; 
Edgar  M.  Hoover,  Jr.,  Location  Theory  and  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Industries, 
Cambridge,  Mass.,  Harvard  University  Press,  1937,  Chaps.  2,  3,  5,  and  6;  CD. 
and  W.  P.  Hyson,  "The  Economic  Law  of  Market  Areas,"  Quarterly  Journal  of 
Economics,  Vol.  LXIV  (May  1950),  pp.  319-27;  and  Melvin  L.  Greenhut,  "Inte- 
grating the  Leading  Theories  of  Plant  Location"  and  "The  Size  and  Shape  of 
the  Market  Area  of  a  Firm,"  Southern  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  18  (April  1952), 
pp.  526-38  and  Vol.  19  (July  1952),  pp.  37-50,  respectively. 

3  See  E.  Chamberlin,  The  Theory  of  Monopolistic  Competition,  Cambridge, 
Mass.,  1938,  p.  74;  and  "Monopolistic  Competition  Revisited,"  Economica,  No- 
vember 1951,  pp.  351-54. 

4  To  do  so  would  take  us  into  the  realms  of  sociology  and  social  psychology. 
For,  to  explain  the  spatial  distribution  of  household  consumers  around  focal 
points — for  example,  the  population  spread  around  any  given  metropolitan  core — 
requires  knowledge  of  the  process  by  which  tastes  are  molded  and,  in  particular, 
understanding  of  the  space  preferences  of  consumers.     Hiunan  ecology  promises 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  145 

assumption,  usually  considered  legitimate  for  economic  analysis,  that 
tastes  and  space  preferences  are  known,  and  thus  demand  schedules 
and  the  spatial  pattern  of  population  about  any  given  pattern  of 
focal  points  are  known,  we  necessarily  "explain"  the  total  quantity 
of  transport  inputs  for  which  household  consumers  are  actively 
responsible. 

Consider  situations,  where,  in  contrast,  the  producer  is  actively 
responsible  for  transporting  his  products  to  the  places  of  use,  where 
each  consumer  is  charged  a  price  equal  to  a  quoted  price  at  a  focal 
point  plus  transport  cost  to  his  place,  and  where  the  producer  arranges 
the  distribution  of  his  product  from  that  focal  point.  If  the  con- 
sumer is  an  industrial  producer,  he  has  in  effect  made  the  decision 
to  contract  for  the  transport  inputs  involved  in  delivery  from  the  focal 
point  to  the  place  of  use  by  having  chosen  to  locate  where  he  is  rather 
than  at  a  site  closer  to  the  focal  point.  He  incurs  the  expense  of 
these  transport  inputs  indirectly  by  paying  a  higher  delivered  price. 
From  society's  standpoint,  we  may  still  consider  the  transport  cost 
on  the  product  paid  by  the  first  producer  as  outlays  by  the  second 
producer  on  transport  inputs  required  to  obtain  one  of  his  raw 
materials.  Once  again  our  analysis  needs  no  extension.  If  the  con- 
sumer is  a  household,  and  we  take  its  tastes,  space  preference,  and 
thus  demand  schedules  as  given,  we  necessarily  "explain"  the  trans- 
port inputs  involved  in  the  delivery  of  the  product  from  the  focal 
point.  The  consumer's  willingness  to  pay  the  delivered  price  signifies 
his  willingness  to  incur  the  costs  of  these  transport  inputs.  When 
the  household  is  unwilling  to  incur  these  costs  and  when  the  industrial 
consumer  finds  it  expedient  to  avoid  transport  inputs  in  obtaining 
the  product  which  he  uses  as  a  raw  material,  the  market  for  the 
producer  of  this  product  reduces  to  a  point.  Viewed  in  this  narrow 
framework,  production  for  a  one-point  market  is  thus  a  special  case 
of  production  for  a  market  area,  continuous  or  discontinuous. 

It  is  fruitful  to  spell  out  these  general  statements,  particularly 
as  they  link  up  with  existing  market  area  analysis.  If  the  producer 
does  not  encounter  competition  from  other  producers  in  serving  con- 
sumers, to  all  of  whom  he  quotes  an  identical  factory  price,  his 
market  area  takes  the  familiar  shape  of  a  circle  where  consumers  of  like 
tastes  and  income  are  uniformly  scattered  over  a  plain  of  even 
topography  (provided  they  are  willing  to  incur  the  costs  of  transport 
inputs).  Unevenness  of  consumer  spread,  inequalities  in  effective 
purchasing  power  and  differences  of  tastes  among  consumers,  irregu- 

eventually  to  provide  such  an  understanding.  (See  Bogue,  op.  cit.;  McKenzie, 
op.  cit.;  and  A.  Hawley,  Human  Ecology,  New  York,  1950.) 


146  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

larities  in  geographic  feature,  economies  of  scale  in  transport,  and  a 
host  of  other  factors  distort  the  "natural"  circular  regularity.  How- 
ever, the  essential  condition  that  the  market  boundary  be  a  locus 
of  consumers  who  are  just  willing  to  pay  for  the  first  unit  of  product 
a  price  which  is  equal  to  the  factory  price  plus  transport  cost  to  the 
point  of  consumption  still  obtains.  ^ 

Introduction  of  a  competitor  producing  the  identical  commodity 
alters  the  condition  in  the  area  in  which  competition  is  in  force. 
Where  both  producers  set  the  same  factory  price,  effective  for  all 
consumers,  and  where  the  freight  rate  is  invariant  with  direction, 
being  a  function  of  weight  and  distance  only,  the  boundary  separating 
the  consumers  served  by  each  producer  is  the  perpendicular  bisector  of 
the  straight  line  joining  the  two  producers.  (For  example,  see  the 
boundary  line  ZV  of  Fig.  28  which  separates  the  markets  of  the 
two  producers  at  A  and  B.)  Only  this  perpendicular  bisector  yields 
a  locus  of  points  of  equal  delivered  price.  In  the  districts  where 
competition  is  absent,  the  previous  condition  for  the  determination  of 
the  boundary  line  for  each  producer  still  obtains. 

In  the  equally  familiar  case  where  one  producer  establishes 
identically  for  all  consumers  a  factory  price  lower  than  the  other,  the 
locus  of  points  of  equal  delivered  price  in  the  area  of  competition 
becomes  an  hyperbola.  (For  example,  see  the  boundary  line  which 
separates  the  market  areas  tributary  to  production  points  L  and  Mj 
in  Fig.  45  in  Chap.  11.)  In  the  more  unusual  circumstance  where 
both  producers  charge  one  and  the  same  factory  price  but  where  the 
product  of  one  producer  bears  a  higher  transport  rate  than  the  product 
of  the  other,  the  market  of  the  former  ultimately  becomes  enclosed 
by  the  market  of  the  latter  (provided,  of  course,  that  the  area  of 
effective  consumption  extends  far  enough  in  the  geographic  hinter- 
land of  the  former)  ;  the  market  of  the  latter  is  limited  in  its  outer 
extents  only  by  the  area  of  effective  consumption.  Finally,  where 
inequality  in  factory  prices  as  well  as  in  transport  rates  obtains,  the 
market  area  of  the  producer  upon  whose  product  the  higher  transport 
rate  applies  ultimately  becomes  contained  by  the  market  area  of  the 

5  Since  consumers  are  not  typically  distributed  so  that  one  is  at  every  con- 
ceivable point  on  a  plain,  the  market  boundary  must  necessarily  cut  through 
certain  stretches  of  the  plain  where  it  does  not  pass  through  possible  points  of 
consumption.  In  these  stretches  its  course  is  somewhat  indeterminate,  being 
restricted  only  by  the  condition  that  it  enclose  those  consumers  who  are  more 
than  willing  to  pay  for  the  first  unit  of  product  the  factory  price  plus  transport 
cost  and  that  it  exclude  those  consumers  who  are  unwilling  to  do  so.  Because  of 
differences  of  incomes  and  tastes  and  other  factors,  enclaves  of  "excluded"  con- 
sumers may  come  to  exist  within  a  producer's  general  market  territory. 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  147 

other  producer,  again  provided  that  the  area  of  effective  consumption 
extends  far  enough  in  the  geographic  hinterland  of  the  former.  ^ 

At  this  point  we  pause  to  consider  how  the  market  area  analysis  thus 
far  developed  can  be  formulated  in  a  substitution  framework.  It  has 
already  been  noted  that  the  market  area  of  the  firm  which  is  not  con- 
fronted by  competitors  assumes  a  circular  form  under  "uniformity" 
conditions  with  respect  to  terrain,  the  geographic  scatter,  income  and 
tastes  of  consumers,  and  other  factors.  Viewed  from  the  firm's  stand- 
point, for  any  given  size  of  output  it  is  always  profitable,  when  the  set 
of  consumers  it  initially  serves  does  not  approximate  a  circular  terri- 
tory, to  substitute  transport  inputs  in  one  direction  for  transport  inputs 
in  another  direction  and  to  continue  doing  so  until  an  approximation 
to  a  circular  market  area  is  attained.  The  substitution  is  effected 
simply  by  the  curtailment  of  sales  to  the  most  distant  consumers  and 
the  extension  of  sales  to  new,  less  distant  consumers  (transport  rates 
being  a  simple  function  of  weight  and  distance  and  invariant  with 
direction) .  Viewed  from  society's  standpoint,  any  given  size  of  output 
can  be  distributed  with  less  average  cost  to  consumers,  and  hence 
with  less  effort  devoted  to  transportation,  when  under  the  above  speci- 
fied situation  a  non-circular  market  territory  is  transformed  into  a 
circular  one  through  the  substitution  of  transport  inputs  in  one  direc- 
tion for  transport  inputs  in  another  direction.  Or  alternatively  (and 
again  under  our  simple  assumptions) ,  given  a  fixed  amount  of  labor 
and  resources  devoted  to  both  production  and  transportation,  the  path 
toward  maximum  social  output  and  consumption  of  goods  involves  the 
reshaping  of  a  non-circular  market  area  into  a  circular  one  through  the 
substitution  of  transport  inputs  in  one  direction  for  transport  inputs  in 
another  direction. 

The  introduction  of  a  competitor,  as  already  indicated,  establishes 
another  type  of  boundary  line,  a  locus  of  points  of  equal  delivered  price. 
A  boundary  consisting  of  any  other  set  of  connected  points  implies,  in 
our  simplified  model,  a  social  inefficiency.  If  such  a  boundary  exists, 
it  becomes  economic  for  certain  consumers  to  shift  their  buying  from 
one  producer  to  another.    In  effect  society  is  thereby  substituting  trans- 

6  Where  pi  and  P2  are  the  two  factory  prices  and  ri  and  ra  the  respective  freight 
rates  on  the  product,  the  competitive  boundary  is  defined  by  the  equation: 
Pi  +  nsi  =  P2  +  ^2S2  where  si  and  S2  are  the  respective  distances  from  the 
two  factory  locations  to  any  given  point  on  the  boundary  line.  This  equation  can 
be  expressed  in  the  form:  si  —  hs2  =  ±k,  where  h  =  r2/ri;  +k  =  (p2  —  Pi) /ri 
when  (p2  —  Pi) / n '>  0 ;  and  —k=  (p2  —  Pi)/ri  when  (p2  —  Px)lr\  <  0.  This 
equation  describes  a  family  of  indifference  curves  which  the  Hysons  have  called 
hypercircles  and  which  comprise  half  the  family  of  Descartes'  ovals.  See  C.  D. 
and  W.  P.  Hyson,  op.  cit. 


148  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

port  inputs  on  the  product  of  one  producer  for  transport  inputs  on  the 
product  of  the  second  producer  and  should  continue  to  do  so  until  a 
boundary  comprising  points  of  equal  delivered  price  is  attained.  At 
the  same  time  society  is  also  substituting  production  outlays  by  one 
producer  for  production  outlays  by  the  second  producer. 

Where  conditions  of  constant  cost  prevail,  the  marginal  rate  of  sub- 
stitution of  production  outlays  by  one  producer  for  production  outlays 
by  the  second  producer  is  also  a  constant.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
transfer  of  consumers  from  one  producer's  market  to  that  of  the  second, 
as  the  dividing  boundary  line  is  gradually  shifted,  entails  a  changing 
marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  transport  inputs  of  the  two  pro- 
ducers in  serving  consumers  on  the  common  boundary  line.'''  It  is 
through  this  changing  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  transport 
inputs  of  the  two  producers  that  we  reach  the  partial  equilibrium  situa- 
tion defined  by  a  locus  of  points  where  the  difference  in  transport 
outlays  of  the  two  producers  equals  the  difference  in  their  production 
outlays.  When  conditions  of  constant  cost  do  not  prevail,  it  is  through 
the  changing  marginal  rates  of  substitution  both  between  transport 
inputs  and  between  production  outlays  that  we  attain  the  desired 
locus  of  points. 

Hoover  has  aptly  portrayed  the  competitive  situation  for  two  pro- 
ducers with  the  use  of  graphs.^  In  Fig.  27  let  a  producer  be  located  at 
A.  Consumers  are  posited  to  be  arrayed  along  line  AB.  If  the  pro- 
ducer at  A  were  to  supply  the  needs  of  consumers  at  A  only,  his  mar- 
ginal costs  would  be  AK.  However,  other  consumers  not  at  A  may  wish 
to  purchase  from  the  producer  at  A.  If  A's  market  area  extends  as  far  as 
L,  his  marginal  costs,  owing  to  economies  of  scale,  fall  to  AJ,  assuming 
that  the  factory  price  he  charges  is  equal  to  marginal  costs. ^  Adding 
transport  cost  to  the  consumers  along  the  stretch  AL  yields  a  delivered 
price  line  JG  whose  vertical  height  at  any  point  is  the  delivered  price 
to  the  corresponding  consumer  along  stretch  AL.  JG  is  also  a  transport 
gradient  line  since  it  indicates  how  transport  cost  on  a  unit  of  product 
rises  as  distance  from  A  increases.  i<> 

"^  It  is  implicitly  assumed  that  each  producer  charges  the  identical  factory  price 
to  all  consumers  and  that  his  factory  price  equals  his  unit  production  cost. 

8  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  II,  particularly  Fig.  7. 

9  If  the  factory  price  is  equal  to  average  unit  cost,  the  factory  price  would  be 
higher,  sales  smaller,  and  marginal  costs  higher;  also,  the  market  area  would  be 
more  Umited  if  the  consumer  at  L  were  just  willing  to  pay  a  delivered  price  equal 
to  AH{=  GL). 

10  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  pp.  8-11.  Where  irregularities  in  rate  structure  exist,  these 
will  be  reflected  in  the  transport  gradient  line. 

The  transport  gradient  line  of  Fig.  27  is  constructed  to  portray  a  rate  structure 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS 


149 


If  A's  market  area  is  now  enlarged  to  reach  as  far  as  M,  sales  under 
marginal  cost  pricing  correspond  to  that  output  at  which  marginal  costs 
fall  to  AE.  At  this  output  marginal  costs  are  at  a  minimum,  and  the 
derived  delivered  price  (transport  gradient)  line  is  accordingly  at  its 
lowest  level  (where  factory  price  is  taken  to  equal  marginal  costs). ^ 


/s 


\ 

f 

/ 

^v                              / 
u 

^              ^^"       *' 

L      M  NX     R 

Fig.  27.     Margin  lines:  two  competitors. 


B 


For  all  other  outputs,  marginal  costs  (factory  price)  are  higher  and 
the  delivered  price  line  higher.  For  example,  if  A's  market  is  enlarged 
to  AN ^  marginal  costs  rise  to  AD,  and  the  transport  gradient  line  starts 
from  point  D  and  necessarily  parallels  EF  at  a  higher  level.  The 
delivered  price  to  the  consumer  at  A^  is  AD  plus  transport  cost,  or 
in  toto  CN. 

If  points  G,  F,  and  C  are  connected  with  other  points,  each  of  which 
by  its  vertical  height  represents  for  a  given  size  market  area  the  deliv- 
ered price  to  the  consumer  on  the  boundary  line,  the  curve  KGFCS  is 

proportional  to  weight  and  distance.  If  the  rate  structure  is  graduated  and  less 
than  proportional  to  distance,  the  transport  gradient  from  J  would  rise  continu- 
ously but  curve  downward. 

11  Obviously,  under  a  different  pricing  system,  sales  would  be  of  a  different  mag- 
nitude, and  marginal  costs  would  not  be  at  a  minimum  when  the  edge  of  the 
producer's  market  is  at  M. 


150  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

obtained;  Hoover  has  designated  this  a  margin  line.  It  indicates  how 
delivered  price  at  the  edge  of  the  market  varies  with  the  geographic 
extent  of  the  market.  It  is  evident  that  the  margin  line  changes  in 
form  as  the  basis  of  pricing  at  the  factory  changes.  ^^ 

It  is  fruitful  to  point  out  that,  in  accordance  with  his  market  area 
theory,  Losch  would  maintain  that  the  stretch  of  the  margin  line  from 
K  through  G,  F,  and  C  to  P  corresponds  to  his  natural  market  area 
when  competition  is  absent  and  when  the  margin  line  is  based  upon 
factory  prices  which  are  equated  to  average  unit  costs. i^  Within  this 
stretch,  the  economies  of  scale  (including  the  advantages  and  disad- 
vantages of  specialization)  outweigh  the  diseconomy  of  transport  cost. 
In  contrast,  beyond  point  P,  the  economies  of  scale  (which  owing  to 
rising  marginal  cost  are  less  than  KQ)  fail  to  match  transport  costs 
(which  exceed  KQ).  Consumers  beyond  R  either  produce  for  them- 
selves or  purchase  from  another  producer,  i^ 

We  may  now  introduce  a  second  producer  situated  at  B.  If  he  con- 
fronts the  same  set  of  conditions  as  A — similar  cost  curves,  types  and 
spatial  spread  of  consumers,  transport  rates — and  if  he,  too,  pursues 
an  average  cost  pricing  system  (as  is  postulated  for  A  in  the  preceding 
paragraph),  his  margin  line  for  serving  consumers  along  the  stretch 
AB  will  be  identical  to  ^'s.    His  margin  line  (TUV)  intersects  A's  at 

12  Conceivably,  the  producer's  marginal  cost  and  average  cost  curves  could  be 
superimposed  upon  Fig.  27  if  the  pricing  system  and  consumer  demand  curves 
were  stipulated  beforehand.  Points  on  the  horizontal  axis  would  not  only  indicate 
distance  from  A  but  also  quantity  of  output  which  would  be  purchased  were  the 
edge  of  the  market  at  each  point. 

It  is  clear  that  if  the  pricing  sj^stem  is  changed,  the  quantity  purchased  in  each 
size  of  market  area  would  also  change;  and  correspondingly  the  shape  and  form 
of  any  marginal  or  average  cost  curve  which  might  be  superimposed  on  Fig.  27 
would  change.  This  would  be  so  even  though,  in  orthodox  fashion,  such  a  mar- 
ginal or  average  cost  curve  is  taken  to  be  independent  of  price  and  a  function  of 
output  only.  Likewise,  the  margin  line  would  shift  since,  for  each  size  of  market 
area,  total  output  and  hence  marginal  or  average  cost  and  the  transport  gradient 
starting  point  along  the  vertical  axis  would  change  (provided,  of  course,  we  retain 
the  postulate  that  factory  price  is  in  some  way  related  to  costs). 

If  the  margin  Hne  of  Fig.  27  were  based  on  a  factory  price  equal  to  average 
cost  rather  than  marginal  cost,  it  would  lie  above  the  line  KGFCS  in  Fig.  27  in 
the  initial  stretch  and  would  remain  above  it  so  long  as  marginal  costs  were  below 
average  costs.  It  would  intersect  this  line  were  the  edge  of  the  market  extended 
sufficiently  to  call  forth  an  output  at  which  marginal  cost  equals  average  cost.  At 
this  output  the  extent  of  the  market  would  be  identical  under  both  a  marginal  cost 
and  average  cost  pricing  system. 

13  Though  the  margin  line  of  Fig.  27  was  constructed  upon  a  marginal  cost 
pricing  system,  we  assume  here  and  in  the  following  discussion  that  it  was  con- 
structed upon  an  average  cost  pricing  system. 

14  Losch,  op.  cit.,  pp.  71-74. 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  151 

W,  which  corresponds  to  point  X  on  the  straight  line  ABA^  It  may 
then  be  said  that  at  X  the  delivered  prices  from  the  two  producers  are 
identical.  Consumers  to  the  left  of  X  purchase  from  A  because  they 
bear  less  transport  cost  in  the  delivery  of  the  product  from  A  than 
from  B.  For  a  similar  reason  consumers  to  the  right  of  X  purchase 
from  B. 

Had  B  been  located  farther  to  the  right  so  that  the  two  margin  lines 
would  have  intersected  at  a  point  to  the  right  of  P  (rather  than  to  the 
left),  A  and  B  would  be  non-competitive. i^  As  already  indicated, 
beyond  P  consumers  in  the  Losch  scheme  find  it  preferable  to  produce 
for  themselves  at  a  cost  of  AK  rather  than  to  purchase  from  A  at  a 
delivered  price  exceeding  AK.  Likewise,  if  any  of  these  consumers 
are  at  the  same  time  to  the  left  of  the  new  position  of  point  V,  they 
find  it  preferable  to  produce  for  themselves  rather  than  to  purchase 
from  B.  Hence,  we  would  have  had  a  situation  (temporary  in  the 
Loschian  scheme)  where  each  producer  was  a  monopolist  within  his  own 
natural  market  area  and  where  each  unserved  consumer  lying  between 
these  two  market  areas  produced  for  his  own  needs,  i'' 

We  return  to  the  situation  depicted  by  Fig.  27  and  to  our  substitution 
framework.  As  soon  as  B  becomes  effective  as  a  producer,  consumers 
along  XR  shift  their  purchasing  from  A  to  B.  In  doing  so,  they  are 
substituting  transport  inputs  on  the  product  from  B  for  transport  inputs 
on  the  product  from  A.  They  are  also  substituting  production  outlays 
by  B  for  production  outlays  by  A.  In  this  case,  because  of  the  sym- 
metry assumptions,  they  are  substituting  lower  production  outlays 
by  B  for  higher  production  outlays  by  A.  In  the  more  general  situa- 
tion, the  marginal  production  outlays  by  B  might  be  either  smaller  or 
greater  than  those  by  A.  However,  if  they  are  greater,  the  transport 
inputs  on  product  from  A  must  exceed  those  on  product  from  B  to 
these  consumers  by  a  still  greater  amount  if  these  consumers  are  to 
shift  their  purchasing  allegiance. 

In  this  analysis  the  transition  from  a  market  area  which  is  a  single 
straight  line  (as  when  in  Losch's  scheme  the  y  co-ordinate  of  every 
consumer's  position  takes  the  value  of  zero)  to  one  which  comprises 
any  number  of  straight  lines  radiating  in  all  directions  from  each  of 
any  set  of  focal  points  (where  the  x  and  y  co-ordinates  of  consumers 
may  take  all  values)  is  easily  effected.    Imagine  A  and  B  as  two  focal 

15  Given  our  assumptions,  X  is  necessarily  the  mid-point  of  AB. 

16  Diagrammatically,  V  would  be  to  the  left  of  P  (rather  than  to  the  right  of  P 
as  in  Fig.  27)  and  X  would  be  to  the  left  of  R  (rather  than  to  the  right  of  R  in 
Fig.  27). 

1''^  In  Fig.  27,  AR  would  be  A's  market  area;  and  beyond  R  to  the  edge  of  B's 
market  area,  consumers  would  be  self-sufficient. 


152 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


points  lying  on  the  a;-axis.  Radiating  from  each  is  a  straight  line  at 
an  angle  a  (less  than  90°)  from  A  and  at  an  angle  180°  —  a  from  B. 
See  Fig.  28.  Again  let  Losch's  uniformity  assumptions  be  adopted.  If 
as  a  logical  consequence  A  and  B  serve  the  same  number  and  kinds  of 
consumers  in  their  respective  market  areas  except  for  consumers  along 


Fig.  28.    The  division  of  a  spatial  market:  two  competitors. 


lines  AW  and  BW,  it  also  follows  that  B  serves  all  the  consumers 
along  line  BW  and  that  A  serves  all  the  consumers  along  line  AW, 
where  AW  =  BW.  For,  if  A  were  to  serve  a  consumer  on  line  BW  (but 
not  at  W) ,  A's  delivery  price  to  this  consumer  would  be  greater  than 
J5's.is  Society  would  deem  it  desirable  for  this  consumer  to  shift  his 
allegiance  from  A  to  B,  and  thereby  for  him  to  substitute  transport 
inputs  on  the  product  from  B  for  transport  inputs  on  the  product  from 
A  and  marginal  production  outlays  at  B  for  marginal  production 
outlays  at  A,  even  though  the  latter  might  be  somewhat  smaller. 

IS  Except  perhaps  in  rare  instances  where  the  marginal  cost  curve  behaves  in 
unusual  fashion. 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  153 

For  all  values  of  a  defined  by  the  competitive  stretch  ZV  (see  Fig. 
28)  the  same  can  be  demonstrated.  In  short,  the  competitive  boundary 
line  between  A  and  B  is,  as  already  indicated  earlier  in  this  chapter, 
a  perpendicular  bisector  of  the  straight  line  connecting  A  and  B  and  is 
a  locus  of  points  equidistant  from  A  and  B.'^^  If  we  follow  Losch 
and  permit  complete  freedom  of  entry  and  exit  for  many  producers  and 
impose  the  restraint  that  all  consumers  be  served  by  at  least  one 
producer,  we  obtain  boundary  lines  which  must  divide  large  regions 
into  identical  and  regularly  shaped  market  areas  in  order  to  be  con- 
sistent with  our  uniformity  assumptions.  Only  equilateral  triangles, 
squares,  and  regular  hexagons  satisfy  these  requirements.  And  Losch 
has  demonstrated  algebraically  that  the  division  of  any  large  region 
into  regular  hexagonal  market  areas  is  more  efficient  than  a  division 
into  either  equilateral  triangular  or  square  market  areas. ^o  Put  in 
another  way,  it  is  efficient  for  society  to  substitute  among  various 
sets  of  transport  inputs  and  marginal  production  outlays  in  order  to 
proceed  to  a  pattern  of  regular  hexagons  from  any  other  pattern  of 
regularly  or  irregularly  shaped  market  areas. 21 

Hence  the  Losch  scheme  of  a  net  of  regularly  shaped  hexagons  is  a 
logical  outgrowth  of  the  simple  Fetter-Launhardt  approach  when  ad- 
ditional assumptions  and  restraints  are  introduced.  As  a  consequence, 
too,  it  can  be  described  in  terms  of  simple  substitution  relations. 

When  it  is  additionally  assumed  that  the  production,  sales,  and 
price  of  any  commodity  are  independent  of  the  production,  sales, 
and  price  of  any  other,  and  when  it  is  recognized  that  differences 
among  commodities  in  applicable  transport  rates  and  economies  of 
scale  will  cause  different  sizes  of  regular  hexagons  to  characterize  the 
market  areas  of  various  commodities,  a  system  of  nets  of  hexagonal 
market  areas  similar  to  Losch's  becomes  a  logical  derivation.  (For 
example,  see  Fig.  51  in  Chap.  11.)  However,  it  does  not  seem  fruitful 
for  one  to  pursue  analysis  on  a  multicommodity  basis  at  this  level 
of  extreme  simplification.  He  would  need  to  relax  the  assumption 
of  the  independence  of  the  production,  sales,  and  prices  of  the  several 
commodities.  In  addition  to  economies  of  scale  he  would  need  to 
recognize  other  economies  of  agglomeration,  whether  they  be  localiza- 
tion, urbanization,  or  other  forms  of  juxtaposition  economies.  He  would 
need  to  eliminate  among  others  the  inconsistency  between  the  set 
of  uniformity  assumptions,  particularly  with  reference  to  population 

19  For  additional  details  see  Hoover,  Location  Theory  .  .  .  ,  o-p.  cit.,  Chaps.  2 
and  3. 

20  Losch,  op.  cit.,  pp.  76-78. 

21  For  a  more  rigorous  demonstration,  see  Chap.  10,  Sect.  4. 


154  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

distribution,  and  the  hierarchical  pattern  of  concentrations  of  economic 
activities  which  results  from  the  superimposition  upon  one  another 
of  nets  of  hexagonal  market  areas.  This  is  especially  so  when  they 
are  ordered  around  a  common  core  as  Losch  is  inclined  to  do.  If  one 
were  to  overcome  these  several  obstacles,  the  Losch  multicommodity 
framework  embodied  in  a  system  of  nets  of  market  areas  would  be 
a  logical  point  of  departure  for  the  pursuit  of  regional  analysis.  Since 
the  assumptions  of  the  Losch  framework  have  most  relevance  to  service 
activities  (where  the  pull  of  raw  materials  tends  to  be  minor)  and 
least  relevance  to  basic  industry  oriented  wholly  or  partially  to 
localized  raw  materials,  the  Losch  approach  is  most  pertinent  for  the 
study  of  highly  urbanized  regions  in  which  service  activities  dominate 
the  economic  structure. 

2.     Supply  (Purchasing)   Area  Analysis 2 2 

The  previous  section  posited  that  raw  materials  were  essentially 
ubiquitous,  available  at  every  potential  factory  site  at  the  same  cost. 
As  already  intimated,  this  assumption  cannot  be  tolerated  for  the 
case  of  wholly  or  partially  resource-oriented  industry.  We  must  con- 
sider the  theoretical  significance  of  quantitative  and  qualitative  in- 
equalities in  the  spatial  distribution  of  raw  material  deposits. 

It  is  clear  that  when  there  are  many  scattered  factories  (manu- 
facturers) to  be  served  by  relatively  few  sources  of  a  raw  material, 
the  analysis  of  the  preceding  section  applies.  Each  of  the  many 
factories  (manufacturers)  can  be  viewed  as  a  consumer  of  the  raw 
material,  and  each  of  the  raw  material  sources  as  a  production  point. 
The  problem  is  to  define  boundary  lines  which  delineate  the  market 
area  composed  of  industrial  consumers  to  be  served  by  each  pro- 
ducing raw  material  source,  where  different  extraction  or  production 
costs  may  obtain  at  the  several  raw  material  sources. 2  3  For  example, 
in  Fig.  46  of  Chap.  11  assumed  conditions  lead  to  an  hyperbolic 
boundary  line  dividing  the  market  areas  of  M^  and  M^',  two  sources 
of  a  first  raw  material,  and  to  a  straight  line  boundary  line  separating 
the  market  areas  of  M2  and  ilf  2';  'two  sources  of  a  second  raw  material. 

22  The  term  supply  area  or  purchasing  area  is  used  here  to  indicate  the  geo- 
graphic area  from  which  a  raw  material  is  furnished  to  a  producer.  It  normally 
consists  of  many  sites  which  produce  the  raw  material.  It  does  not  refer  to  the 
geographic  area  of  consumers  whose  purchases  of  a  given  commodity  are  sup- 
plied by  a  specified  factory.  This  latter  area  has  already  been  designated  a 
market  area. 

23  This  is  the  case  for  which  Hoover  initially  develops  his  margin  line  concept. 
Points  A  and  B  of  Fig.  27  are  sites  of  an  extractive  activity.  Line  AB  represents 
a  locus  of  possible  consumers,  industrial  or  household.   (Hoover,  op.  cit.,  pp.  11-16.) 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  155 

The  case  is  different  when  each  industrial  consumer  must  procure 
his  raw  material  requirements  from  many  sources.  Here,  one  may 
assert,  we  have  market  area  analysis  in  reverse.  And  as  with  market 
areas,  analysis  of  supply  areas  is  facilitated  when  we  proceed  from 
the  simple  to  the  more  complex  situations. 

Imagine  an  industrial  consumer  who  does  not  confront  competition 
in  procuring  his  raw  material  from  many  potential  sources  of  supply. 
If  these  sources  are  uniformly  scattered  in  a  plain,  if  each  can  yield 
the  raw  material  at  the  same  constant  unit  cost,  and  if  no  single  source 
can  furnish  the  full  amount  of  the  raw  material  demanded  at  a  price 
which  is  equal  to  unit  cost,  the  industrial  consumer's  supply  area  will 
tend  to  be  circular. ^  4  Since  the  delivered  price  of  the  marginal  unit  of 
raw  material  procured  rises  as  the  radius  of  the  supply  area  increases, 
the  supply  area  is  limited  by  the  condition  that  the  delivered  price 
be  consistent  from  a  profit  standpoint  with  the  price  at  which  the 
marginal  unit  of  output  can  be  marketed. ^  5 

Even  in  the  more  realistic  case  where  increasing  costs  are  encountered 
in  supplying  the  raw  material,  the  industrial  consumer's  supply  area 
tend-s  to  be  circular.  The  delivered  price  to  the  industrial  consumer 
of  the  marginal  unit  from  each  source  of  raw  material  supply  utilized 
will  be  the  same.  The  difference  in  marginal  costs  for  any  two 
sources  will  equal  the  difference  in  the  unit  transport  costs  borne 
by  these  two  sources.  And,  consequently,  intensity  in  the  utilization 
of  any  source  of  raw  material  will  fall  off  with  increasing  distance 
from  the  point  of  industrial  consumption.  These  latter  conditions 
are  also  fulfilled  when  the  industrial  consumer  can  be  served  by  only 
a  relatively  few  sources. ^ 6     Needless  to  say,  if  these  conditions  are 

24  The  supply  area  reduces  to  a  point  when  each  source  can  furnish  the  full 
amount  of  raw  material  demanded. 

25  The  industrial  consumer  procures  the  maximum  possible  quantity  of  raw 
material  from  any  given  source  before  purchasing  from  another,  more  distant 
source.  Hence,  each  source  lying  within  the  circular  supply  area  tends  to  be  fully 
exploited  and  to  generate  locational  rent. 

26  When  there  are  only  a  relatively  few  sources  each  of  which  operates  under 
different  cost  conditions,  we  can  graphically  depict  the  situation  with  a  modified 
Hoover-type  diagram.  In  Fig.  29  point  T  is  a  site  of  industrial  consumption. 
Points  A,  B,  and  C  are  raw  material  sources  which  need  not  be  along  a  straight 
line  from  T  but  which  are,  respectively,  AT,  BT,  and  CT  distance  from  T.  At 
raw  material  source  A,  curve  aa  is  a  traditional  supply  curve  representing  the  dif- 
ferent quantities  of  the  raw  material  which  would  be  forthcoming  at  A  at  different 
net  prices,  where  net  price  is  measured  along  a  vertical  hne  passing  through  A 
parallel  to  TL  and  where  quantity  is  measured  along  AT.  At  raw  material  source 
B,  the  corresponding  supply  curve  is  bb,  where  net  pi'ice  is  measured  along  a  ver- 
tical line  passing  through  B  parallel  to  TL  and  where  quantity  is  measured  along 
line  BT.    At  raw  material  source  C,  the  corresponding  supply  curve  is  cc. 


156 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


Since  transport  costs  are  incurred  in  moving  the  raw  material  to  point  T,  the 
price  at  T  necessary  to  ehcit  the  production  of  any  quantity  of  raw  material  at 
A,  B,  or  C  must  exceed  the  corresponding  price  at  A,  B,  or  C  by  an  amount  equal 
to  the  cost  of  shipping  a  unit  from  A,  B,  or  C.  In  the  above  figure  the  dash-dot 
transport  gradient  lines  are  constructed  to  indicate  transport  costs  on  a  unit  of 
raw  material  from  sources  A,  B,  and  C  to  T.  Hence,  to  the  industrial  consumer 
at  T,  the  supply  curve  aa  appears  as  a' a';  the  price  at  a' a'  associated  with  any 
given  quantity  of  raw  material  exceeds  the  corresponding  price  at  aa  by  an  amount 
equal  to  transport  costs  which  are  represented  by  the  vertical  rise  in  the  corre- 


A  B  C  T 

Fig.  29.    The  division  of  a  market  among  several  supply  points. 


sponding  dash-dot  transport  gradient  line.  Likewise,  to  the  industrial  consumer 
at  T,  bb  appears  as  b'b'  and  cc  as  c'c'.  Since  for  any  price  established  at  T  the 
several  quantities  available  from  the  three  raw  material  sources  are  additive,  we 
obtain  at  T  the  aggregate  supply  curve  b'def.  If  the  industrial  consumer's  derived 
demand  curve  for  the  raw  material  is  DD,  the  equilibrium  price  and  aggregate 
quantity  are  TS  and  SR,  respectively.  A,  B,  and  C  furnish  respectively  SE,  SF, 
and  SG  quantities  of  the  raw  material  {SR  =  SE  +  SF  +  SG). 

With  this  diagram  it  can  be  easily  demonstrated  how  shifts  of  demand,  different 
transport  rates,  increases  and  decreases  in  transport  tariffs,  and  changes  in  other 
elements  affect  the  quantities  produced  at,  and  commodity  flows  stemming  from, 
each  raw  material  source. 

This  type  of  diagram  can  also  be  employed  when  one  raw  material  source  or 
producer,  say  at  T,  serves  several  industrial  or  household  consumers,  say  Sit  A,  B, 
and  C.  At  A,  B,  and  C  one  constructs  the  respective  demand  cui-ves  for  the  raw 
material  or  commodity  produced  at  T.  Each  of  these  demand  curves  can  be 
transformed  into  an  effective  demand  curve  at  T  through  depressing  its  vertical 
level  by  an  amount  equivalent  to  the  cost  of  shipping  the  raw  material  or  com- 
modity from  T  to  the  corresponding  point  of  consumption.  In  this  case,  the 
dash-dot  transport  gradient  lines  are  downward  sloping.     At  point  T  one  can 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  157 

not  met  (or  if  circularity  of  supply  area  is  not  realized  in  a  con- 
tinuous potential  supply  area),^^  both  society  and  the  industrial  con- 
sumer will  find  it  desirable  to  substitute  among  the  various  transport 
inputs  and  among  the  various  marginal  production  outlays  associated 
with  the  several  or  many  sources  until  these  conditions  are  fulfilled 
(or  circularity  attained). 

Where  the  industrial  consumer  confronts  competition  from  other 
industrial  consumers  in  purchasing  his  raw  materials,  the  boundary 
lines  separating  the  supply  areas  of  the  several  industrial  consumers 
tend  to  be  straight  lines,  given  the  Losch  type  of  uniformity  assump- 
tions. In  contrast,  when  transport  rates  on  raw  material  are  differen- 
tiated according  to  the  point  of  termination,  or  when  prices  paid 
at  these  points  of  termination  by  the  several  industrial  producers 
differ,  or  both,  boundary  lines  take  the  general  form  of  hypercircles, 
which  in  special  instances  degenerate  into  circles,  hyperbolas,  and,  as 
already  discussed,  straight  lines. ^  8 

If  these  types  of  boundary  lines  do  not  obtain  in  the  situations 
alluded  to,  once  again  it  becomes  economically  feasible  for  society 
to  shift  raw  material  sources  from  the  supply  hinterland  of  one  in- 
dustrial consumer  to  the  supply  hinterland  of  another,  and  thereby 
to  substitute  among  the  relevant  transport  inputs  and  among  the 
relevant  marginal  production  outlays.  It  is  not  necessary  to  develop 
this  point  in  detail  and  with  the  use  of  figures.  The  reasoning  and 
graphic  analysis  of  the  preceding  section,  appropriately  refashioned, 
apply  here. 


construct  an  aggregate  demand  curve  by  adding  together  horizontalwise  the  several 
reduced  demand  curves.  One  can  also  construct  a  supply  curve  and  proceed  in 
traditional  fashion  to  determine  the  equilibrium  price  and  quantity  and  the 
apportionment  of  the  total  equilibrium  quantity  among  the  several  consumers. 
Again,  one  can  easily  demonstrate  how  a  shift  of  the  supply  curve,  different 
transport  rates,  and  changes  in  tariff  structure  can  affect  the  realized  pattern  of 
consumption  and  commodity  flows  from  T. 

In  the  situation  where  both  consumers  and  producers  are  at  different  distances 
from  a  point  T  to  which  all  output  is  transported  for  sale  and  from  which  deUv- 
eries  to  consumers  are  made,  we  can  construct  both  the  aggregate  demand  curve 
and  the  aggregate  supply  curve  which  obtain  at  T.  Proceeding  as  above,  we  can 
determine  market  price  at  T,  net  price  to  each  producer,  delivered  price  to  each 
consumer,  the  distribution  of  output  among  consumers,  the  allocation  of  sales 
among  producers,  and  commodity  flows  to  and  from  T. 

2'^  Where  a  continuous  potential  supply  area  encompasses  subsections  in  which 
extraction  costs  differ,  the  circularity  restriction  must  be  relaxed.  Also,  where 
different  transport  rates  apply  in  different  directions,  circularity  must  be  expressed 
in  terms  of  economic  distance  and  not  physical  distance. 

28  Hyson,  op.  cit. 


158  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

In  a  pure  abstract  sense  one  could  even  proceed  to  the  analysis  of 
systems  of  supply  areas  in  a  way  analogous  to  the  manner  in  which 
Losch  molds  systems  of  market  areas.  But  in  reality,  physical 
space  restrictions  essentially  preclude  this.  It  is  possible  to  associate 
with  any  particular  point  a  consumer  who  purchases  a  number  of 
products  and  accordingly  is  served  by  a  number  of  producers.  How- 
ever, for  the  most  part  it  is  not  physically  possible  to  associate  with 
any  particular  point  the  production  of  more  than  one  raw  material 
or  type  of  raw  material  mix.  This  fact  raises  the  vital  problem 
of  competition  in  the  use  of  land  and  logically  leads  to  the  Thiinen 
type  of  agricultural  location  theory  and  to  land  rent  analysis,  which 
will  be  discussed  later.  Furthermore,  many  raw  materials  such  as 
coal  and  bauxite  are  highly  localized.  In  these  cases  the  Weberian 
framework,  as  already  discussed  in  Chap.  5  and  as  extended  in  later 
chapters,  is  particularly  applicable  rather  than  a  Loschian  system  of 


3.     Some  Remarks  on  Spatial  Pricing  Systems  and 
Competitive  Locational  Equilibrium 

Hitherto  we  have  avoided  discussion  of  spatial  pricing  systems  and 
competition.  For  the  most  part  we  have  assumed  that  either  (1) 
the  firm  establishes  a  price  at  the  factory  on  the  basis  of  cost  or 
some  other  objectively  given  consideration;  or  (2)  the  firm  has  a 
negligible  influence  upon  a  ruling  market  price  and  accepts  it  as  a 
datum.  This  latter  situation  obtains  where  a  small  firm  and  a  large 
number  of  competitors  are  concentrated  at  one  point,  which  is  mostly 
a  theoretical  possibility,  or  where  competitors'  markets  are  concen- 
trated at  a  point,  as  is  the  case  with  groups  of  farmers.  In  any  case, 
our  firm  has  not  been  concerned  with  the  reactions  of  competitors. 

Losch  has  demonstrated  that  for  the  more  usual  case  in  the  space- 
economy  of  reality  the  above  assumptions  are  invalid.  Even  in  the 
pure  situation,  where  there  are  many  independent  producers  with 
complete  freedom  of  entry  and  exit,  with  complete  knowledge  on 
technology  and  markets,  and  with  equal  access  to  inputs,  each 
firm  has  at  least  from  the  standpoint  of  classical  economics  a  limited 
control  over  the  market  price  it  realizes.  Because  of  the  spatial 
spread  of  consumers  and  producers  characteristic  of  reality,  the 
demand  curve  for  the  individual  firm's  product,  save  for  exceptional 
instances,  is  not  a  horizontal  line  of  infinite  elasticity  at  the  price  de- 
termined by  the  intersection  of  the  demand  and  supply  curves  for 
the  industry,  as  it  is  under  the  traditional  pure  competition.  Rather, 
the  friction  of  distance  imparts  to  each  producer  a  limited  monopolistic 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  159 

position  with  regard  to  consumers  closer  to  him  transportation-wise 
than  to  other  producers.  The  demand  curve  for  the  firm's  product, 
as  Losch  has  neatly  portrayed, ^ 9  has  a  negative  slope.  We  should 
therefore  pursue  locational  analysis  on  the  second  of  the  four  levels 
discussed  in  the  early  part  of  Chap.  5. 

If  reactions  by  competitors  can  be  ignored,  we  may  view  the  firm 
as  weighing,  for  each  possible  location,  the  net  revenue  potentials 
from  different  possible  sets  of  prices  and  outputs  on  the  one  hand  and 
the  related  sets  of  outlays  on  transport  and  other  inputs  on  the  other. 
For  each  possible  location  the  firm  selects  that  price  (or  an  array  of 
prices  in  the  case  of  price  discrimination)  which,  in  view  of  its  esti- 
mate of  the  aggregate  demand  curve  for  its  product  (or  of  each  in- 
dividual consumer's  demand  curve),  yields  maximum  net  revenue. 
Since  the  firm  is  in  a  position  to  control  prices  at  least  to  a  limited 
extent  and  does  tend  to  associate  different  prices  with  different  outputs, 
its  relevant  price-ratio  and  iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines  are  no  longer 
straight  as  in  Fig.  24  of  Chap.  5  and  Fig.  26  of  Chap.  6.  Rather 
they  become  convex  and  concave  curves  or  sets  of  points. ^o  None- 
theless, the  firm's  calculations  can  be  set  forth  and  expressed  in  terms 
of  equilibrium  conditions. 

Having  determined  for  each  possible  location  the  maximum  net 
revenue,  the  firm  selects  among  locations.  In  choosing  one  rather 
than  another,  the  firm  substitutes  among  potential  revenues,  outlays, 
and  transport  inputs.  The  conditions  of  locational  equilibrium,  which 
are  satisfied  by  the  location  yielding  the  greatest  net  revenue  of  all, 
can  be  stated  in  formal  terms  (if  the  reader  so  desires)  with  the 
use  of  transformation  lines,  outlay-substitution  lines,  revenue-outlay 
substitution  lines,  price-ratio  lines,  iso-outlay  lines,  iso-revenue  lines, 
and  iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines,  ^i 

29  Losch,  op.  cit.,  pp.  70-74.  Losch  calculates  for  a  given  factory  price  the 
amount  which  will  be  taken  by  each  consumer  along  a  straight  line  from  the  fac- 
tory. At  a  lower  (higher)  price  each  consumer  will  take  more  (less),  and  the 
extent  of  the  firm's  market  will  be  lengthened  (shortened)  to  include  more  (fewer) 
consumers,  whether  or  not  at  the  expense  of  competitors.  Hence,  the  aggregate 
demand  curve  for  the  firm's  product  with  reference  to  consumers  along  the  line 
is  negatively  sloping.  Deriving  the  demand  curve  with  reference  to  consumers 
along  every  other  line  which  can  radiate  from  the  factory  site  and  summing  yields 
the  total  demand  curve  for  the  firm's  product  in  the  entire  spatial  market  area. 
This,  too,  will  be  negatively  sloping,  whether  or  not  we  follow  Losch  in  postulating 
an  even  spatial  spread  of  consumers  of  like  tastes  and  income,  a  homogeneous 
transport  network,  absence  of  competition,  etc. 

30  Each  pair  of  consecutive  points  may  be  connected  by  a  straight  line.  The 
resulting  straight  lines  would  have  a  different  slope. 

31  It  is  implicitly  assumed  that  the  firm's  operations  have  only  a  neghgible  effect 


160  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Once  we  admit  the  essential  reality  of  a  firm's  ability  to  influence 
prices,  we  are  logically  compelled  to  recognize  that  price  changes  by 
one  firm  frequently  provoke  retaliatory  measures  by  other  firms.  A 
firm  then,  in  seeking  to  maximize  its  profits  and  to  locate  at  the  most 
desirable  site,  in  many  instances  must  take  cognizance  of  the  possible 
reactions  of  other  firms,  and  must  select  its  location,  set  its  price, 
and  determine  its  output  after  considering  not  only  the  direct  conse- 
quences but  also  the  possible  indirect  repercussions  from  the  reactions 
of  other  firms.  Unfortunately,  our  theoretical  schemata  for  under- 
standing the  complex  oligopolistic  situations  of  reality,  despite  recent 
major  advances  scored  by  the  theory  of  games  and  related  studies, 
are  rather  inadequate,  particularly  as  they  pertain  to  locational 
equilibrium.  We  still  have  not  developed  what  might  be  considered 
a  pattern  of  rational  behavior  on  the  part  of  the  firm  in  response  to 
possible  reactions  of  other  firms,  their  indirect  repercussions,  and 
the  many  uncertainties  which  becloud  the  problem.  Nonetheless,  it 
is  of  value  to  have  in  mind  some  of  the  more  important  methodology 
and  achievements  of  those  who  have  struggled  with  this  problem  in 
its  locational  aspects.  This  allows  a  more  comprehensive  perspective  of 
the  space-economy  of  reality  and  a  finer  appreciation  of  the  magnitude 
of  the  assignment. 

We  have  already  noted  several  times  that  Launhardt  presented  the 
earliest  systematic  treatment  of  the  division  of  a  market  area  among 
competing  firms.  However,  in  his  analysis,  the  spatial  co-ordinates  of 
the  firm  were  given;  only  variations  in  output  and  prices  were  con- 
sidered. Fetter's  attention  likewise  centered  on  firms  having  fixed 
locations;  and  Englander  did  not  explicitly  analyze  the  combined 
effects  of  variations  in  both  price  and  location  in  expounding  his 
doctrine  of  the  "local  conditionality  of  demand  and  supply. "^^ 
Hotelling  was  the  first  to  allow  price  and  location  to  vary  simul- 
taneously.    He  used  a  simple  case  primarily  designed  to  elucidate 

upon  the  local  and  regional  income  stream.  Where  regional  income  is  influenced 
significantly  by  a  firm's  location,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Fairless  Steelworks  and  the 
Delaware  River  economy,  then  forces  are  generated  which  in  turn  affect  price 
and  output  of  the  firm,  as  well  as  the  prices  of  various  other  inputs  such  as  labor, 
power,  and  transport.  These  indirect  and  cumulative  effects  are,  at  least  in  the 
traditional  economic  sense,  beyond  the  pale  of  individual  firm  analysis  and  are 
judiciously  relegated  to  the  categoiy  of  regional  analysis.  They  clearly  point  up 
the  close  interrelation  between  firm  and  regional  analysis. 

32  "Kritisches  und  Positives  .  .  .  "op.  cit.  A  general,  though  incomplete,  mathe- 
matical formulation  of  the  problem  of  price  policy  for  two  or  more  spatially  fixed 
competitors  is  given  by  E.  Schneider,  "Observations  on  a  Theory  of  Space  Econ- 
omy," Econometrica,  Vol.  3  (1935),  pp.  79-105. 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  161 

the  imperfect  competitive  conditions  of  reality. ^^  Palander  has  justly 
christened  the  following  as  the  Laimhardt-Hotelling  problem. 

Hotelling's  simplification  pictures  two  firms  each  producing  a  given 
quantity  of  a  commodity  under  constant  cost  conditions  and  each  com- 
peting for  a  market  stretched  along  a  line  of  length  I.  Corresponding 
to  each  unit  length  of  line,  one  unit  quantity  of  commodity  is  con- 
sumed during  each  unit  of  time.  The  demand  from  each  unit  of  the 
line  is  infinitely  inelastic.  Customers'  purchases  are  influenced  only 
by  price — factory  price  plus  transport  cost;  customers  are  indifferent 
to  all  other  circumstances  surrounding  the  act  of  selling.  Firms  A 
and  B  are  located  at  distances  a  and  b  from  their  respective  ends  of 
the  line  and  at  distances  x  and  y  respectively  from  a  point  at  which 
the  delivered  prices  from  A  and  B  are  the  same.  First,  Hotelling 
determines  the  set  of  equilibrium  factory  prices  for  A  and  B  in  terms  of 
a,  b,  I,  and  c  (the  cost  of  transport  per  unit  quantity,  per  unit  dis- 
tance) where  costs  of  production  are  zero,  assuming  that  neither 
producer  attempts  to  drive  the  other  out  of  the  market  by  undercutting. 
He  comes  to  consider  the  case,  among  others,  where  producer  A  is 
spatially  immobilized  and  producer  B  is  free  to  locate  wherever  he 
wishes.  B  proceeds  on  the  assumption  that  A  will  not  change  his 
price  in  reaction  to  B's  price  or  location,  that  is,  that  A  trades 
autonomously.  B  therefore  finds  it  profitable  to  locate  as  close  to  A 
as  other  conditions  permit,  on  the  side  of  A  facing  the  more  extensive 
market.  3  4  This  solution  of  Hotelling's  is  also  borne  out  by  Zeuthen's 
graphic  analysis.  ^  5 

Both  Hotelling  and  Zeuthen  consider  another  type  of  price  policy. 
Instead  of  sharing  the  market  under  the  best  possible  terms,  com- 
petitors can  aim  to  eliminate  one  another  by  undercutting.  This 
course  of  action  becomes  the  more  likely  the  closer  the  two  com- 
petitors are  to  each  other.  ^^  5  realizes  maximum  profits,  given  ^'s 
price,  when  he  sets  his  price  so  that  his  own  delivered  price  will  be 

33  H.  Hotelling,  "Stability  in  Competition,"  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  39  (March 
1929),  pp.  41-57. 

34  If  B  were  approaching  A  on  the  short  side  of  the  market  stretch,  a  position 
as  close  as  possible  to  A  on  the  short  side  would  not  represent  a  maximum  nor  a 
stable  location.  B  would  find  it  profitable  to  skip  over  A,  as  it  were,  and  locate 
as  close  as  possible  on  the  other  side. 

35  F.  Zeuthen,  "Theoretical  Remarks  on  Price  Policy :  Hotelling's  Case  with 
Variations,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  47,  pp.  231-53. 

36  Where  the  two  firms  come  to  be  and  remain  fixed  at  locations  infinitesimally 
close,  we  have  a  problem  similar  to  the  traditional  one  treated  by  Cournot,  Amo- 
roso, Edgeworth,  and  others,  i.e.,  of  two  firms  producing  like  products  and  located 
at  a  one-point  market  center. 


162  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

just  below  ^'s  delivered  price  at  all  points  in  A's  hinterland  when 
the  quantity  he  offers  corresponds  to  the  total  market  demand. 3'' 

Where  both  firms  are  free  to  move,  each  adopting  a  policy  of  sharing 
the  market,  and  where  also  the  same  given  factory  price  is  charged 
by  each,  we  have  a  stable  solution.  Both  firms  locate  at  the  center 
of  the  market  line  or,  more  rigorously,  one  at  the  center,  the  other 
adjacent  to  the  first  on  either  side. ^ 8  For,  if  either  firm  were  to  serve 
a  shorter  stretch  (that  is,  one  noticeably  less  than  one-half  of  the 
market)  with  factory  prices  given  and  equal  and  the  other  assump- 
tions still  valid,  that  firm  could  improve  its  situation  by  skipping 
over  to  the  other  side  of  its  competitor,  and  thus  usurping  the  larger 
market  stretch.  Where  three  or  more  firms  serve  the  market  line, 
each  spatially  mobile,  then  under  the  above  simplified  postulates 
Chamberlin  reasons  that  there  will  not  be  a  tendency  for  concentra- 
tion at  the  market  center,  as  Hotelling  implies.  Rather  there  will  be 
a  dispersion,  the  dispersion  being  least  when  sellers  are  grouped  in  pairs: 

Taking  the  length  of  the  line  as  unity,  the  general  conclusion  for  n  sellers 
is  that  the  space  between  the  last  sellers  at  either  end  and  the  ends  of  the 

line  would  never  exceed  1/n  (if  the  number  of  sellers  is  odd  it  can  never 

1    \  v 

exceed ) ,  and  that  the  space  between  any  two  sellers  can  never 

n  +  1  / 

exceed  2/n,  this  limit  being  reached  only  in  the  extreme  case  where 

sellers  are  grouped  by  twos.^^ 

Anyone  entering  the  market  or  any  firm  considering  a  new  site, 
operating  under  the  assumption  that  the  positions  of  all  of  its  com- 
petitors are  fixed,  will  locate  either  adjacent  to  that  firm  which 
services  the  longest  market  stretch  on  one  of  its  sides  or,  in  certain 
likely  circumstances,  at  a  point  on  the  longest  stretch  between  any 
two  consecutively  placed  competitors. 

Palander,  eschewing  certain  of  Hotelling's,  Zeuthen's,  and  Chamber- 
lin's  assumptions,  penetrates  still  further  this  problem  of  spatial  com- 
petition. First,  he  shows  that  Hotelling's  basic  solution  for  two  firms 
trading  autonomously  is  not  generally  valid.  A  stable  equilibrium  is 
reached  only  where  the  two  firms  are  far  apart  and  have  small  hinter- 
lands.    Otherwise,  a  constant  fluctuation  of  price  takes  place  within 

37  Apropos  the  applicability  of  conclusions  relevant  for  a  market  of  fixed  linear 
extent  to  a  market  of  unlimited  areal  character,  refer  to  Losch  (op.  cit.,  1st  ed., 
1940,  pp.  12-14). 

38  See  E.  Chamberlin,  The  Theory  of  Monopolistic  Competition,  Cambridge, 
Mass.,  1938,  3rd  ed.,  Appendix  C. 

39  Ibid.,  p.  209. 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  163 

limits,  and  price  may  even  be  cut  to  the  level  of  costs  (constant) 
if  the  firms  lie  very  close  to  each  other.  The  solution  for  two  firms 
where  one  is  free  to  locate  is  thus  inherently  unstable. ^^ 

Second,  Palander  generalizes  the  problem  to  apply  when  firm  B,  in 
selecting  a  new  location,  can  choose  (1)  to  eliminate  its  competitor 
from  the  market  by  undercutting;  (2)  to  share  the  intermediate  market 
with  its  competitor;  or  (3)  by  raising  its  price,  to  confine  its  sales  to 
consumers  in  its  own  hinterland,  that  is,  to  adopt  a  policy  of  hinterland 
defense.  A¥here  B  trades  autonomously,  as  A  does,  then  B  adopts  either 
(1)  a  policy  of  eliminating  A  from  the  market  in  which  case  he  locates 
right  next  to  A  and  slightly  undercuts  A's  price;  or  (2)  a  policy  of 
hinterland  defense,  in  which  case  he  may  locate  adjacent  to  .A,  or  as 
far  away  as  the  mid-point  on  the  largest  market  stretch — this  depend- 
ing upon  A^s  price  and  location. ^i  In  these  circumstances,  B  would 
never  find  it  advantageous  to  share  the  intermediate  market  with  A. 
Where  B  trades  ''superpolitisch,"  i.e.,  is  aware  of  A's  path  of  reaction 
to  his  (B's)  choice  of  location  and  price,  he  will  pursue  a  different  but 
determinate  course.  He  will  locate  relatively  far  away  from  A.  Where 
both  A  and  B  trade  superpolitisch,  there  results  an  express  tendency 
for  deglomeration. 

Lerner  and  Singer, ^  2  somewhat  more  realistic,  set  an  upper  limit  to 
the  price  which  each  buyer  is  willing  to  pay  for  one  unit  of  the  com- 
modity (that  is,  limit  the  stretch  of  infinite  inelasticity  on  the  demand 
curve  of  each  consumer)  ;4  3  and  they  have  suggested  analytic  methods 
for  the  case  where  a  demand  with  some  elasticity  is  postulated  for  each 
consumer.  As  a  consequence  their  conclusions  at  times  differ  signifi- 
cantly from  those  of  the  above  authors.  To  a  certain  extent,  too,  they 
examine  more  comprehensively  the  range  of  conditions,  patterns  of 

40  Palander,  op.  cit..  Chap.  IX,  especially  p.  248.  Furthermore,  Palander  finds 
a  logical  inconsistency  at  the  base  of  Hotelling's  agglomeration  tendency.  Hotel- 
ling  postulates  that  firm  B  trades  autonomously  with  respect  to  price  (assumes 
that  .4's  price  will  not  change)  yet,  in  selecting  the  most  desirable  location,  some- 
how comes  to  possess  knowledge  of  the  final  equilibrium  price  that  should  result 
from  mutual  price  adaptations  by  A  and  B  (ibid.,  p.  251). 

"^1  When  A's  price  is  relatively  high  and  his  position  relatively  near  the  center 
of  the  market,  B  will  tend  to  eliminate  A  from  the  market.  When  ^'s  price  is 
relatively  low  and  he  lies  relatively  near  one  of  the  ends  of  the  market  line,  B 
will  tend  to  locate  at  some  distance  from  A  and  set  a  price  so  high  that  he  will 
just  be  able  to  retain  the  consumers  lying  in  his  own  hinterland.  (Ibid.,  pp. 
391-93.) 

42  A.  P.  Lerner  and  H.  W.  Singer,  "Some  Notes  on  Duopoly  and  Spatial  Com- 
petition," Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  45  (1937),  pp.  145-86. 

43  See  also  in  this  connection,  A.  Robinson,  "A  Problem  in  the  Theory  of  Indus- 
trial Location,"  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  51  (June-Sept.  1941),  pp.  270-75. 


164  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

reaction,  and  possible  solutions  that  are  inherent  within  the  problem. 
For  example,  they  consider  an  alternative  to  the  short-sighted  policy 
where  two  mobile  competitors  undercut  each  other,  being  primarily 
concerned  with  short-run  gains.  Each  producer  assumes  that  his 
competitor  will  not  respond  to  the  sort  of  encroachment  where  the 
former  shifts  location — so  long  as  his  encroachment  is  limited  to  one- 
half  of  his  competitor's  customers — but  that  his  competitor  will,  on  the 
other  hand,  reciprocate  undercutting  of  price  with  undercutting.  This 
assumption  yields  the  result  that  A  and  B  may  be  located  adjacent  to 
one  another  or  at  various  distances  apart,  depending  upon  transport 
cost,  size  of  market,  and  the  upper  limit  to  price.** 

Smithies* 5  has  gone  farther  and  discarded  the  postulate  of  an  inelas- 
tic demand  for  each  consumer.  He  examines  the  case  where  identical 
linear  demand  functions  exist  at  every  point  on  the  linear  market  and 
accordingly  arrives  at  solutions  different  from  those  deduced  by  others. 
For  example,  the  solution  to  the  full  competition  case  where  both  firms 
are  mobile  and  each  assumes,  in  any  move,  that  the  other's  price  and 
location  are  given,  is  not  that  one  which  follows  Hotelling's  line  of 
reasoning.  It  does  not  conclude  with  the  two  firms  adjacent — a  solu- 
tion which  others  have  suggested  when  special  conditions  obtain.  In- 
stead, the  two  firms  remain  apart  although  less  than  half  the  linear 
market  separates  them.  This  is  so  because  each  producer  is  compelled 
to  weigh  the  gains  from  further  encroachment  upon  his  competitor  as 
he  moves  closer  to  the  market  center  against  the  loss  of  consumer 
patronage  in  his  own  hinterland  from  greater  freight  charges.* ^ 

■*^  In  addition,  Lemer  and  Singer  have  treated  the  question  of  spatial  price  dis- 
crimination in  some  detail,  a  question  which  Hotelling,  Zeuthen,  and  Palander 
had  already  recognized  to  different  extents.  Hoover,  too,  has  made  a  number  of 
astute  observations  on  the  problem  (E.  M.  Hoover,  Jr.,  "Spatial  Price  Discrimina- 
tion," The  Review  of  Economic  Studies,  Vol.  IV,  No.  3,  pp.  182-91).  Others,  such 
as  A.  Smithies  ["Monopolistic  Price  Policy  in  a  Spatial  Market,"  Econometrica, 
Vol.  9  (1941),  pp.  63-73],  E.  Schneider,  in  several  articles,  and  H.  Moller  ["Grund- 
lagen  einer  Theorie  der  regionalen  Preisdifferenzierung,"  Weltwirtschajtliches 
Archiv,  Bd.  58  (1943),  pp.  335-90]  have  been  concerned  with  the  question  either 
in  a  monopolistic  or  oligopolistic  setting. 

Price  discrimination,  which  tends  to  be  most  expedient  within  spatial  markets 
where  distance  and  other  geographic  obstacles  enable  the  producer  to  deal  sepa- 
rately with  the  various  sectors  of  his  market,  offers  to  the  individual  firm  oppor- 
tunities for  additional  profits.  Obviously  as  one  proceeds  from  a  monopolistic  to 
an  oligopolistic  situation,  these  opportunities  become  limited,  the  more  so  as  the 
number  of  competitors  increases  and  their  locations  draw  nearer  to  that  of  the 
given  firm. 

45  A.  Smithies,  "Optimum  Location  in  Spatial  Competition,"  Journal  of  Political 
Economy,  Vol.  44  (June  1941),  pp.  423-39. 

46  Smithies  has  also  considered  a  more  generalized  set  of  conjectural  hypotheses 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  165 

Ackley4  7  examines  still  more  realistic  market  conditions  in  spatial 
competition.  He  analyzes  a  number  of  cases  where  there  is  a  discon- 
tinuous distribution  of  customers  with  different  demand  functions,  that 
is,  cases  of  spatially  discrete  demand  where  the  quantity  sold  by  either 
seller  is  a  discontinuous  function  of  his  own  and  his  rival's  prices  and 
locations.  He  shows  clearly  that  no  precise  generalized  solutions 
emerge,  even  when  rigid  assumptions  are  made  as  to  competitor's  be- 
havior. The  solution  of  each  specific  discrete  case  needs  to  be  worked 
out  anew  under  various  assumptions  regarding  competitor's  reactions. 
Often  the  very  type  of  market  discontinuity  conditions  the  type  of 
assumption  sellers  make  as  to  their  competitor's  conduct.  In  striving 
for  maximum  profits  the  sellers  do  not  necessarily  confront  any  less 
determinate  or  more  unstable  situations  than  where  a  continuous 
spatial  market  exists.'* ^ 

Finally,  we  should  mention  a  generalized  approach  being  developed 
in  connection  with  game  theory,  an  analytical  advance  which  has 
received  its  initial  and  principal  stimulus  from  the  work  of  von 
Neumann  and  Morgenstern.^s     Game  theory  pertains  to  situations 

for  each  competitor.  In  addition  to  the  full  competition  case  cited,  he  examines 
the  cases  where  (1)  "Each  competitor  in  making  an  adjustment  assumes  that  his 
rival  will  set  a  price  equal  to  his  own  and  will  adopt  a  location  symmetrical  with 
his  own"  {ibid.,  p.  427),  and  (2)  "each  competitor  assumes  that  his  rival  will  have 
the  same  price  reactions  as  above  but  will  keep  his  location  unchanged"  {ibid., 
p.  427).  The  case  where  each  firm  assumes  that  his  competitor  will  not  react,  if 
he  (the  competitor)  is  cut  out  of  the  market  entirely  by  his  rival,  is  discarded  as 
fantastic. 

In  addition,  Smithies  investigates  somewhat  the  effect  upon  the  final  equilibrium 
relationship  of  changes  in  marginal  cost  of  one  or  both  firms. 

47  G.  Ackley,  "Spatial  Competition  in  a  Discontinuous  Market,"  Quarterly 
Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  56   (February  1942),  pp.  212-30. 

48  Mbller  {op.  cit.),  following  H.  von  Stackelberg's  approach,  discusses  at  length 
the  problem  of  stability  of  equilibrium  under  various  regional  competitive  and 
price-setting  situations. 

49  J.  von  Neumann  and  0.  Morgenstern,  Theory  of  Games  and  Economic  Be- 
havior, Princeton,  1944.  Also  refer  to  the  excellent  and  somewhat  complementary 
expository  reviews:  J.  Marschak,  "Neumann's  and  Morgenstern 's  New  Approach 
to  Static  Economics,"  The  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  LIV  (April  1946), 
pp.  97-115;  L.  Hurwicz,  "The  Theory  of  Economic  Behavior,"  The  American 
Economic  Review,  Vol.  XXXV  (December  1945),  pp.  909-925;  and  C.  Kaysen, 
"A  Revolution  in  Economic  Theory,"  Review  of  Economic  Studies,  Vol.  XIV, 
No.  35  (1946-47),  pp.  1-15.  A  recent  survey  of  game  theory  is  contained  in  R. 
Duncan  Luce  and  Howard  Raiffa,  A  Survey  of  the  Theory  of  Games,  Behavioral 
Models  Project,  Columbia  University,  1954,  hectographed.  Also  see  John  Nash, 
"Two-Person  Cooperative  Games"  and  J.  P.  Mayberry,  J.  F.  Nash,  and  M.  Shubik, 
"A  Comparison  of  Treatments  of  a  Duopoly  Situation,"  Econometrica,  Vol.  21 
(January  1953),  pp.  12&-40  and  141-54,  respectively. 


166  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

of  interest  conflict;  it  has  relevance  to  the  above  locational  equilibrium 
problem  where  a  firm,  either  individually  or  in  collusion  with  others, 
competes  with  other  firms  or  coalitions  of  firms  in  serving  a  given 
consumer  market. 

Basic  to  game  theory  in  its  current  form  are  certain  postulates.  It 
is  posited  that  the  variables  within  a  given  situation  are  well  specified 
and  that  the  values  which  they  may  take  and  the  possible  outcomes  of 
the  situation  can  be  precisely  characterized.  (In  our  spatial  equi- 
librium problem  the  behavior  of  competitors  need  not  be  postulated  as 
invariant,  or  as  varying  within  certain  limits,  but  can  be  considered 
an  unrestricted  variable.)  Individuals  are  assumed  to  be  completely 
informed  about  the  physical  characteristics  of  the  given  situation  and 
to  be  "able  to  perform  all  the  statistical,  mathematical,  etc.  operations 
which  this  knowledge  makes  possible."50  Further,  they  are  able,  either 
directly  or  indirectly,  to  assign  to  each  possible  outcome  a  numerical 
utility,  for  all  practical  purposes  a  money  value,  which  in  coalition 
activity  must  be  transferable. 

Assuming  that  each  individual  (producer)  desires  to  maximize  utility 
(gains),  von  Neumann  and  Morgenstern  define  rational  behavior  of  an 
individual  as  the  choice  of  that  strategy  which  permits  him  the  best 
of  all  possible  minima,  that  is,  the  maximum  of  the  minima.  This 
follows  since  he  knows  that  his  competitors  (viewed  as  a  coalition  if 
we  wish  to  consider  the  individual  competitor  alone)  in  attempting  to 
maximize  their  gains  will  minimize  his  own.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
coalition  of  competitors,  knowing  that  its  rival  will  tend  to  maximize 
his  gains,  will  pursue  a  strategy  which  permits  its  rival  the  least  of  all 
maxima,  that  is,  the  minimum  of  the  maxima.  When  both  parties 
pursue  their  respective  policies  simultaneously,  it  is  conceivable  that 
a  relatively  simple  stable  solution  will  be  arrived  at;  it  would  be  a 
"saddle-point"  solution  where  the  maximum  of  the  minima  coincides 
with  the  minimum  of  the  maxima.  In  the  usual  case  a  saddle-point 
will  not  exist.  However,  the  authors  have  abstractly  demonstrated 
that  when  each  party  pursues  a  course  of  "mixed  strategies,"  that  is, 
chooses  several  strategies  and  assigns  definite  probabilities  to  each, 
then  a  solution  will  always  exist.  The  competitive  struggle  between 
an  individual  firm  and  a  coalition  of  rivals  can  thus  be  resolved.  By 
a  similar  reasoning  process  the  individual  competitor  may  find  it  profit- 
able to  ally  himself  with  others  and  be  part  of  a  coalition. 

50  Neumann  and  Morgenstern,  op.  cit.,  p.  30.  This  assumption  does  not  specify 
"perfect  information"  on  the  part  of  all  competitors.  The  rules  of  the  game  "may 
explicitly  prescribe  that  certain  participants  should  not  possess  certain  pieces  of 
information"   (p.  30  note). 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  167 

In  addition  to  confronting  the  conceptual  complications  of  collusive 
action  and  the  tremendous  problem  of  empirical  verification  in  a  situa- 
tion where  the  variety  and  complexity  of  solutions  are  overwhelming, 
game  theorists  do  labor  under  some  very  unrealistic  assumptions.  It 
is  difficult  to  accept  the  assigning  of  complex  probabilities  to  various 
courses  of  action  as  characteristic  of  man's  behavior  in  the  competitive 
struggle.  It  is  perhaps  even  more  difficult  to  accept  the  assumption 
of  complete  knowledge  in  a  very  involved  situation  when  experience 
teaches  us  that  any  human  being  is  far  more  restricted  in  his  per- 
ceptions. Moreover,  empirical  studies  do  show  a  great  variation  in 
individual  abilities  which  runs  counter  to  von  Neumann's  and  Mor- 
genstern's  condition  that  all  rivals  are  equally  capable  of  drawing 
inferences  from  given  amounts  of  information. ^i  (Nor  does  the  usual 
businessman  concede  the  point  that  his  competitors  are  his  equal. 
Rather,  it  is  an  everyday  observation  that  businessmen  strive  to  outwit 
their  competitors,  being  convinced  of  their  own  superiority.)  Lastly, 
in  a  spatial  competition  setting,  von  Neumann  and  Morgenstern's  ap- 
proach would  overemphasize  the  dependence  of  any  individual's  choice 
of  strategy  upon  his  competitors'  reactions.  In  a  social  exchange  econ- 
omy, geographic  separation  of  rivals  acts  as  insulation  from  reactions 
and  in  many  instances  simplifies  the  problem  of  maximization. 

Despite  these  difficulties  and  shortcomings,  the  contributions  in  the 
area  of  game  theory  represent  an  initial  major  achievement.  As  game 
theory  develops  it  will  undoubtedly  cast  considerable  light  upon  a  host 
of  basic  problems  as  well  as  the  locational  equilibrium  problem.  ^  2 

51  However,  J.  Marschak  {op.  cit.),  after  presenting  some  simple  illustrations, 
concludes :  "it  seems  to  us  that  properly  stated  differences  in  degrees  of  knowledge 
or  intelligence  of  individual  players  can  also  be  regarded  as  rules  of  the  game" 
(p.  106). 

52  Allied  to  the  locational  equilibrium  problem  of  this  section  are  the  contribu- 
tions of  S.  Enke  ["Equilibrium  among  Spatially  Separated  Markets:  Solution  by 
Electric  Analogue,"  Econometrica,  Vol.  19  (January  1951),  pp.  40-47],  P.  Samuel- 
son  ["Spatial  Price  Equilibrium  and  Linear  Programming,"  American  Economic 
Review,  Vol.  XLII  (June  1952),  pp.  283-303],  M.  Beckmann  ["A  Continuous 
Model  of  Transportation,"  Econometrica,  Vol.  20  (October  1952),  pp.  643-660,  and 
"The  Partial  Equilibrium  of  a  Continuous  Spatial  Market,"  Weltwirischaftliches 
Archiv,  Bd.  71  (1953),  Heft  1,  pp.  73-89],  K.  A.  Fox  ["A  Spatial  Equilibrium 
Model  of  the  Livestock-Feed  Economy  in  the  United  States,"  Econometrica,  Vol. 
21  (October  1953),  pp.  547-566],  and  others  on  spatial  price  equilibrium,  especially 
as  related  to  transportation  flow  patterns. 

In  one  of  its  simplest  forms  Enke  poses  the  problem  as  follows : 
"There  are  three  regions  trading  a  homogeneous  good.     Each  region  consti- 
tutes a  single  and  distinct  market.    The  regions  of  each  possible  pair  of  regions 
are  separated — but  not  isolated — by  a  transportation  cost  per  physical  unit 
which  is  independent  of  volume.    There  are  no  legal  restrictions  to  limit  the 


168  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

actions  of  the  profit-seeking  traders  in  each  region.  For  each  region  the 
functions  which  relate  local  production  and  local  use  to  local  price  are  known, 
and  consequently  the  magnitude  of  the  difference  which  will  be  exported  or 
imported  at  each  local  price  is  also  known.  Given  these  trade  functions  and 
transportation  costs,  we  wish  to  ascertain: 

(1)  the  net  price  in  each  region, 

(2)  the  quantity  of  exports  or  imports  for  each  region, 

(3)  which  regions  export,  import,  or  do  neither, 

(4)  the  aggregate  trade  in  the  commodity, 

(5)  the  volume  and  direction  of  trade  between  each  possible  pair  of  regions 
..."  {o-p.  cit.,  p.  41). 

Viewed  in  this  way  the  problem  is  essentially  a  transportation  problem  and  not  a 
basic  location  problem.  Enke  demonstrates  how  an  electric  analog  can  be 
employed  to  derive  a  solution  to  this  problem. 

As  Samuelson  has  shown,  the  Enke  problem  contains  within  it  the  following 
Koopmans-Hitchcock  minimum  transport  cost  problem :  "A  specified  total  number 
of  (empty  or  ballast)  ships  is  to  be  sent  out  from  each  of  a  number  of  ports.  They 
are  to  be  allocated  among  a  number  of  other  receiving  ports,  with  the  total  sent  in 
to  each  such  port  being  specified.  If  we  are  given  the  unit  costs  of  shipment 
between  every  two  ports,  how  can  we  minimize  the  total  costs  of  the  program?" 
[Samuelson,  op.  cit.,  p.  284.  For  full  discussion  of  this  problem  see  T.  C.  Koop- 
mans,  "Optimum  Utilization  of  the  Transportation  System,"  Econometrica,  Vol. 
17,  Supplement  (July  1949),  pp.  136-146;  and  T.  C.  Koopmans  and  S.  Reiter,  "A 
Model  of  Transportation,"  Chap.  XIV  in  Activity  Analysis  of  Production  and 
Allocation,  ed.  by  T.  C.  Koopmans,  John  Wiley  &  Sons,  Inc.,  1951.]  It  should 
also  be  noted  that  the  Enke  problem  contains  within  it  a  bit  of  the  location  prob- 
lem. For  the  Enke  problem  determines  the  scale  of  output  in  each  given  region 
(the  Koopmans-Hitchcock  problem  implicitly  assumes  that  the  scale  is  given). 

Enke  has  not  confined  himself  to  only  three  regions.  His  analog  solution  is 
proposed  as  applicable  to  a  problem  embracing  many  regions.  Samuelson  has 
also  probed  the  many-region  problem,  and  Beckmann  has  gone  even  further  and 
considered  the  case  of  "continuous  geographical  intensity  distributions  of  produc- 
tion," i.e.,  where  every  infinitesimally  small  area  in  an  economy  which  can  consist 
of  many  regions  both  produces  and  consumes  a  commodity. 

If  excess  supply  functions  could  be  derived  for  each  infinitesimally  small  area 
of  the  world  and  if  the  Samuelson-Beckmann  formulation  could  be  considered 
relevant  and  adequate  and  could  yield  a  quantitative  solution,  then  the  location 
problem  would  be  solved.  Corresponding  to  each  infinitesimally  small  area,  there 
would  be  a  unique  scale  of  output  (zero  or  positive  amount  of  production),  such 
as  Enke  obtains  for  each  region  in  his  more  limited  model.  We  would  have  our 
geographic  distribution  of  production.  Theoretically,  both  the  location  and 
transportation  patterns  would  have  been  derived  simultaneously. 

In  practice,  however,  the  Samuelson-Beckmann  formulation  ignores  a  number 
of  basic  locational  forces,  as  Beckmann  fully  recognizes,  and  more  important  is 
not  now  able,  and  is  not  likely  in  the  future  to  be  able,  to  yield  a  quantitative 
solution  for  every  infinitesimally  small  area.  It  is  at  this  juncture  that  location 
theory  makes  its  contribution.  For  location  theory  seeks  principles  to  narrow 
down,  and  greatly  narrow  down,  the  number  of  points  to  be  considered  as  potential 
locations  for  the  production  of  any  given  commodity.  Once  a  relatively  small 
number  of  production  points  or  regions  are  isolated,  the  Enke-Samuelson-Beck- 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  169 

4.     Concluding  Remarks 

In  bringing  this  chapter  to  a  close  we  should  fully  appreciate  the 
progress  which  still  needs  to  be  achieved  to  understand  rational  be- 
havior for  the  individual  firm,  even  under  simplified  cost  assumptions. 
When  more  realistic  cost  conditions  are  introduced,  when  geographic 
mobility  of  the  firm  is  permitted  not  only  along  a  line  as  in  most  of  the 
discussion  of  the  preceding  section  but  also  within  a  geographic  area, 
and  when  the  uneven  areal  distribution  of  consumer  demand  is  recog- 
nized and  different  pricing  policies  are  allowed,  still  greater  progress 
is  required. 

From  the  standpoint  of  enabling  one  to  reach  precise  results,  the 
market  and  supply  area  analyses  discussed  in  the  first  two  sections  of 
this  chapter  are  more  satisfactory  than  the  locational  equilibrium 
analysis  following  Hotelling's  approach,  even  when  the  latter  is  sup- 
plemented by  game  theory.  Market  and  supply  area  analyses  achieve 
these  more  precise  results  through  postulating  a  relatively  simple  prob- 
lem and  through  abstracting  from,  among  other  factors,  competitors' 
reactions,  pricing  policy  as  a  variable,  and  for  the  most  part  locational 
mobility. 

In  contrast,  the  locational  equilibrium  approach  stemming  from 
Hotelling's  work  is  much  more  sophisticated  in  its  consideration  of 
reactions  and  mobility.  However,  this  approach  yields  results  only 
within  a  very  restrictive  framework.  It  almost  completely  ignores  the 
cost  side  of  the  picture  and  the  inequalities  in  the  spatial  distribution 
of  natural  and  human  resources.  Apart  from  the  fact  that  entrepre- 
neurial ability  and  organization  and  scale  of  output  may  vary  from 
firm  to  firm  and  thus  cause  each  firm  to  face  a  different  cost  situation, 
which  in  turn  affects  each  one's  competitive  policy,  it  is  generally  true 
that  production  and  distribution  costs  will  not  be  the  same  for  all  sites. 
Access  to  raw  material  sources  and  power  facilities,  transport  relations 
with  consumers,  availability  of  skilled  and  unskilled  labor,  labor  organ- 
ization, external  economies  from  association  with  other  industries,  taxes 
and  other  social  burdens,  political  conditions,  relevant  geographic  fea- 
tures such  as  bed-rock  conditions  for  power  plants  and  soil  for  farming, 
capital  supply,  markets  for  by-products,  opportunities  for  waste  dis- 


mann  formulation  may  offer  a  more  efficient  approach  to  the  determination  of  the 
resulting  geographic  flows  of  commodities  (e.g.,  see  Fox,  op.  dt.). 

However,  in  a  second  volume  on  principles  of  regional  science  we  hope  to  be 
able  to  demonstrate  how  the  activity  analysis  approach  can  further  regional  theory 
and  thereby  our  understanding  of  industrial  location. 


170  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

posal,  etc.,  do  vary  from  site  to  site  and  give  rise  to  significant  cost 
differentials.  Herein  lies  probably  the  most  serious  weakness  of  the 
Hotelling  approach. 

Though  the  Hotelling  approach  does  not  yield  as  precise  results  as 
do  market  and  supply  area  analyses,  it  can  nonetheless  be  cloaked  in 
a  formal  substitution  framework  for  most  specific  situations  where 
adequate  assumptions  are  made  about  the  behavior  of  such  variables 
as  competitors'  reactions,  price  policies,  and  cost  functions.  For  exam- 
ple, consider  the  first  of  Hotelling's  problems  discussed  above.  In 
terms  of  outlay-substitution  lines,  revenue-outlay  substitution  lines, 
and  iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines  which  relate  to  transport  outlays  and 
commodity  revenue,  in  moving  toward  A's  location,  B  substitutes  trans- 
port outlays  in  one  direction  for  transport  outlays  in  another  direction. 
(This  corresponds  to  a  shift  along  an  outlay-substitution  line.)  B  is 
at  the  same  time  proceeding  along  a  revenue-outlay  substitution  line 
on  to  iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines  of  higher  and  higher  order  (see  Fig. 
26,  Chap.  6).  When  B  finally  comes  as  close  as  possible  to  A,  on  the 
side  of  A  facing  the  more  extensive  market,  his  corresponding  position 
on  the  revenue-outlay  substitution  line  rests  on  an  iso-revenue-less- 
outlay  line  higher  in  order  than  any  other  iso-revenue-less-outlay  line 
with  which  the  substitution  line  has  a  point  in  common.  This  point 
corresponds  to  maximum  profits  and  stability,  given  Hotelling's 
assumptions.  5  3 

As  already  indicated  game  theory  promises  to  furnish  additional 
insights  into  the  Hotelling  locational  equilibrium  (interdependence) 
problem.  When  this  is  achieved,  there  still  remains  the  task  of  inte- 
grating the  Hotelling  approach  with  the  type  of  market  and  supply 
area  analyses  presented  in  the  earlier  sections  of  this  chapter  and  with 
the  Weberian  doctrine  reformulated  in  the  preceding  and  later  chap- 
es Or  consider  a  more  complex  situation  in  which  both  processing  costs  and 
transport  costs  on  raw  materials  are  variables.  Along  the  horizontal  axis  of  a 
relevant  graph  (once  again  see  Fig.  26,  Chap.  6),  we  would  measure  transport  plus 
processing  outlays.  Along  the  vertical  axis  we  would  measure  product  revenue. 
B  would  then  shift  his  location  until  he  reached  a  site  which  would  correspond 
to  that  point  on  his  revenue-outlay  substitution  line  which  lies  on  the  highest 
iso-revenue-less-outlay  line.  However,  in  this  case  the  revenue-outlay  substitu- 
tion Hne  would  in  turn  be  associated  not  only  with  a  substitution  line  between 
transport  outlays  on  product  in  one  direction  and  transport  outlays  on  product  in 
the  opposite  direction  but  also  with  a  second  substitution  line  between  transport 
outlays  on  product  and  transport  outlays  on  raw  material  and  a  third  substitution 
line  between  total  transport  outlays  and  processing  outlays. 

For  an  interesting  set  of  graphs  which  illuminates  this  problem  see  Greenhut, 
"Integrating  the  Leading  Theories  .  .  ."  op.  cit. 


MARKET  AND  SUPPLY  AREA  ANALYSIS  171 

ters.54  Even  allowing  for  progress  on  both  these  scores,  we  must  still 
grapple  with  other  variables  which  basically  condition  industrial  loca- 
tion and  regional  development.  Several  of  these  are  introduced  into 
the  analysis  in  the  succeeding  chapter. 

54  Greenhut,  in  his  several  articles,  op.  cit.,  has  explored  and  probed  considerably 
into  this  problem. 


Chapter 


8 


Agglomeration  Analysis  and 
Agricultural  Location  Theory 


In  his  classic  work  on  location  theory,  Alfred  Weber  emphasizes 
three  basic  location  forces.  ^  Two  of  these,  transport  cost  differentials 
and  labor  cost  differentials,  interplay  to  determine  the  regional  dis- 
tribution of  industries.  We  have  already  treated  these  two  forces 
among  others  in  the  preceding  chapters.  The  third  general  location 
factor,  agglomeration  (deglomeration)  economies  and  diseconomies, 
acts,  according  to  Weber,  to  concentrate  or  disperse  industries  within 
any  given  region.  In  our  discussion  thus  far  we  have  touched  inciden- 
tally upon  this  third  locational  factor.    We  now  probe  deeper. 

Following  Ohlin,  Hoover  has  neatly  classified  agglomeration  (de- 
glomeration) factors  as  follows: 

(a)  Large-scale  economies  within  a  firm,  consequent  upon  the  enlarge- 
ment of  the  firm's  scale  of  production  at  one  point. 

(b)  Localization  economies  for  all  firms  in  a  single  industry  at  a 
single  location,  consequent  upon  the  enlargement  of  the  total  output  of 
that  industry  at  that  location. 

(c)  Urbanization  economies  for  all  firms  in  all  industries  at  a  single 
location,  consequent  upon  the  enlargement  of  the  total  economic  size 
(population,  income,  output,  or  wealth)  of  that  location,  for  all  industries 
taken  together. 

Bearing  this  classification  in  mind,  we  can  now  examine  how  agglom- 
eration theory  can  be  reformulated  in  order  to  facilitate  a  more  satis- 

1  C.  J.  Friedrich,  Alfred  Weber's  Theory  of  Location  of  Industries,  University 
of  Chicago  Press,  Chicago,  1929. 

172 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     173 

factory  integration  with  the  previous  substitution  analysis  and  with 
orthodox  production  theory. 

1.     Economies  of  Scale 

As  the  first  step  let  us  investigate  the  influence  of  large-scale  econo- 
mies upon  the  location  of  production.  Let  us  reconsider  the  case  to 
which  Fig.  27  of  the  preceding  chapter  pertains.  Two  firms,  A  and  B, 
are  competing  for  the  market  along  the  straight  line  connecting  their 


Fig.  30.    A  case  of  agglomeration  from  economies  of  scale. 

factory  sites.  Their  respective  margin  lines  are  KGWP  and  TUWV. 
The  delivered  price  of  each  to  the  consumer  at  X,  when  X  is  the  mar- 
ginal consumer,  is  the  same.  A  comes  to  serve  consumers  lying  along 
the  stretch  AX;  B  serves  those  along  the  stretch  XB.^ 

In  this  case  the  marginal  costs  of  both  firms  are  rising  sufficiently 
rapidly  to  make  feasible  a  division  of  the  market.  Suppose,  however, 
that  significant  economies  of  scale  extend  over  a  much  larger  range  of 
production  and  that  the  margin  lines  of  the  two  producers  are  as  in 
Fig.  30.  ^'s  margin  line  always  lies  below  B's;  no  matter  which  con- 
sumer is  designated  as  marginal,  A  can  deliver  to  him  at  a  lower  price 
than  B.  A  usurps  the  entire  market  and  can  do  so  because  production 
economies  realized  with  increase  of  his  output  more  than  balance  the 
mounting  transport  cost  disadvantage  as  more  distant  consumers  are 
served. 

2  A  la  Hoover,  it  is  assumed  that  a  producer  always  serves  first  the  nearer  of 
any  two  consumers. 


174 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


The  case  of  Fig.  30  warrants  concentration  of  production  at  A.^ 
When  contrasted  with  Fig.  27  it  neatly  illustrates  the  impulse  toward 
agglomeration  which  stems  from  economies  of  scale.  In  another  con- 
nection, namely,  in  determining  for  each  commodity  the  appropriate 
size  of  an  hexagonal  market  area,  Losch  has  also  developed  this  point. ^ 

Although  the  concentration  of  production  at  A  (rather  than  a  divi- 
sion between  A  and  B)  entails  an  increase  of  over-all  transport  outlays, 
it  permits  a  still  greater  decrease  in  over-all  production  outlays.  In 
terms  of  our  substitution  framework,  transport  outlays  are  substituted 
for  production  outlays.  If  we  were  to  visualize  one  parent  company 
controlling  the  two  subsidiary  firms  A  and  B,  the  parent  company, 
by  concentrating  production  at  A,  would  be  shifting  along  an  outlay- 
substitution  line  and  proceeding  on  to  lower  iso-outlay  (transport  plus 
production  outlay)  lines.  Viewed  from  society's  standpoint,  such  con- 
centration of  production  is  desirable;  it  allows  the  production  of  any 
given  output  at  lower  cost  and  thus  releases  resources  for  other  pro- 
duction and  use. 

The  solution,  however,  does  not  necessarily  rest  with  concentration 

3  However,  in  other  types  of  situations  there  may  not  be  a  clear-cut  indication 
of  the  location  at  which  production  should  concentrate.  Take,  for  example,  the 
case  represented  by  Fig.  31.  A  and  B  have  identical  cost  curves  and  confront 
identical  transport  rate  structures.     (Consumers  are  uniformly  distributed  along 


K 


Fig.  31.    A  case  of  indeterminacy  in  location. 


AB.)  Economies  of  scale  dictate  concentration  of  production  in  one  plant,  but 
such  concentration  is  as  feasible  at  5  as  at  ^.  In  the  traditional  sense  the  solution 
to  this  problem  is  indeterminate;  and  as  Hoover  has  pointed  out  (op.  cit.,  pp. 
98-99),  the  location  at  which  production  is  undertaken  first  is  the  location  at  which 
production  is  more  likely  to  concentrate.  (The  alternative  of  a  division  of  the 
market  between  the  two  sites  involves  instability.) 
4  Losch,  o-p.  cit.,  pp.  70-85. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     175 

of  production  at  A.  There  may  be  other  sites  lying  between  A  and  B 
which  would  not  labor  at  such  high  production  costs  as  B  must.  Since 
they  would  occasion  less  transport  outlays  than  A  in  serving  the  total 
array  of  consumers  (except  in  extreme  instances) ,  they  must  be  con- 
sidered as  potential  locations.  If  any  of  these  intermediate  sites  can 
produce  over  the  relevant  range  of  output  at  lower  costs  than  A,  obvi- 
ously production  should  shift  from  A.  If  none  can,  then  comparison 
must  be  made  between  savings  on  transport  outlays  engendered  by 
any  given  shift  from  A  and  the  corresponding  increase  in  production 
outlays.  If  a  shift  were  found  to  be  desirable,  the  producer  (parent 
company)  would  be  proceeding  along  a  revenue-outlay  substitution  line 
(as  well  as  along  several  outlay-substitution  lines)  on  to  a  higher  iso- 
revenue-less-outlay  line.^ 

The  significant  generalization  which  emerges  from  consideration  of 
cases  of  this  sort  is  that  in  any  location  decision  the  scale  of  output  is 
one  of  several  basic,  interdependent  variables.  As  scale  varies,  so  may 
the  substitution  points  between  any  pair  of  transport  outlays,  between 
any  two  sets  of  outlays,  between  outlays  and  revenues,  and  so  forth. ^ 

5  Hoover's  neat  discussion  {op.  cit.,  pp.  99-104)  of  the  factors  governing  the 
location  of  marketing  and  other  intermediary  estabhshments  presents  another 
variation  on  this  theme.  He  focuses  upon  three  basic  elements:  (1)  costs  of 
transport  (transfer)  from  the  factory;  (2)  costs  of  operation  of  the  intermediary 
establishment;  and  (3)  costs  of  transport  (transfer)  to  the  consumer.  His  diagram 
illustrates  how  production  (operation)  outlays  substitute  for  transport  outlays  as 
one  shifts  the  intermediary  establishment  to  successive  transport  junction  points 
along  the  path  from  the  factory  to  the  consumer.  At  the  same  time  it  illustrates 
the  concomitant  substitution  of  transport  outlays  (inputs)  on  the  unprocessed 
commodity  for  transport  outlays  (inputs)  on  the  finished  commodity. 

6  In  the  case  depicted  by  Fig.  30,  we  considered  two  firms,  a  given  linear  dis- 
tribution of  consumers,  and  a  fixed  pattern  of  raw  material  supply.  The  relation 
between  scale  and  location,  however,  can  be  illustrated  in  any  number  of  ways. 
To  take  another  example  suppose  we  consider  a  single  firm  to  whom  the  market 
and  raw  materials  supply  are  variables,  as  well  as  scale.  For  a  predetermined  rate 
of  output,  an  optimum  site  may  be  identified  with  which  is  associated  an  equi- 
librium relation  between,  let  us  say,  transport  outlays  to  the  west  and  transport 
outlays  to  the  east.  For  a  larger  scale  of  output  the  resources  from  a  different 
source  of  a  vital  input  may  be  required — a  source,  say,  which  lies  further  eastward 
— because  the  other  source  is  taxed  to  capacity,  or  because  a  step-up  in  output  at 
the  original  source  involves  such  steeply  rising  costs  that  it  becomes  feasible  to 
commence  exploiting  a  more  distant  source.  Or,  perhaps  for  a  larger  scale  of 
output,  a  larger  supply  area  of  raw  materials  is  required,  one  more  easily  expanded 
in  the  east  because  of  certain  natural  conditions.  Or,  perhaps  the  larger  market 
area  which  the  enterprise  contemplates  serving  extends  much  farther  to  the  east 
than  to  the  west  of  the  original  site.  An  obvious  conclusion  follows.  Total  trans- 
port charges  will  increase,  and  if  the  site  of  production  remains  unchanged,  most 
of  this  increase  will  be  accounted  for  by  greater  transport  outlays  to  the  east. 


176  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

This  point  is  widely  accepted  and  recognized,  and  reflects  the  fact  that 
the  phase  of  agglomeration  theory  which  treats  economies  of  scale  is 
already  embraced  by  existing  production  theory.  It  is  easily  incor- 
porated into  substitutional  location  analysis. 

2.     Localization  Economies 

A  more  controversial  issue  in  agglomeration  theory  revolves  around 
the  influence  of  localization  economies.  Weber  raised  this  question 
early.  Without  clearly  distinguishing  among  the  three  different  types 
of  agglomeration  factors  already  noted,  he  asks  under  what  conditions 
and  where  several  units  of  production  will  agglomerate.  He  provides 
precise  answers  to  these  questions.  Several  individual  units  of  produc- 
tion will  agglomerate  when  (in  relation  to  any  assumed  unit  of  agglom- 
eration):    (1)    their  critical  isodapanes'''   intersect  and    (2)    together 

However,  there  will  be  a  tendency  for  transport  outlays  to  the  west  to  be  sub- 
stituted for  transport  outlays  to  the  east,  that  is,  for  the  firm  to  shift  its  location 
eastward  in  order  to  lower  total  transport  outlays. 

It  should  be  observed  that  such  a  shift  of  site  can  involve  a  considerable  spatial 
jump.  For  example,  until  a  certain  size  of  output  is  reached,  a  dominant  raw 
material  may  be  supplied  by  a  single  source  so  that  the  site  of  production  is  at 
that  source.  With  a  larger  output  it  may  become  feasible,  as  we  have  seen,  to 
utilize  a  second  source  of  the  raw  material  and  thus  to  locate  at  an  intermediate 
site  between  the  two  sources.  Or  it  may  be  that  with  the  larger  output  the  raw 
material  loses  its  dominance  and  production  becomes  market-oriented  or  is  most 
suitably  located  within  the  locational  polygon  of  raw  material  sources  and  market 
points.  Or  it  is  conceivable  that  up  to  a  certain  output  production  is  essentially 
transport-oriented,  i.e.,  carried  on  at  the  minimum  transport  cost  point.  But  with 
a  larger  output  a  cheap  labor  location,  or  a  cheap  power  location,  etc.,  becomes 
effective  in  attracting  production  to  itself.  Again  all  these  conditions  can  be 
formally  presented  in  terms  of  substitution  and  transformation  lines  which  embrace 
all  scales  of  output  in  order  to  point  up  the  interrelation  of  scale  and  location. 

It  is  also  apparent  that  the  question  of  the  most  efficient  size  of  output  to  a 
large  extent  depends  on  the  manner  in  which  sources  of  raw  materials  and  other 
inputs  are  exploitable  and  markets  for  finished  goods  available  both  in  terms  of 
their  spatial  distribution  and  their  quantitative  importance.  And  in  turn  the 
scale  variable  influences  to  a  major  degree  the  specific  sources  of  raw  materials 
utilized  and  the  specific  markets  served. 

7  In  this  connection  the  critical  isodapane  for  any  unit  of  production  is  that 
locus  of  points  for  each  of  which  transport  costs  in  assembhng  the  raw  materials 
and  shipping  the  finished  product  exceed  the  corresponding  transport  costs  asso- 
ciated with  the  optimal  transport  point  by  a  constant  amount.  This  amount  is 
equal  to  the  economies  of  agglomeration  that  would  be  realized  by  association 
with  the  assumed  unit  of  agglomeration. 

See  Weber  for  extensive  discussion  of  the  critical  isodapane  and  of  its  depend- 
ence upon  locational  weight,  transport  rates,  the  function  of  economy  of  agglom- 
eration, and  other  variables. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     177 

they  attain  within  the   common  segment  the  requisite   quantity  of 
production. 

Suppose  three  units  of  production,  Pj,  P2,  and  P3,  each  transport- 
oriented,  are  located  as  in  Fig.  32.    Around  each  are  drawn  its  locational 


Fig.  32.     Non-intersecting  critical  isodapanes:   no  agglomeration. 

figure  and  critical  isodapane.  The  critical  isodapanes  do  not  intersect. 
Agglomeration  is  infeasible.  In  contrast  stands  the  situation  depicted 
by  Fig.  33  where  these  same  three  units  are  assumed  initially  to  lie 
closer  to  one  another.  Here,  their  critical  isodapanes,  the  heavy 
undashed  circles,  do  intersect.  (For  the  present,  ignore  the  dashed 
circles).  A  la  Weber,  agglomeration  will  take  place  at  a  site  within 
the  common  segment  which  is  shaded. 

Weber's  determination  of  the  center  of  agglomeration  is  as  precise 
as  his  statement  of  conditions  under  which  agglomeration  will  occur. 
The  center  of  agglomeration  "will  be  located  at  that  one  of  the  several 


178 


LOCATION  AKD  SPACE-ECONOMY 


possible  points  of  agglomeration  which  has  the  lowest  transportation 
costs  in  relation  to  the  total  agglomerated  output.''^  This  point  is 
derived  by  means  of  a  locational  figure  and  analysis  of  the  equilibrium 
of  forces  in  much  the  same  way  as  is  the  optimal  transport  point 


Fig.  33.    Intersecting  critical  isodapanes:  agglomeration. 


for  any  given  unit  of  production.  However,  in  the  derivation  of  this 
point,  Weber  permits  the  use  of  new  sources  of  raw  material  supplies 
(replacement  deposits)   for  each  unit  of  production. 

Weber  gives  a  precise  answer  also  to  the  question  of  the  size  of  the 
unit  of  agglomeration  to  which  each  unit  of  production  will  be  at- 
tracted. Each  unit  of  production  will  select  that  unit  of  agglomeration 
whose  center  lies  most  distant  from  the  relevant  critical  isodapane 
of  the  given  unit  of  production. 

Weber's  analysis  is  not  unsophisticated.  He  does  consider  for  each 
unit  of  production  a  function  of  economy  of  agglomeration  which 
varies  with  the  size  of  agglomeration.     He  admits  exceptions  to  his 

8  Friedrich,  o-p.  cit.,  p.  138. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     179 

conditions  under  which  agglomeration  will  be  precipitated.  ^  He 
emphasizes  labor  locations  as  centers  of  agglomerations,  where  both 
cheap  labor  and  agglomeration  economies  are  obtainable,  and  intro- 
duces various  realities  into  his  analysis.  i<^  Nonetheless  it  must  be 
said  that  Weber's  schema  has  limited  application,  especially  in  under- 
standing the  forces  which  determine  the  site  at  which  agglomeration 
obtains  in  actuality. 

Imagine  an  entrepreneur  who  controls  three  units  of  production  and 
who  confronts  the  location  problem,  de  novo.  Considering  the  locational 
polygon  of  raw  material  sources  and  markets  relevant  for  each  unit 
and  assuming  that  economies  of  scale  are  not  operative,  he  could 
locate  each  unit  at  its  optimal  transport  point.  Or,  he  could  locate 
the  three  units  adjacent  to  each  other  at  a  center  of  agglomeration, 
thereby  achieving  localization  economies  but  only  by  incurring  larger 
transportation  costs.  This  is  one  type  of  situation  to  which  Weber's 
schema  has  most  application.  In  this  type  of  situation,  each  unit 
of  production  may  be  visualized  as  substituting  transport  outlays  for 
production  outlays  of  one  sort  or  another  when  it  shifts  to  the  center 
of  agglomeration.  And  in  this  sense,  that  phase  of  agglomeration 
theory  which  concerns  localization  economies  could  be  integrated  into 
our  substitutional  framework  just  as  we  have  integrated  that  phase  of 
agglomeration  theory  which  concerns  economies  of  scale.  ^ 

^  For  example,  the  critical  isodapane  of  a  given  unit  of  production  may  not 
quite  reach  the  common  segment  formed  by  the  intersection  of  the  critical 
isodapanes  of  other  units.  Nevertheless,  if  the  given  unit's  production  is  neces- 
sary for  the  group  to  attain  the  requisite  total  of  production  and  if  other  units 
would  enjoy  sizable  economies  from  agglomeration,  the  given  unit  of  production 
can  be  induced  to  shift  to  the  potential  center  of  agglomeration  by  some  form 
of  subsidy  or  side  payment. 

10  As  with  the  analyses  of  other  location  factors,  it  is  not  our  intention  to  present 
here  these  more  sophisticated  aspects  of  Weber's  analysis  nor  to  study  the 
agglomeration  factor  in  full.  Rather,  we  touch  upon  it  to  the  extent  necessary 
to  integrate  it  with  our  general  location  analysis  and  other  existing  theories. 
The  reader  is  referred  to  other  studies  for  more  comprehensive  and  detailed 
treatments  of  the  agglomeration  and  deglomeration  variables.  He  can  easily 
graft  these  more  extensive  treatments  onto  the  analysis  presented  in  this  chapter. 

11  Palander  contends  that  where  the  several  units  of  production  are  controlled 
by  one  firm,  the  localization  economies  problem  disappears.  According  to 
Palander,  the  firm  confronts  a  scale  problem;  it  must  determine  the  amounts  of 
production  to  engage  in  at  various  locations.  In  any  case,  however  one  views 
the  problem,  the  substitutional  framework  applies. 

The  reader  should  also  bear  in  mind  that  as  soon  as  Weber  considers  centers 
of  agglomeration  where  several  units  of  production  locate,  his  assumptions  of 
fixed  raw  material  prices,  transport  rates,  wages,  and  other  costs  are  less  valid 
than  when  only  one  unit  of  production  is  associated  with  a  given  site. 


180  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

However,  as  Engliinder  and  Palander  have  rightly  indicated  in  their 
sharp  criticism  of  Weber's  agglomeration  theory,  this  type  of  situation 
is  not  widely  characteristic  of  reality.  Societal  development  is  an 
historical  process.  At  any  given  point  of  time  there  exists  an  in- 
herited physical  structural  framework.  Plants  have  already  been 
erected  and  are  producing.  To  relocate  these  plants  involves  oppor- 
tunity costs  since  one  would  forego  the  use  of  facilities  forced  into 
obsolescence.  Critics  of  Weber  have  therefore  emphasized  the  ad- 
vantages of  existing  production  points  as  centers  of  agglomeration, 
whether  they  reflect  labor  or  any  other  form  of  orientation.  As  new 
units  of  production  come  into  existence,  they  will  tend  to  gain  localiza- 
tion economies  by  agglomerating  around  established  production  points. 
Thereby  they  frequently  strengthen  the  gravitational  pull  of  these 
points.  From  this  standpoint,  the  evolutionary  framework  becomes 
critical  as  a  locational  factor;  and  any  pure  substitutional  theory 
which  is  not  linked  to  specific  regional  structure  is  of  severely  limited 
significance. 

Moreover,  even  if  the  opportunity  costs  of  relocation  could  be 
ignored  and  plants  were  completely  mobile,  the  problem  is  not  as 
simple  as  Weber  depicted.  In  shifting  to  a  center  of  agglomeration,  it 
is  to  the  advantage  of  each  unit  of  production  to  deviate  as  little  as 
possible  from  its  optimal  transport  site.  At  the  same  time,  the 
managers  of  these  units  of  production  differ  in  bargaining  ability. 
Therefore,  it  is  to  be  expected  that  the  center  of  agglomeration  will 
not  be  at  the  over-all  minimum  transport  cost  point  of  a  new  over-all 
locational  polygon;  rather,  it  will  tend  to  lie  within  the  common 
segment  closer  to  the  firms  with  greater  bargaining  ability.  It  could 
even  lie  at  a  point  outside  the  common  segment  if  an  appropriate  set 
of  side  payments  were  made  to  firms  who  could  not  otherwise  be 
induced  to  agglomerate.  And,  if  costs  of  relocation  are  reintroduced 
into  the  problem,  the  center  of  agglomeration  could  lie  at  the  site  of  an 
already  existing  production  point.  Since  this  would  eliminate  one 
group  of  relocation  costs,  in  many  situations  each  unit  of  production 
could  be  made  better  off  through  an  appropriate  set  of  side  payments 
than  if  all  were  to  shift  to  Weber's  over-all  transport  optimal  point. 

Clearly,  game  theory  strikes  at  the  heart  of  this  latter  type  of 
situation.  The  several  participants  are  the  several  units  of  pro- 
duction. Whether  they  be  new  units  with  whom  no  relocation  costs 
are  associated  or  existing  units  confronted  with  relocation  costs,  they 
interact  engaging  in  various  forms  of  collusive  action.  The  bargain- 
ing which  ensues  is  complicated  not  only  because  of  the  innumerable 
coalitions  which  are  possible  but  also  because  of  the  different  scales  of 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     181 

agglomeration  which  are  potentially  feasible  for  each  unit  of  produc- 
tion. 12  As  with  the  Hotelling  and  similar  locational  equilibrium 
problems  examined  in  the  previous  chapter,  progress  in  this  phase  of 
agglomeration  theory  and  its  incorporation  into  existing  forms  of 
analysis  must  await  further  development  of  game  theory. 

From  an  entirely  different  standpoint,  however,  Weber's  agglomera- 
tion theory  may  be  justly  defended.  Suppose  a  new  area  is  to  be 
opened  for  development  by  a  governmental  planning  authority.  Tech- 
nological and  other  factors  dictate,  for  any  given  commodity,  the  range 
of  feasible  scales  for  the  units  of  production.     Should  these  units 

12  To  spell  out  somewhat  more  the  way  in  which  game  theory  pertains  to  this 
phase  of  agglomeration  theory,  imagine  there  are  three  units  of  production 
(parties)  placed  as  in  Fig.  33.  Their  critical  isodapanes  intersect  with  respect 
to  two  sizes  of  agglomeration.  (We  already  oversimplify  the  problem  by  con- 
sidering only  two  sizes.)  The  critical  isodapanes  relevant  for  the  smaller  unit 
of  agglomeration  are  the  dashed  circles;  those  relevant  for  the  larger  unit  are  the 
undashed  circles.  Any  two  parties  could  agglomerate  to  form  the  smaller  unit 
of  agglomeration.  The  third  party  would  consequently  gain  nothing.  It  is  there- 
fore to  his  advantage  to  encourage  the  formation  of  the  larger  unit  of  agglomera- 
tion in  which  he  could  participate  and  from  which  he  could  reap  gain.  Leaving 
aside  the  determination  of  which  party  is  the  third  party,  we  encounter  the 
problem  of  identifying  types  of  collusive  actions  which  might  develop.  Whom 
will  the  third  party  approach  to  form  a  coalition?  To  make  an  effective  approach 
he  must  offer  a  gain  to  the  co-operating  (second)  party  which  will  be  greater  than 
what  the  latter  obtains  in  the  smaller  unit  of  agglomeration.  The  third  party  may 
offer  a  side  payment.  Or  he  may  propose  to  agglomerate  at  a  site  closer  to  the 
second  party's  initial  location  (optimal  transport  point) ;  this  proposal  may,  or 
may  not,  be  contingent  upon  the  participation  of  the  remaining  (first)  party. 
Or  the  second  party  may  be  strong  enough  to  force  agglomeration  at  his  own 
optimal  transport  point,  provided  the  first  and  third  parties  reap  gain  either 
directly  or  indirectly  through  side  payments.  However,  the  first  party  cannot 
be  presumed  to  be  an  inactive  participant.  His  power,  like  the  power  of  any  of 
the  other  two  parties,  rests  in  the  fact  that  without  his  co-operation  the  additional 
gains  of  the  larger  unit  of  agglomeraion  are  not  possible.  He  too  has  bargaining 
power  and  can  be  presumed  to  exercise  it. 

Costs  of  relocation  complicate  the  problem  still  more  by  altering  the  proba- 
bilities of  diverse  moves.  They  significantly  affect  the  range  of  collusive  action. 
Furthermore,  the  problem  as  presented  is  not  a  constant-sum  game.  As  Weber 
demonstrates,  there  is  a  center,  the  over-all  optimal  transport  point,  at  which 
agglomeration  can  proceed  with  a  minimum  addition  to  the  sum  of  the  transporta- 
tion costs  of  all  parties.  Any  deviation  from  this  point  reduces  the  "surplus"  or 
"net  gain"  to  be  apportioned  among  the  participants.  In  certain  situations  it  may 
therefore  be  useful  to  introduce  a  fourth  participant,  a  dummy,  in  order  to 
convert  the  problem  into  a  constant-sum  or  zero-sum  game.  This  entails  further 
complexities,  as  well  as  does  any  variation  from  the  symmetrical  situation 
presented,  such  as  with  respect  to  initial  geographic  positions,  size  of  output  of 
each  unit  of  production,  ability  to  relocate  as  measured  by  opportunity  costs, 
and  so  forth. 


182  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

be  agglomerated  to  realize  localization  economies,  or  should  they  be 
spatially  disconnected  in  order  to  reduce  transportation  costs?  From 
this  social  welfare  approach,  irrationalities  and  differences  among 
managers  in  bargaining  ability  do  not  enter  the  problem.  Nor  do 
inherited  physical  structures.  The  localization  economies  achievable 
at  Weber's  over-all  transport  optimal  point  (and  not  at  any  other 
point)  must  be  compared  with  the  additional  transport  outlays  occa- 
sioned by  agglomeration  at  this  point.  Moreover,  this  social  welfare 
approach  implicit  in  Weber,  though  not  generally  realistic,  provides 
a  useful  guidepost;  in  certain  contexts  it  can  indicate  directions  in 
which  existing  structure  should  be  transformed  in  order  to  approach 
optimum  resource  utilization.  Hence,  from  these  standpoints,  too, 
the  Weberian  agglomeration  theory  is  relevant,  i^  and  likewise  the 
substitutional  locational  framework  within  which  it  fits. 

3.     Urbanization  Economies 

The  third  phase  of  agglomeration  theory,  which  concerns  urbaniza- 
tion economies,  is  in  as  unsatisfactory  a  state  as  that  phase  which 
treats  localization  economies.  This  is  to  be  expected  to  some  extent 
since  the  analysis  of  urbanization  economies  can  be  said:  (1)  to  re- 
semble, or  (2)  partially  to  evolve  from,  or  (3)  even  to  contain,  accord- 
ing to  some  persons,  the  analysis  of  localization  economies,  i-* 

In  the  previous  section  we  did  not  specify  types  of  localization 
economies  (and  diseconomies)  which  arise,  such  as  those  associated 
with  access  to  a  larger  pool  of  skilled  labor,  with  fuller  use  of  spe- 
cialized and  auxiliary  industrial  and  repair  facilities,  with  large-lot 
buying  and  selling  through  common  brokers  and  jobbers.  We  at- 
tacked the  problem  as  if  these  economies  were  known  and  furnished 
us  in  the  form  of  a  function  of  economy  of  agglomeration  (a  la 
Weber).  In  the  study  of  urbanization  economies  we  face  all  these 
in  a  broader  context  as  well  as,  among  others:  (1)  economies  which 
stem  from  a  higher  level  of  use  of  the  general  apparata  of  an  urban 
structure  (such  as  transportation  facilities,  gas  and  water  mains,  and 
the  like)  and  from  a  finer  articulation  of  economic  activities  (daily, 

13  Critics  of  Weber's  agglomeration  theory  are  too  often  inclined  to  forget  that 
in  his  Vber  den  Standort  der  Industrien  Weber  seeks  a  "pure"  theory  such  as  one 
which  is  relevant  for  social  planning  rather  than  a  "realistic"  theory  wherein 
institutional  forces  are  duly  considered. 

14  The  discerning  reader  may  have  already  concluded  that  in  several  respects 
there  is  also  only  a  fine  line  of  distinction  between  localization  economies  and 
economies  of  scale.  He  may  have  observed  for  example  that  the  figures  used  in 
connection  with  the  discussion  of  economies  of  scale  are  also  relevant,  with 
appropriate  changes  in  initial  premises,  for  inquiry  into  localization  economies. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     183 

seasonally,  and  interindustrially)  ;  and  (2)  diseconomies  engendered 
by  rises  in  the  cost  of  living  and  money  wages,  in  the  costs  of  local 
materials  produced  under  conditions  of  diminishing  returns,  in  time- 
cost  and  other  costs  of  transportation,  and  in  land  values  and  rents. 
Consequently,  we  can  theoretically  employ  the  approach  linked  to 
critical  isodapanes,  as  developed  in  the  preceding  section,  for  the 
investigation  of  the  impact  of  at  least  some  of  these  urbanization 
economies  and  diseconomies.  Here,  the  units  of  production  need  not 
engage  in  the  same  type  of  activity. 

In  this  general  sense  little  can  be  added  to  the  existing  state  of 
analysis.  It  can  be  presumed  that  Weber's  approach  would  have  still 
less  application  here  than  in  the  treatment  of  localization  economies. 
Cities  evolve  over  time.  They  are  much  less  subject  to  relocation 
than  are  individual  units  of  production.  To  put  it  another  way,  the 
accumulated  fixed  investments  of  an  urban  mass  in  conjunction  with 
its  vested  social  institutions  entail  major  geographic  immobilities  and 
rigidities  and,  for  the  most  part,  tend  to  preclude  urban  relocation. 
Cities  attract  or  repel  units  of  production  in  accordance  with  the 
urbanization  (for  the  most  part,  external)  economies  or  diseconomies 
relevant  to  each  unit  of  production.  In  this  sense,  one  concludes 
that  agglomeration  analysis,  particularly  that  of  the  substitutional 
variety,  has  little  to  say  beyond  the  obvious;  units  are  attracted  to 
or  repelled  from  cities  according  to  a  simple  comparison  of  advantages 
and  disadvantages  generated  by  these  cities. 

However,  it  is  instructive  to  pursue  a  tangential  extension  of  the 
above  discussion.  Once  more  we  pose  the  following  problem.  A  new 
area  is  to  be  developed.  Given  a  full  knowledge  of  existing  tech- 
nology and  likely  changes  in  this  technology,  of  the  human  and 
natural  resources  of  the  area,  and  of  other  relevant  relations  and 
materials,  how  should  one  plan  a  net  of  cities  for  this  area?  What 
is  the  optimum  spatial  distribution  and  hierarchy  of  cities  of  different 
sizes?  Within  each  urban-metropolitan  region  what  is  the  best  spatial 
distribution  of  different  types  of  satellite  cities  and  centers?  Within 
each  city  what  is  the  most  desirable  constellation  of  community  and 
neighborhood  sites  of  various  sorts?  In  what  ways  should  the  inten- 
sities of  land  use  and  traffic  generation  be  controlled  to  be  consistent 
with  an  optimum  structure  of  cities? 

Closely  allied  with  the  above  theoretical  questions  is  a  more 
practical  one.  Given  a  network  of  cities  and  corresponding  patterns 
of  land  use,  along  what  channels  should  changes  in  the  structure  of 
this  network  and  these  patterns  be  fostered  in  order  to  attain  a  situa- 
tion closer  to  optimum?    Since  cities  are  conglomerations  of  economic 


184 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


activities,  in  what  directions  should  the  joint  geographic  distribution 
of  economic  activities  be  reshuffled  when  flexibility  in  the  structure 
exists? 

At  this  point,  only  a  meager  beginning  can  be  made  at  answers  to 
these  basic  questions,  which  have  already  been  posed  several  times, 
either  implicitly  or  explicitly.  To  start  exploratory  analysis,  let  there 
be  given  the  economies  of  scale  associated  with  every  utility  and 
service  which  a  city  provides  and  with  every  other  activity  or  service 


1,000 
350 


10,000 
3,750 


100,000 
40,000 


Population 
Kw  capacity 


Fig.  34.    Economies  of  scale  in  power  generation  with  urban  size. 


subject  to  urbanization  economies  or  diseconomies.  Let  us  focus  first 
upon  the  economies  and  diseconomies  associated  with  the  provision  of 
electric  power.  To  do  so  we  have  constructed  Fig.  34.  Along  the 
vertical  axis  we  measure  net  economies  (economies  less  diseconomies) 
in  power  generation.  Along  the  horizontal  axis  we  measure  both  scale 
of  output  and  the  corresponding  size  of  city  which  can  absorb  any  scale 
of  output.  We  posit  more  or  less  representative  cities  for  each  of 
which  an  approximate  level  of  power  output  can  be  identified.  (In 
reality,  of  course,  the  power  consumption  of  any  city  is  a  function 
of  many  characteristics;  and  consequently  the  kilowatt-hour  require- 
ments of  any  two  cities  of  the  same  size  can  differ  widely.)  We  also 
postulate  that  fuel  of  stated  BTU  quality  is  available  to  all  sizes  of 
cities  at  a  fixed  price  or  at  prices  which  are  a  function  of  quantity 
of  purchase  but  not  of  geographic  position ;i5  and  that  for  each  scale  of 
output  the  most  efficient  power  plant  design  is  in  effect.  Excess  capac- 
ity beyond  that  necessitated  by  peak  load  requirement    (which  is 

15  Hence,  all  cities  are  taken  to  be  equally  distant  from  a  fuel  source. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     185 

taken  to  exceed  average  load  by  a  uniform  percentage  in  all  cities)  does 
not  exist.  16 

Given  these  assumptions,  Fig.  34  indicates  annual  net  economies 
in  power  generation  which  would  be  realized  if  any  given  size  of 
population  together  with  its  associated  industrial  and  commercial 
activities  were  concentrated  in  one  city  rather  than  in  cities  of  1000 
population  each.^'''  The  solid  curve  refers  to  a  situation  in  which 
the  cities  of  1000  each  would  be  too  distant  from  one  another  to  permit 
service  by  one  or  a  relatively  few  power  stations.  The  dashed  curve 
refers  to  a  situation  in  which  the  cities  of  1000  each  would  be 
sufficiently  close  to  permit  some  integration  in  power  production  and 
service.  18  Obviously,  a  set  of  curves  can  be  constructed  to  depict 
different  degrees  of  integration  which  might  be  feasible. 

For  every  other  service  and  commodity  whose  production  or  cost 
reflects  urbanization  economies  and  diseconomies,  we  can  construct  a 
similar  set  of  net  economy  curves  when  appropriate  assumptions  are 
stipulated.  One  set  would  reflect  in  the  early  stage  of  each  curve 
the  general  economies  which  arise  from  access  to  larger  and  more 
diversified  pools  of  skilled  labor,  and  in  a  later  stage  the  diseconomies 
in  the  use  of  labor  which  stem  from  internal  congestion  and  inefficiency 
(the  journey-to-work  problem),  increases  in  money  wages,  and  other 
factors  as  the  urban  mass  multiplies.  Another  set  would  reflect 
economies  and  diseconomies  in  the  operation  of  an  urban  transportation 
system  (including  streets,  rail  and  truck  terminals,  parking  facilities 
as  well  as  bus,  subway,  street  and  electric  railway,  and  other  transit 
media)  or  of  a  subset  of  the  transportation  system  if  an  identifiable 
subset  of  the  transportation  system  can  be  meaningfully  isolated  for 
study.  In  reality  the  size  and  character  of  urban  transportation 
systems  vary  with  the  spatial  distribution  of  population,  of  economic, 
cultural,  and  other  activities  within  the  city,  with  patterns  of  group 
behavior  and  social  organization,  with  topography  and  other  geo- 
graphic features,  with  the  state  of  technology,  and  with  many  other 
factors.     However,  we  postulate  that  it  is  possible  to  associate  at 

18  Already  the  reader  may  seriously  object  to  the  set  of  postulates  adopted 
whereby  cities  are  standardized  in  terms  of  power  consumption,  price  of  fuel, 
and  other  factors. 

1'^  In  Fig.  34  we  depict  increasing  per  capita  consumption  of  power  in  all  uses 
with  increase  in  size  of  city  in  order  to  reflect  the  effect  upon  power  consumption 
of  the  lower  power  rates  which  larger  cities  tend  to  charge  because  of  lower  unit 
power  costs.    The  kilowatt  capacity  scale  has  specific  reference  to  the  solid  curve. 

18  Both  curves  fall  off  slightly  after  a  certain  size  of  city  is  reached  because  of 
slowly  mounting  diseconomies  in  the  co-ordination  and  management  of  larger  and 
larger  power  systems. 


186  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

least  approximately  a  size  and  character  of  transportation  system 
with  each  size  of  city,  and  that  the  difficult  problem  of  defining 
a  unit  of  transportation  service  can  be  surmounted. ^^  Each  curve 
in  the  resulting  set  of  net  economy  curves  would  rise  to  a  maximum  and 
then  fall  significantly  as  deglomerative  forces,  such  as  congestion  and 
co-ordination  problems,  grow  in  relative  importance. 

Still  other  sets  of  curves  would  depict  economies  and  diseconomies  in 
the  performance  of  various  municipal  functions:  in  the  provision  of 
fire  and  police  protection;  in  the  administration  and  operation  of  an 
educational  system;  in  the  construction  and  maintenance  of  gas,  water, 
and  sanitation  facilities;  in  the  organization  and  supply  of  recreational 
facilities  and  services;  and  in  other  activities.  Here,  too,  as  population 
numbers  increase,  as  congestion  multiplies,  as  rents,  land  values,  and 
the  costs  of  food  supply  rise,  diseconomies  mount  in  relative  importance. 
Imagine  that  somehow  or  other  it  is  possible  a  priori  to  identify  for 
any  large  region,  either  already  settled  or  about  to  be  settled,  that 
curve  in  each  set  of  net  economy  curves  which  tends  to  be  most 
relevant  or  representative  for  the  situation  under  study.  These  curves 
(one  from  each  set)  could  be  plotted  as  in  Fig.  35,  where  only  four  of 
them  have  been  constructed.  It  is  tempting  to  sum  all  these  curves 
and  to  interpret  the  resulting  total  curve  as  an  over-all  index  of 
economy  or  function  of  economy  which  defines  the  over-all  urbaniza- 
tion economies  and  diseconomies  associated  with  cities  of  different 
sizes.  Unfortunately,  this  is  not  justifiable.  There  are  many  logical 
objections  to  this  procedure. 

To  reiterate  a  point  already  mentioned,  the  standardization  of  cities 
is  subject  to  serious  criticism.  There  are  no  standard  cities.  Each 
is  unique.  Furthermore,  the  selection  of  a  relevant  or  representative 
curve  from  any  given  set  of  net  economy  curves  presents  logical 
difficulties  of  a  somewhat  similar  nature.  It  is  unnecessary  to  spell 
out  these  fairly  obvious  points. 

Additionally,  there  are  a  number  of  other  objections  of  which  at 
least  two  should  be  explicitly  mentioned.  One  involves  the  problem 
of  weighting.  Summing  the  individual  curves  of  Fig.  35  to  derive 
the  total  curve  depicted  thereon  implies  that  the  sets  of  economies  are 
of  equal  importance.  Yet  it  is  clearly  evident  that  the  relative  im- 
portance of  any  set  of  economies  depends  upon  many  characteristics 
of  a  given  situation;  among  others,  industrial  composition,  income, 

19  In  effect,  we  standardize  cities  in  terms  of:  (1)  the  ratio  of  industrial  activity 
to  commercial  and  service  activities;  (2)  industrial  mix  (heavy  and  light)  and 
composition  of  commercial  and  service  activities;  (3)  land-use  patterns;  (4) 
journey-to-work  and  commodity  flow  configurations;  and  many  other  relations. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     187 

culture  and  social  organization,  consumption  patterns,  and  geographic 
setting.  In  a  situation  where  cities  are,  or  are  likely  to  be,  charac- 
terized by  a  heavy  proportion  of  electro-process  activities  within 
their  basic  industry  sectors,  greater  significance  should  be  attached 
to  the  power  economy  curves,  ceteris  paribus.     In  another  situation 


Total  economies 


Transportation  economies 
__^JV— Labor  economies 


1,000  10,000  100,000  1,000,000      ^ 

Population 


Fig.  35.    Hypothetical  economies  of  scale  with  urban  size. 


\ 


\ 


where  general  urban  settlement  is  severely  restricted  by  mountainous 
slopes,  ocean,  and  other  barriers,  the  transportation  economy  curves 
assume  greater  relative  importance,  ceteris  paribus.  Thus,  some  form 
of  weighting  must  be  introduced  into  the  problem  in  a  valid  analytical 
manner. 

Another  objection,  perhaps  the  most  serious  of  all,  stems  from  the 
neglect  of  interdependence  among  the  sets  of  net  economy  curves 
(as  well  as  interurban  and  urban-rural  interrelations) .  Economies  in 
urban  transit  are  directly  related  to  economies  in  power  generation 
since  considerable  power  is  consumed  in  street  and  electric  railways 


188  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

and  other  transit  facilities.  In  turn,  economies  in  power  generation 
are  directly  related  to  economies  in  the  operation  of  port  and  rail 
facilities  since  a  significant  fraction  of  the  delivered  price  of  fuel 
may  consist  of  transportation  charges.  Economies  and  diseconomies 
in  the  educational  system,  in  the  provision  of  fire  and  police  protec- 
tion, and  in  various  other  municipal  services  are  also  directly  in- 
fluenced by  the  character  and  efficiency  of  the  transportation  system. 
Likewise,  labor  economies  and  diseconomies  are  related  to  a  number 
of  other  sets  of  economies  and  diseconomies.  In  short,  it  is  erroneous 
to  consider  the  various  economies  and  diseconomies  associated  with 
the  numerous  urban  activities  as  simply  additive.  Rather,  they  are 
multiplicative  in  a  complex  fashion. 

The  above  considerations  are  sufficient  in  themselves  to  invalidate 
the  use,  even  in  an  approximative  fashion,  of  a  simple  total  curve 
or  index  of  economies  and  diseconomies  in  the  functioning  of  cities 
of  various  sizes.  The  construction  of  Fig.  35  does  not  answer  the  basic 
questions  posed  earlier  in  this  section;  nor  does  it  cast  significant 
light  upon  the  third  phase  of  agglomeration  theory,  which  is  con- 
cerned with  urbanization  economies  and  diseconomies.  We  are  still 
thrown  back  upon  the  simple  statement  that,  with  respect  to  each 
firm,  there  are  attracting  and  repelling  forces  for  location  in  rural 
areas  and  in  cities  of  different  sizes.  When  the  potential  savings  of 
a  location  shift  override  the  additional  costs  involved,  the  firm  will 
shift.  In  doing  so  it  will  be  substituting  one  set  of  outlays  and 
revenues  for  another  set.  (And,  as  already  indicated,  in  the  presenta- 
tion of  this  problem  the  critical  isodapane  techniques,  a  la  Weber,  are 
helpful  only  to  a  limited  extent.) 

Nonetheless,  it  seems  worthwhile  to  explore  further  the  above 
approach  in  the  analysis  of  urbanization  economies  and  diseconomies. 
In  a  future  volume,  which  will  place  chief  emphasis  upon  regional 
analysis,  it  will  be  shown  how  within  urban-metropolitan  regions  some 
of  the  complex  interdependence  of  the  sets  of  net  economy  curves  can 
be  understood  and  partially  identified  in  quantitative  terms.  Yet,  this 
interdependence  problem,  together  with  the  probleras  of  weighting 
and  of  introducing  flexibility  and  non-standardization  into  the  ap- 
proach, is  of  tremendous  scope  and  requires  a  large  amount  of 
additional  research. 

4.     Agricultural  Location  Theory 

As  indicated  at  the  beginning  of  Chap.  5,  there  is  a  traditional 
dualism  in  location  theory — viz.,  a  Thiinen  type  of  analysis  for  the 
agricultural  sphere  and  a  Weberian  scheme  for  the  industrial.    His- 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     189 

torically,  the  former  has  confined  itself  to  an  aggregative  analysis;  the 
latter  primarily  to  individual  firm  analysis.  Since  these  two  schools 
have  been  concerned  with  two  different  levels  of  inquiry,  it  might 
appear,  as  it  has  to  some  in  the  past,  that  their  doctrines  are  non- 
integrable.  It  might  seem  illogical  to  discuss  agricultural  location 
theory  in  a  section  of  a  chapter  where  the  preceding  sections  have 
centered  primarily  around  the  individual  firm.    However,  we  contend: 

(1)  that  there  is  a  smooth  transition  from  individual  firm  analysis  in 
the  Weberian  sense  to  the  analysis  of  the  individual  farm  enterprise; 

(2)  that  the  analysis  of  the  individual  farm  enterprise  must  investigate 
the  bonds  which  link  the  agricultural  firm  to  the  aggregate  of  agricul- 
tural activities;  and  (3)  that  casting  the  locational  analysis  of  the 
individual  farm  enterprise  against  the  background  of  locational  forces 
which  interplay  on  the  aggregative  level  in  agriculture  can  throw  at 
least  some  light  upon  the  way  location  forces  which  influence  the 
individual  industrial  enterprise  are  interlocked  with  those  governing  the 
spatial  distribution  of  industry  on  a  more  aggregative  level. 20 

The  previous  discussion  has  emphasized  the  distance  variable. 
Transport  inputs  and  transport  outlays  have  been  given  a  focal  position 
in  the  theoretical  scaffolding.  Yet  the  internal  spatial  dimensions  of 
the  firm,  of  industrial  agglomerations,  or  of  urban  aggregates  have 
been  ignored.  On  the  surface,  at  least,  to  ignore  them  was  justifiable 
in  individual  firm  analysis  where  it  was  implicitly  assumed  that  the 
firm  was  associated  with  a  factory-type  operation  whose  requirements 
of  land  were  relatively  small.  Differentials  associated  with  the  cost 
of  land  services  were  taken  to  be  minor  as  they  typically  are  for  most 
industrial  factories.  In  contrast  this  neglect  is  not  justifiable  for 
industrial  agglomerations,  for  cities,  and  for  firms  whose  internal 
spatial  dimensions  are  relatively  large.  These  latter  firms  are  well 
typified  by  agricultural  enterprises. 

In  agricultural  location  theory,  rent  differentials  have  always 
occupied  a  central  position.  Since  the  internal  spatial  extent  of  the 
typical  agricultural  enterprise  is  relatively  large,  differences  in  the 
price  of  land  services  associated  with  different  spatial  positions  (as 
well  as  resource  content)  are  a  major  location  influence.  However, 
to  the  agricultural  enterprise,  the  rent  differential  plays  the  same 
role  as  the  labor  cost  differential  to  an  enterprise  in  an  industry  which 
is  labor  intensive,  or  the  power  cost  differential  to  an  enterprise  in 
an  industry  which  is  power  intensive.    In  the  case  of  the  agricultural 

20  The  imperative  need  to  attack  the  analysis  of  industrial  agglomeration  from 
a  more  aggregative  standpoint  has  already  been  pointed  up  in  the  preceding 
sections. 


190  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

enterprise,  it  is  critical  to  investigate  the  substitution  relation  between 
rent  outlays  and  transport  outlays;  in  the  case  of  textiles,  it  is  im- 
portant to  examine  the  substitution  relation  between  labor  outlays  and 
transport  outlays;  in  the  ease  of  the  aluminum  industry,  between 
power  outlays  and  transport  outlays.  In  this  sense,  location  theory 
for  agricultural  firms  is  no  different  from  that  for  industrial  firms. 
Comparison  of  cost  differentials  and  investigation  of  substitution  re- 
lations among  the  several  outlays  are  basic  to  both.  The  only  signifi- 
cant difference  rests,  it  may  be  contended,  in  the  fact  that  the  small 
character  of  the  many  agricultural  enterprises  cultivating  most  major 
crops  coupled  with  the  concentration  of  markets  at  particular  points 
in  general  permits  a  deeper  locational  analysis  of  the  agricultural 
sphere  than  of  the  industrial.  We  therefore  proceed  to  the  discussion  of 
agricultural  location  theory  as  a  logical  extension  of  the  general 
analytical  framework  evolved  in  the  preceding  pages.  21 

Consider  the  operator  of  an  agricultural  enterprise.  Among  others, 
his  decisions  regarding  the  location  of  his  enterprise  (in  terms  of  dis- 
tance from  the  market),  product (s)  to  be  cultivated,  factor  proportions 
to  be  used,  and  intensity  of  production  are  interrelated.  Some  of  these 
interrelations  can  be  neatly  demonstrated  with  the  use  of  a  set  of  graphs 
developed  by  Dunn. 2 2 

In  Fig.  36  are  presented  a  set  of  price  and  cost  curves  for  the  indi- 
vidual farm  operator.  OE  represents  the  price  at  the  market  for  the 
particular  product  he  cultivates.  OD  represents  the  net  farm  price,  i.e., 
market  price  less  the  cost  to  transport  the  unit  of  product  to  the  market 
which  is  indicated  by  ED.  The  solid  curves,  AC  and  MC,  are  respec- 
tively his  average  and  marginal  cost  curves;  they  exclude  rent  pay- 
ments or  are  relevant  when  the  price  of  land  is  taken  to  be  zero. 

If  the  price  of  land  were  zero,  the  operator  would  extend  output  to 
the  level,  01 1,  at  which  level  marginal  costs  equal  net  farm  price 
(marginal  revenue)  and  where,  ex  definitione,  gross  marginal  costs 
(including  cost  of  transport  to  the  market)  equal  market  price  (gross 

21  In  this  section,  we  shall  treat  only  some  of  the  basic  elements  of  agricultural 
location  theory.  For  a  full  statement,  see  Edgar  S.  Dunn,  The  Location  0}  Agri- 
cultural Production,  University  of  Florida  Press,  Gainesville,  1954;  August  Losch, 
Die  rdumliche  Ordnung  der  Wirtschaft,  G.  Fischer,  Jena,  1944,  pp.  24-44;  E.  M. 
Hoover,  Jr.,  Location  Theory  and  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Industries,  Harvard  Uni- 
versity Press,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1937,  Chap.  2;  E.  T.  Benedict,  et  at.,  Theodor 
Brinkman's  Economics  of  the  Farm  Business,  University  of  California  Press, 
Berkeley,  1935;  F.  Aeroboe,  Allgemeine  landwirtschajtsliche  Betriebslehre,  P. 
Parey,  Berlin,  1923,  and  J.  H.  von  Thiinen,  Der  isolierte  Staat  in  Beziehung  auj 
Landwirtschajt  und  Nationalokonomie,  Hempel  and  Parey,  Berlin,  1895. 

22  Dunn,  op.  cit..  Chap.  HI. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION      191 

marginal  revenue).     Total  surplus  is  represented  by  the  area  of  the 
rectangle,  ABCD. 

To  supplement  Fig.  36  one  can  construct  Fig.  37  which  focuses  upon 
other  relations  of  this  situation.     Along  the  vertical  and  horizontal 


'Market  price 


D 


^marKct  price  j^  "^^  ^     ^^^„ 

Net  farm  price  /  /^'       ,mC 


L 


I, 


Output 

Fig.  36.    Price  and  cost  curves  of  an  agricultural  enterprise. 


axes  we  measure  respectively  amounts  of  land  inputs  and  amounts  of 


a  composite  set  of  other  inputs.    Each  of  the  curves  /] 


/. 


repre- 


sents an  iso-product  curve, ^  3  and,  in  order,  they  relate  to  decreasing 
levels  of  output.    The  dashed  lines  0»Si,  0S)2  .  .  .  OSn  are  scale  lines. 2* 

23  Each  iso-product  curve  depicts  the  various  combinations  of  the  amounts  of 
land  inputs  and  of  the  composite  set  of  other  inputs  required  to  produce  that 
given  level  of  output  corresponding  to   the   iso-product   curve. 

24  Each  scale  line  is  a  locus  of  points  indicating  the  combinations  of  the 
amounts  of  land  inputs  and  of  the  composite  set  of  other  inputs  which  involve 
the  least  total  outlay  for  the  production  of  each  level  of  output,  for  a  given 
specific  price-ratio  oj  inputs. 


192 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


Since  rent,  the  price  of  land  services,  is  taken  to  be  zero,  the  Hicksian 
price-ratio  (the  iso-outlay  or  iso-cost)  lines  are  vertical,  such  as  line 
VX.  Given  the  level  of  output,  OIi,  to  be  produced  (as  determined 
by  Fig.  36),  the  equilibrium  amounts  of  land  and  other  inputs  are  given 


^-Sn 


100    200 


600   700 


300   400   500 
Other  inputs 

Fig.  37.    Input  proportions,  scale,  and  equilibrium  for  an  agricultural  enterprise. 

by  the  point  of  tangency,  P,  of  the  iso-product  curve  Zj  (which  corre- 
sponds to  an  output  of  01 1)  with  the  price-ratio  line  VX. 

Dunn  has  discussed  the  inconsistency  of  the  above  derivation.  The 
surplus,  ABCD  (Fig.  36),  when  divided  by  the  30  units  of  land  utilized 
(as  given  by  point  P,  Fig.  37)  yields  rent  per  unit  of  land.  This  rent 
or  price  for  the  use  of  the  services  of  land  may  be,  in  certain  circum- 
stances, an  opportunity  cost  or,  in  other  circumstances,  an  actual  pay- 
ment by  the  farm  operator  who  leases  the  land  in  full  competition 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     193 

with  other  potential  users.  In  any  case,  a  price  for  the  use  of  land 
services  exists,  and  vertical  price-ratio  lines  like  VX  are  incorrect.  As 
a  first  approximation,  the  rent  of  each  of  the  30  units  of  land  under 
use  may  be  taken  to  be  ABCD/30.  This  would  yield  a  set  of  price- 
ratio  lines  whose  slopes  are  identical  to  that  of  line  B^Ai.  Accordingly, 
U  would  be  the  new  point  of  tangency  of  the  Ii  iso-product  curve  with 
the  relevant  price-ratio  line  of  the  new  set.  It  would  be  economic  to 
reduce  land  inputs  and  increase  other  inputs  as  indicated  by  the  shift 
along  curve  Ji  from  P  to  U,  and  thereby  to  substitute  outlays  on  other 
inputs  for  rent  outlays. 

However,  if  the  quantities  of  land  inputs  and  other  inputs  given  by 
point  U  were  to  be  employed  to  produce  01^  of  output,  Dunn  has 
shown  that  the  resulting  rent  per  unit  of  land  is  greater  than  that 
assumed  by  the  price-ratio  line  BiA^.  As  a  consequence,  a  new  set 
of  price-ratio  lines,  with  less  steep  slope,  becomes  relevant.  Another 
substitution  of  outlays  on  other  inputs  for  rent  outlays  is  justified. 
This,  in  turn,  generates  a  still  greater  rent  per  unit  of  land  and  makes 
relevant  another  slope  for  the  price-ratio  lines.  In  Dunn's  words:  "a 
series  of  successive  substitution  adjustments  is  made  with  the  tangency 
point  moving  down  the  iso-product  line  from  [P  to  Q  in  Fig.  37] .  Each 
of  these  successive  adjustments,  however,  yields  a  rapidly  decreasing 
increment  to  the  rent  per  acre.  When  the  point  Q  is  reached,  the  rent 
per  acre  cannot  be  increased  any  further  by  increasing  the  ratio  of 
the  'other'  input  factors  to  land. "^ 5 

A  second  basic  set  of  substitutions  occurs  simultaneously  with  these 
adjustments.  As  rent  is  explicitly  acknowledged  as  a  cost,  the  marginal 
and  average  cost  curves  rise.  (Land  inputs  are  a  variable.)  In  Fig.  36, 
the  intersection  of  the  new  dashed  marginal  cost  curve  M'C^  in  which 
the  rent  is  included  as  a  cost,  with  the  net  farm  price  line  suggests  OI2 
as  the  equilibrium  output,  rather  than  01 1.  This  would  correspond 
to  a  shift  from  Q  to  R  along  scale  line  OS2  in  Fig.  37.  However,  the 
change  of  scale  increases  rent  per  unit  land  (when  the  enterprise  is 
operating  under  decreasing  returns  to  scale),  decreases  the  steepness 
of  the  relevant  set  of  price-ratio  lines,  and  indicates  a  series  of  substi- 
tutions which  lead  to  point  T  on  the  I^  iso-product  line.  Once  again 
contraction  of  scale  is  warranted.  Ultimately,  according  to  Dunn,  the 
various  scale  contractions  and  the  substitution  of  outlays  on  other 
inputs  for  outlays  on  land  inputs  lead  to  point  W  where  neither  scale 
adjustments  nor  outlay  substitutions  are  prompted. 2 6    Corresponding 

25  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  p.  30.    The  letters  and  number  in  brackets  are  mine. 

26  The  reader  should  bear  in  mind  that  the  step-by-step  set  of  adjustments 
depicted  in  Fig.  37  is  for  illustrative  purposes  only.    Both  scale  adjustments  and 


194  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

to  point  W  are  the  dot-dash  marginal  and  average  cost  curves  [M'^C" 
and  A''C"0  of  Fig.  36 ;  the  average  cost  curve  inclusive  of  rent  is  tangent 
at  its  minimum  point  to  the  net  farm  price  line.  Given  the  spatial 
position  of  the  land  to  be  used  and  the  crop  to  he  cultivated,  point  W 
represents  a  stable  equilibrium  position  for  the  agricultural  enterprise. 

Thus  far,  only  part  of  the  total  problem  confronting  the  agricultural 
operator  has  been  presented.  Another  part  concerns  his  location. 
Abstracting  from  changes  in  the  resource  content  of  the  land,  in  posi- 
tion relative  to  fixed  transport  facilities,  in  the  tax,  legal,  and  other 
socio-economic  and  political  frameworks  which  condition  land  use,^''' 
we  can  depict  the  impact  of  a  shift  of  location  upon  the  operation  of 
an  agricultural  enterprise  with  the  use  of  Fig.  36.  In  terms  of  economic 
distance,  let  the  agricultural  enterprise  shift  closer  to  the  market.  Ac- 
cordingly, its  net  farm  price  line  rises,  the  transport  cost  to  the  market 
being  diminished. ^s  A  higher  net  farm  price  line  would  obviously 
permit  a  greater  rent  per  unit  of  land  if  inputs  and  output  and  all  other 
prices  are  constant.  However,  since  the  ratio  of  the  price  of  a  land 
input  to  the  price  of  a  composite  of  other  inputs  rises,  the  slope  of  the 
relevant  price-ratio  lines  becomes  less  steep.  A  series  of  substitution 
adjustments  leading  to  still  greater  rent  per  unit  of  land  and  to  a  higher 
ratio  of  other  inputs  to  land  inputs  is  warranted ;  and  consequently  the 
intensity  with  which  a  unit  of  land  is  cultivated  increases. 

Allow  the  agricultural  enterprise  to  shift  its  location  to  a  third  site 
still  closer  to  the  market  and  in  succession  to  a  fourth  and  a  fifth.  It 
becomes  evident  that  the  closer  the  enterprise  to  the  market  the  higher 
the  rent  per  unit  of  land  and  the  greater  the  intensity  at  which  it  is 
economically  feasible  to  cultivate  a  unit  of  land ;  and,  the  more  distant 
the  enterprise  from  the  market  the  less  the  rent  which  the  operator 
can  afford  to  pay  for  a  unit  of  land  and  the  less  the  intensity  with 


substitutions  can  and  do  take  place  simultaneously.    Many  different  kinds  of  paths 
leading  from  the  hypothetical  point  P  to  the  equilibrium  point  W  are  possible. 

27  AH  these  elements  influence  the  firm's  operations  through  their  effect  upon 
its  cost  curves.  Thus,  if  the  resource  content  of  the  land  deteriorates  and  taxes 
rise  as  a  firm  shifts  from  one  location  to  another,  we  can  expect  the  relevant 
average  cost  curve  for  the  second  location  to  course  at  a  higher  level  than  that 
pertinent  for  the  first  location,  ceteris  paribus.  Since  the  variation  in  the 
influence  of  these  elements  does  not  exhibit  a  spatial  regularity,  a  study  of  their 
effects  lies  outside  the  scope  of  this  volume,  although  for  any  particular  situation 
their  pi'esence  must  be  fully  recognized.  The  reader  interested  in  their  effects 
is  referred,  among  others',  to  Brinkmann,  op.  cit.;  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  pp.  22-33;  and 
Dunn,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  5. 

28  The  extent  of  this  diminution  would  be  given  by  the  typical  transport 
gradient  line  over  the  relevant  stretch. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     195 

which  he  cultivates  it.  If  the  rent  potential  per  unit  of  land  were 
plotted  for  each  possible  location  of  the  agricultural  enterprise  along 
a  line  extending  from  the  market,  a  rent  function  would  be  described 
such  as  is  depicted  by  curve  A  A  on  Fig.  38.^9 


Distance  from  market 

Fig.  38.    Rent  functions  for  different  agricultural  land  uses. 


It  should  be  emphasized  that  any  shift  of  the  agricultural  enterprise 
involves  the  general  substitution  between  rent  outlays  and  all  other 
outlays  combined.     Of  still  greater  relevance  are  certain  subsidiary 

29  Our  rent  function  is  identical  with  Hoover's  "rent  surface"  and  with  Dunn's 
"industry  rent  function."  At  times  this  rent  function  has  been  depicted  as  a 
straight  line  (e.g.  Losch,  op.  cit.  pp.  25-40;  and  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  2)  when  it 
has  been  either  implicitly  or  explicitly  assumed  that  intensity  of  cultivation  is 
invariant  with  distance  from  the  market.  In  these  instances,  the  rent  function  is 
given  as:  R  =  E{p  —  a)  —  Ejk  where  R  is  rent  per  unit  of  land,  k  (an  inde- 
pendent variable)  is  distance  from  the  market,  and  E,  p,  a,  and  /  (all  constants 
or  parameters)  are,  respectively,  yield  per  unit  of  land,  market  price,  average 
production  cost,  and  transport  rate  (Dunn,  op.  cit.,  p.  7). 

Because  of  its  emphasis  upon  the  firm  as  the  core  unit  our  formulation  of  the 
problem  precludes  the  use  of  a  straight  line  rent  function.  A  straight  hne  rent 
function,  although  helpful  for  pedagogical  purposes,  is  logically  invalid. 


196  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

substitutions.  Viewed  from  the  standpoint  of  transport  orientation 
theory,  the  enterprise  finds  its  transport  optimal  (minimum  transport 
cost)  point  at  the  market.  As  the  enterprise  moves  away  from  the 
market,  it  substitutes  transport  outlays  for  rent  outlays,  ceteris  paribus; 
and  concomitantly,  because  the  price  of  land  becomes  more  moderate, 
it  substitutes  rent  outlays  for  other  (excluding  transport)  outlays, 
ceteris  paribus.^^  This  substitution  represents  a  deviation  from  the 
transport  optimal  point.  This  deviation  is  of  the  same  order  as  the 
deviation  which  occurs  when,  following  traditional  Weberian  dogma, 
a  firm  shifts  from  its  transport  optimal  point  to  a  cheap  labor  location. 
Among  others,  this  latter  shift  involves  two  basic  substitutions:  (1)  a 
substitution  of  transport  outlays  for  labor  outlays,  ceteris  paribus;  and 
(2)  a  substitution  of  labor  outlays  for  other  (excluding  transport)  out- 
lays since  the  price  of  labor  is  less  at  the  cheap  labor  location.  The 
only  basic  distinction  between  these  two  shifts,  it  can  be  maintained, 
is  that  on  the  one  hand  the  shift  of  the  agricultural  enterprise  can  be 
a  somewhat  continuous  one  whilst  on  the  other  hand  the  shift  of  the 
industrial  firm  to  a  cheap  labor  location  typically  involves  a  discrete 
jump. 

It  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  any  one  farmer  or  agricultural 
operator  need  not  approach  the  location  decision  in  the  comprehensive 
fashion  depicted  above.  He  need  not  be  fully  aware  of  the  breadth 
of  the  problem.  His  vision  may  be  narrowly  circumscribed.  Yet  he 
behaves  as  if  he  were  fully  aware  of  the  entire  problem.  This  result 
obtains  because  the  relative  freedom  of  entry  into  and  exit  from  agri- 
cultural production  tends  to  force  the  farmer  into  efficient  paths  or  to 
weed  him  out  if  he  persistently  deviates  from  these  paths,  ^i  Essen- 
tially there  corresponds  to  every  site  an  appropriate  set  of  character- 
istics relating  to  size  of  enterprise,  intensity  of  land  use,  and  ratios 
of  factor  inputs.  This  appropriate  set  yields,  for  each  site,  the  maxi- 
mum rent,  all  of  which  accrues  to  the  landowner.  The  competitive 
process  wipes  away  any  surplus  profit  which  might  befall  an  operator 
at  any  site,  and  at  the  same  time  ensures  "normal  returns"  or  "normal 
profits."32    Thus,  theoretically,  the  farm  operator  is  indifferent  to  the 

30  A  move  in  the  opposite  direction,  let  us  say  from  no-rent  land  (re :  the  given 
commodity)  toward  the  market,  involves  a  substitution  of  rent  outlays  for 
transportation  outlays,  ceteris  paribus,  and  a  substitution  of  other  (excluding 
transport)  outlays  for  rent  outlays. 

31  Unless,  being  a  landowner,  he  can  pursue  inefficient  practices  at  the  expense 
of  economically  justifiable  rent. 

32  If  the  operator  makes  an  abnormal  profit  after  allowance  for  unusual 
entrepreneurial  ability,  etc.,  by  implication  his  rent  payment  to  the  landowner 
is  too  low.       Accordingly  other  individuals  will  be  attracted  to  the  use  of  the 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     197 

position  at  which  he  is  located,  provided,  of  course,  he  is  within  the 
rent-yielding  hinterland.  Hence,  observing  the  adjustments  of  the 
individual  agricultural  entrepreneur  at  each  possible  distance  from 
the  market  yields,  for  the  given  crop,  a  theoretically  valid  rent  func- 
tion of  the  general  order  of  the  curve  AA  on  Fig.  38. 

As  already  intimated,  there  is  another  basic  substitution  path  along 
which  an  individual  farm  operator  can  proceed.  He  can  elect  to  pro- 
duce a  different  crop.  With  respect  to  this  second  crop  we  can  derive 
for  each  meaningful  location  the  relevant  net  farm  price  line,  ratios 
of  factor  inputs,  scale  of  output,  and  the  rent  potential  which  through 
the  process  of  competitive  bidding  would  accrue  to  the  landowner. 
As  with  the  first  crop,  a  rent  function  results,  let  us  say  curve  BB  of 
Fig.  38.  Again,  when  production  is  restricted  to  the  second  crop,  the 
agricultural  operator  is  theoretically  indifferent  to  location  within  the 
rent-yielding  hinterland  since  at  all  locations  his  average  unit  cost 
curve  (inclusive  of  rent  payments)  would  be  tangent  at  its  minimum 
point  to  the  effective  net  farm  price  line.  Of  course,  to  avoid  losses 
and  to  attain  a  position  corresponding  to  this  tangency  point,  the 
operator  is  compelled  to  adhere  to  the  appropriate  set  of  substitution 
points,  which  set  varies  with  distance  from  the  market. 

When  the  possibility  of  producing  each  crop  is  permitted,  speciali- 
zation in  land  use  may  ensue.  Crop  A  should  be  cultivated  at  those 
sites,  if  any,  at  which  the  ordinate  of  the  rent  function  curve  AA  exceeds 
the  ordinate  of  the  rent  function  curve  BB.  And  similarly,  crop  B 
should  be  produced  at  those  sites,  if  any,  at  which  its  cultivation 
yields  greater  rent  per  acre  land.  If  the  agricultural  operator  were 
to  persist  in  the  cultivation  of  either  crop  A  or  crop  B  at  any  location 
when  conditions  dictate  otherwise,  his  land  would  be  bid  away  from 
him  by  potential  operators  who  channel  their  activity  in  accord  with 
the  practice  which  yields  maximum  rent  per  unit  of  land  at  that  loca- 
tion. Thereby,  in  shifting  from  one  crop  to  another,  he  (or  the  ultimate 
operator  of  the  land)  substitutes  among  various  revenues  and  among 
various  outlays,  as  generally  developed  in  the  individual  firm  discus- 
sion of  Chap.  6. 

given  land  and  continuously  bid  up  rent  until  the  surplus  profits  associated  with 
its  use  are  eliminated.  In  contrast,  if  the  operator  contracts  for  the  use  of  land 
at  a  price  greater  than  its  rent  potential,  his  average  unit  costs  (inclusive  of 
adequate  payments  for  entrepreneurial  abihty,  privately-owned  capital,  etc.)  will 
exceed  his  net  farm  price.  He  will  tend  to  leave  the  industry.  The  land  which  he 
cultivated  will  tend  to  remain  idle  until  the  landowner  reduces  rent  to  the  point 
where  the  operator's  average  unit  cost  curve  can  be  tangent  with  his  net  farm 
price  hne.  At  all  sites,  zero  surplus  tends  to  obtain  after  appropriate  payment 
is  made  for  all  inputs. 


198  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Likewise,  we  can  derive  a  rent  function  for  a  third  crop,  a  fourth 
crop  .  .  .  and  for  an  nth  crop.  Each  of  these  can  be  graphically  depicted 
in  Fig.  38.3  3  Land  use  at  any  location  is  governed  by  the  rent  function 
which  has  the  highest  value  at  that  location.  For  example,  in  Fig.  38, 
the  stretch  of  land  OZ  should  be  devoted  to  the  production  of  crop  A, 
ZY  to  crop  B,  YX  to  crop  C,  and  XW  to  crop  D.^^  It  is  clear  that 
the  individual  farmer  at  any  one  location  is  forced  to  cultivate  that 
crop  which  yields  greatest  rent  to  the  landowner,  so  long  as  relative 
freedom  of  entry,  exit,  and  contract  is  granted.  Thus,  when  we  con- 
centrate upon  the  individual  farm's  adjustments,  we  obtain  the  typical 
set  of  rent  functions  traditionally  central  to  agricultural  location 
theory.  Further,  when  we  rotate  lines  OZ,  OY,  OX,  and  OW  around 
point  0  as  the  center,  we  obtain  the  familiar  Thiinen  rings  (concentric 
circles). 

In  the  above  manner,  individual  firm  analysis  moves  in  the  direction 
of  aggregative  equilibrium  analysis  for  the  industry.  The  analysis  of 
the  problem  on  the  firm  level  involving  resources  devoted  to  a  single 
use  is  extended  to  encompass  the  problem  involving  competition  of 
different  uses  for  the  same  land.  It  is,  of  course,  a  necessary  condition 
that  the  supply  and  demand  for  each  crop  be  equated  at  the  given 
market  price.  If  not,  relative  market  prices  must  change,  rent  functions 
shift,  appropriate  firm  adjustments  occur,  and  a  new  pattern  of  land 
use  be  established  consistent  with  this  necessary  condition.  3  5  Thus 
conditions  relating  to  the  agricultural  industry  as  a  whole — conditions 
which  the  Thiinen  school  has  emphasized — are  of  equal  importance  as 
those  governing  individual  firm  adjustments  in  deriving  an  equilibrium 
land  use  pattern.  It  should  be  pointed  out  that  the  resulting  pattern  is 
logically  more  precise  and  different  from  the  approximative  pattern 
which  the  Thiinen  school  derives  when  it  abstracts  from  individual 
firm  adjustments. 

Where  several  concentrated  markets,  rather  than  one,  exist  for  agri- 
cultural products,  the  problem  becomes  more  complex  graphically  but 
remains  the  same  conceptually.  For  each  crop  as  many  rent  functions 
may  be  identified  as  there  are  markets,  each  rent  function  being  linked 
to  the  consumption  of  the  crop  at  one  and  only  one  market.  Each  rent 
function  throughout  its  course  reflects  appropriate  sets  of  individual 
firm  adjustments.  As  before,  any  given  unit  of  land  becomes  geared 
to  that  use  which  yields  maximum  rent  returns  within  the  entire  range 

33  Curves  CC  and  DD  represent  rent  functions  for  two  of  these  crops. 

34  For  more  extensive  discussion  of  boundary  and  related  conditions  see  Chap. 
10  and  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  Chaps.  2  and  3  and  Appendix  A. 

35  For  a  fuller  treatment  which  considers  the  income  factor  as  well,  see  Dunn, 
op.  cit.,  pp.  16-24. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     199 

of  markets  and  crops.  ^^  Furthermore,  these  principles  governing  land 
use  apply  with  equal  force  whether  we  consider  for  each  unit  of  land 
the  production  of  single  crops  or  any  number  of  products  in  combina- 
tion. In  reality  products  in  combination  (farming  systems)  tend  to 
characterize  the  operations  of  agricultural  enterprises.  However,  the 
above  analysis  remains  unchanged  since  a  crop  can  be  easily  redefined 
as  a  set  of  products  in  combination.  ^^ 

Hence  we  observe  how  the  agricultural  farm  location  problem  can  be 
viewed  as  an  integral  part  of  the  general  individual  firm  location  prob- 
lem. In  the  case  of  industrial  firms,  outlays  on  land  services  may 
frequently  be  less  critical  locationally  than  outlays  on  transport,  labor, 
power,  and  other  inputs.  In  the  case  of  the  agricultural  enterprise, 
some  of  these  latter  outlays  (excluding  transport)  may  be  the  less 
significant  ones;  and  typically,  outlays  on  land  are  major.  Despite 
these  contrasts  on  the  concrete  level,  in  both  cases  the  location  problem 
of  the  individual  unit  involves  the  identical  basic  substitution  process; 
the  individual  unit  whether  agricultural  or  non-agricultural  must,  ex- 
plicitly or  implicitly,  substitute  among  outlays,  among  revenues,  and 
among  outlays  and  revenues. 

Additionally,  because  of  the  relative  freedom  of  entry  and  exit  and 
because  of  the  many  small  units  which  typically  produce  a  given  crop, 
the  analysis  of  the  adjustments  of  the  individual  farm  enterprise  within 
the  full  array  of  feasible  locations,  crops,  and  systems  of  crops,  leads 
to  fruitful  conclusions  on  a  more  aggregative  level.  When  combined 
with  total  conditions  and  restraints  bearing  upon  supply,  demand,  price, 
income,  and  related  variables  within  the  agricultural  industry  as  a 
whole,  this  analysis  leads  to  over-all  equilibrium  land-use  patterns 
within  the  industry  and  to  a  more  precise  determination  of  the  familiar 
Thiinen  spatial  configurations.  However,  to  specify  these  total  con- 
ditions and  restraints  requires  the  study  of  forces  governing  the  inter- 
relations of  various  urban-metropolitan  markets,  their  connections 
with  regional  hinterlands,  and  their  respective  sizes.  These  forces 
operating  on  the  more  aggregative  regional  level  will  be  analyzed  in  a 
future  volume. 

36  This  multimarket  framework  is  dealt  with  at  greater  length  in  Chap  10.  Also 
see  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  pp.  57-63. 

Likewise,  differentials  in  input  prices  among  sites  at  different  distances  from 
the  market,  an  aspect  of  the  agricultural  location  problem  with  which  Brinkmann 
and  Losch  among  others  have  been  concerned,  can  also  be  easily  encompassed 
by  the  substitution  framework.  See  Chap.  10.  Additionally,  other  phases  of  the 
agricultural  location  problem  can  be  incorporated  into  the  above  framework 
(see  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  Chaps.  5  and  6). 

37  For  further  discussion,  see  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  pp.  46-52. 


200 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


Appendix  to  Chapter  8 
Some  Theoretical  Notes  on  Urban  Land-use 

Traditionally,  the  analysis  of  urban  land-use  patterns  has  fallen  outside 
the  realm  of  location  theory.  Yet,  in  many  respects,  urban  land-use  theory 
is  a  logical  extension  of  agricultural  location  theory.  In  this  appendix  we 
shall  dwell  upon  some  of  the  interconnections  of  these  two  forms  of  theories. 
We  must  leave  to  the  reader  and  subsequent  writers  the  task  of  compre- 
hensively stating  these  interconnections  and  of  relating  the  literature  in  these 
two  fields. 

Arbitrarily  select  a  unit  of  urban  land.  To  what  use  should  it  be  put? 
The  price  each  potential  user  is  willing  to  bid  is  dependent  upon  many  factors 
such  as:   (1)  effective  distance  from  the  core;   (2)  accessibility  of  the  site  to 


T  K 

Effective  distance 

Fig.  39.    Variation  of  sales  with  distance  from  urban  core. 


potential  customers;  (3)  number  of  competitors,  their  locations,  and  the 
intensity  with  wliich  they  vie  for  sales;  and  (4)  proximity  to  land  devoted 
to  an  individual  use  or  a  set  of  uses  which  are  complementary  in  terms  of 
both  attracting  potential  customers  and  cutting  costs,  whether  they  be  pro- 
duction, service,  advertising,  or  other. 

Couple  with  the  selected  unit  of  land  a  particular  use,  let  us  say,  use  A. 
The  relations  governing  the  decision  of  a  businessman  to  bid  for  the  unit  of 
land  and  devote  it  to  such  use  may  be  depicted  by  a  set  of  graphs.  In 
Fig.  39  we  measure  along  the  vertical  and  horizontal  axes,  respectively,  dollar 
volume  of  sales^s  and  effective  distance  from  the  core.     (Effective  distance 

38  An  alternative  would  be  to  measure  physical  volume  of  sales  along  the  vertical 
axis.     Since  retail  and  commercial  activities  tend  to  dominate  urban  economic 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     201 

is  not  synonymous  with  physical  distance.  Rather  it  is  physical  distance 
adjusted  in  the  time-cost  dimensions.  As  a  consequence,  equal  physical  dis- 
tances from  the  core  along  the  several  routes  feeding  into  the  core,  whether 
directly  or  indirectly  via  other  routes,  correspond  to  different  effective 
distances.)  When  the  values  for  advertising  outlays,  price  mark-up,  quality 
of  product  or  service,  and  other  relevant  variables  are  set,  the  businessman 
presumably  estimates  dollar  volume  of  sales.  This  volume  of  sales  and  the 
effective  distance  separating  the  core  and  the  selected  unit  of  land  may  be 
represented,  let  us  say,  by  point  R,  in  Fig.  39. 

The  businessman  interested  in  producing  the  commodity  or  service  corre- 
sponding to  use  A  also  considers  other  sites  as  potential  locations.  Given  the 
same  set  of  values  for  advertising  outlays,  price  mark-up,  quality  of  product, 
and  other  relevant  factors,  he  anticipates  for  each  possible  site  a  dollar  volume 
of  sales.  When  the  effective  distance  and  dollar  volume  of  sales  corresponding 
to  each  site  are  plotted  on  Fig.  39,  we  obtain  curve  W .  In  general,  it  is  to 
be  expected  that  dollar  volume  of  sales  falls  off  with  effective  distance  from 
the  core  although  at  times  it  rises  to  secondary  peaks  only  to  decline  again. 3 9 

However,  the  potential  land  user  can  consider  other  sets  of  parametric 
values  for  quality  of  service,  advertising  outlays,  price  mark-up,  and  other 
relevant  variables.  There  are,  in  effect,  an  infinite  number  of  sets  possible. 
For  each  possible  set  the  potential  land  user  can  derive  a  curve  similar  to  VV. 
We  have  added  to  Fig.  39  curves  WW  and  ZZ  which  represent  two  of  the 
infinite  number  possible. 4  o 

In  addition  to  Fig.  39,  we  construct  Fig.  40.  Figure  40  depicts  marginal 
cost  and  average  cost  curves  in  whose  construction  rent  payments  are 
excluded.    These  curves  relate  to  that  quahty  of  product  or  service  and  that 

activities  and  since  the  price  of  a  retail  or  service  activity  may  often  be  syn- 
onymous with  a  price  mark-up  based  upon  dollar  values,  we  have  chosen  to  speak 
in  terms  of  dollar  volume  of  sales  and  price  mark-ups.  The  reader  may  do 
otherwise  without  affecting  the  validity  of  the  argument. 

39  Where  the  urban  structural  pattern  is  set  and  relatively  inflexible,  these 
secondary  peaks  can  be  readily  ascertained.  They  appear  at  those  effective 
distances  which  separate  secondary  and  satellite  commercial  and  shopping  centers 
from  the  core. 

In  contrast,  where  the  urban  structural  pattern  is  extremely  fluid  and  largely 
to  be  determined,  it  is  difBcult  to  identify  the  effective  distances  from  the  core 
at  which  secondary  peaks  occur.  Since  secondary  peaks  reflect  the  juxtaposition  of 
complementary  activities  and  since  in  this  latter  setting  the  spatial  configurations 
of  all  economic  activities  including  transportation  patterns  are  interdependent, 
only  a  general  equihbrium  (simultaneous  equations)  approach,  which  takes  into 
account  all  aspects  of  complementarity  and  competition,  yields  the  effective 
distances  at  which  secondary  peaks  occur. 

Nonetheless,  if  only  for  purposes  of  exposition,  we  have  inserted  secondary 
peaks  in  Fig.  39. 

40  Rigorously  speaking,  the  problem  involves  n-variables,  n-dimensions,  and 
(to  —  1)  spaces.  However,  the  reader  may  care  to  Hmit  the  framework  of  refer- 
ence of  Fig.  39  to  three  variables:  dollar  volume  of  sales,  effective  distance,  and 
price  mark-up.  In  this  case  curves  WW,  VV,  and  ZZ  refer  to  three  different  values 
for  the  variable,  price  mark-up,  curve  ZZ  being  associated  with  the  highest  of  the 
three  and  curve  WW  with  the  lowest. 


202 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


amount  of  advertising  outlays  associated  with  curve  VV  of  Fig.  39.  Also, 
they  reflect  variation  of  costs  with  sales  volume  only.  Just  as  we  assumed 
that  agricultural  cost  functions  (exclusive  of  rent)  vary  insignificantly  with 
distance  from  the  market,  we  postulate  that  the  cost  functions  relating  to 
land  use  A  are  invariant  with  distance  from  the  core. 4 1  As  with  Fig.  36,  we 


$0.20 
$0.15  f 
$0.10 


$0.05  - 


o 


p      \   ^ 

J 

MC 

/ 

AC 

/ 

.  \ 

M 

> 

/ 

'.  \ 

Dollar  volume  of  sales 

Fig.  40.    Variation  of  cost  and  profit  with  volume  of  sales. 


measure  along  the  vertical  axis  not  only  costs  in  dollars,  but  also  price 
(price  mark-up). 

Associated  with  the  curve  VV  of  Fig.  39  is  a  price  mark-up,  let  us  say 
15  cents.  This  price  mark-up  is  represented  by  the  price  line  PP  in  Fig.  40. 
Therefore,  for  any  given  volume  of  sales,  the  spread  between  the  price  line 
and  the  ayerage  cost  curve  is  profits  per  dollar  of  sales  (exclusive  of  rent 
payments).  Multiplying  this  spread  by  volimie  of  sales  yields  total  profits. 
Since  we  have  posited  freedom  of  entry,  exit,  and  contract  in  the  long  run, 
this  total  profit  in  general  will  accrue  to  the  landowner  as  rent  through  the 
process  of  competitive  bidding. 

Returning  to  Fig.  39,  we  find  that  the  businessman  estimates  his  volume 
of  sales  at  OS  if  the  arbitrarily  selected  unit  of  land  (at  effective  distance 
OT  from  the  core)  is  devoted  to  use  A.    Corresponding  to  this  voltime  of 

41  As  already  mentioned,  in  reality  fertility  of  soil,  topography,  labor  costs,  and 
other  factors  do  vary  in  a  specific  regional  situation  with  distance  from  a  central 
market  and  thus  affect  agricultural  cost  functions.  Similarly,  topography,  accessi- 
bility to  labor  force,  and  other  factors  do  vary  in  a  specific  urban  setting  with  dis- 
tance from  the  core  and  do  cause  cost  functions  (excluding  rent)  associated  with 
any  given  land  use  to  vary  with  the  position  of  the  land  employed.  However, 
these  features  of  the  broad  physical  and  social  environment  do  not  vary  in  a 
regular  fashion  with  distance  from  any  pertinent  focal  point  but  rather  vary  hap- 
hazardly. Hence,  their  variation  cannot  be  incorporated  into  our  analysis  which 
aims  at  generality  and  which  abstracts  from  specific  environmental  situations. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     203 

sales  in  Fig.  40  is  the  spread  (profit  per  dollar  of  sales)  MN  and,  therefore, 
a  rent  (total  profits)  which  is  represented  by  the  area  of  the  rectangle  PNML. 
Accordingly,  we  can  plot  in  Fig.  41  point  F  which  indicates  that  a  total  rent 
OJ  {=  PNML)  is  yielded  by  the  arbitrarily  selected  unit  of  land  (at  OT 
distance  from  the  core)  if  devoted  to  use  A.  In  Fig.  41,  we  measure  effective 
distance  along  the  horizontal  axis  and  rent  along  the  vertical. 


c 


> 

_^ 

- 

F 

O     D 


E 


A    gB 


Effective  distance 

Fig.  41.    Rent  functions  for  different  urban  land  uses. 


For  every  other  unit  of  land,  the  businessman,  who  has  already  estimated 
volume  of  sales  corresponding  to  any  effective  distance  from  the  core  (as 
given  by  curve  VV,  Fig.  39),  can  determine  profits  per  dollar  sales  and  total 
profits  (rent)  in  accordance  with  Fig.  40.  We  can  therefore  plot  in  Fig.  41 
the  rent  corresponding  to  each  effective  distance  separating  any  relevant  unit 
of  land  from  the  core.  We  obtain  the  dashed  curve  EE.  It  depicts  rent 
generally  declining  with  increase  in  effective  distance  though  rising  to  sec- 
ondary peaks  at  satelhte  centers  where  sales  volume  also  attains  secondary 
peaks. 

Curve  EE  might  be  construed  as  the  rent  function  relating  to  use  A,  much 
as  curve  AA  in  Fig.  38  was  construed.  Except  in  a  very  limited  sense,  this 
interpretation  would  be  incorrect.  In  considering  the  employment  of  different 
units  of  land  in  use  A,  the  businessman  would  not  confine  his  potential  opera- 
tions to  the  values  for  price  mark-up,  quality  of  product  or  service,  advertising 
outlays,  and  other  variables  which  underlie  curve  VV  of  Fig.  39.  He  would 
find  that  total  profits  could  be  enhanced  if  one  or  more  of  these  values  were 
varied  at  each  potential  location.  Simultaneously,  of  course,  his  cost  functions 
would  be  altered. 

For  example,  the  businessman  might  realize  greater  profits  at  effective 


204  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

distance  OK  (Fig.  39)  if  he  operated  under  conditions  specified  by  curve  ZZ 
rather  than  by  curve  VV.  His  profit  could  be  greater  even  though  his  volume 
of  sales  would  not  be  HK,  but  only  JK,  since  the  cost  curves  associated  with 
curve  ZZ  would  be  significantly  lower  than  those  in  Fig.  40.4  2 

Hence,  at  this  and  most  locations  the  rent  wliich  could  potentially  accrue 
to  the  landowner  would  exceed  that  indicated  by  curve  EE  (Fig.  41) ;  at  no 
location  would  rent  be  less.  We  therefore  let  curve  AA  be  the  locus  of 
points,  each  of  which  depicts  at  the  given  effective  distance  the  maximum 
rent  obtainable  from  the  variation  of  all  factors  under  control  of  the  business- 
man.   It  is  the  relevant  rent  function  for  use  4.43 

In  similar  fashion  we  can  derive  for  each  possible  use — retail,  commercial, 
wholesale,  industrial,  residential,  cultural,  etc. — a  rent  function  which  would 
depict  the  maximum  rent  potential  at  each  possible  site.  For  purposes  of 
illustration,  we  have  added  two  of  these  functions,  BB  and  CC,  to  Fig.  41. 
As  with  Fig.  38,  at  each  effective  distance,  that  use  whose  rent  function  has 
the  highest  ordinate  wins  out  in  the  competition.  For  example,  if  there  were 
only  three  possible  uses  of  urban  land  and  if  at  each  effective  distance  the 
rent  potential  in  any  use  were  completely  independent  of  the  uses  to  which 
other  land  was  put,  the  units  of  land  along  stretch  OD  would  be  channelled 
into  use  A,  along  stretch  DG  into  use  B,  and  beyond  G  into  use  C.  In  reality, 
at  any  effective  distance  the  rent  potential  of  land  in  a  given  use  may  be 
significantly  affected  by  the  uses,  whether  competitive  or  complementary,  to 
which  adjacent  and  other  units  of  land  in  the  urban  area  are  put.  Competi- 
tion coupled  with  limited  volume  of  sales  is  likely  to  depress  markedly  the 
rent  potential  of  any  given  unit  of  land  when  decisions  are  or  have  been 
made  to  devote  other  units  to  the  same  use. 4  4  Furthermore,  innumerable 
rent  functions  obtain,  each  of  which  corresponds  to  a  unique  use  to  which 
urban  land  can  be  put.  Thus,  aside  from  general  residential  and  industrial 
land,  only  a  relatively  few  sites  of  the  many  possible  ones  are  allocated  by  the 
market  mechanism  to  any  particular  use.    Such  sites  may  comprise  clusters 

42  For  related  discussion  on  the  problem  of  choosing  for  any  given  location  the 
correct  set  of  values  for  price  mark-up,  advertising  outlays,  and  quaUty  of  product, 
the  reader  is  referred  to,  among  others:  Kenneth  E.  Boulding,  Economic  Analysis, 
Harper  &  Brothers,  New  York,  rev.  ed.  1948,  Chaps.  31  and  32,  especially  pp. 
717-727;  Edward  Chamberhn,  The  Theory  a)  Monopolistic  Competition,  Harvard 
University  Press,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  1938,  Chaps.  V  and  VI;  L.  Abbott,  "Vertical 
Equilibrium  Under  Pure  Quahty  Competition,"  American  Economic  Review,  Vol. 
XVIII  (December  1953),  pp.  826-845;  and  R.  Dorfman  and  P.  0.  Steiner,  "Opti- 
mal Advertising  and  Optimal  Quahty,"  American  Economic  Review,  Vol.  XLIV 
(December  1954),  pp.  826-836. 

43  If  there  were  plotted  in  Fig.  41  an  infinite  number  of  curves,  each  corre- 
sponding to  the  relevant  conditions  depicted  by  one  of  the  infinite  number  of 
curves  which  we  can  draw  in  Fig.  39,  we  would  find  that  at  each  effective  distance 
curve  AA  passes  through  the  maximum  of  the  infinite  number  of  values  of  the 
ordinate  given  by  these  curves  at  that  effective  distance. 

4'i  This  is  not  to  deny  that  the  rent  potential  of  certain  units  of  land  in  a  given 
use  may  be  greatly  enhanced  when  the  use  (whether  like  or  unlike)  of  adjacent 
land  results  in  increasing  the  attractive  power  (dollar  volume  of  sales)  of  the 
several  juxtaposed  units  as  a  whole. 


AGGLOMERATION  AND  AGRICULTURAL  LOCATION     205 

of  adjacent  units,  units  spatially  distributed  throughout  the  urban  area  in 
more  or  less  regular  fashion,  or  both. 4  5 

In  the  above  fashion,  it  is  thus  possible  to  proceed  with  the  derivation  of 
optimal  land-use  patterns  for  different  urban  settings.  Only  a  skeletal  frame- 
work has  been  traced  in  this  appendix.  Yet  it  suffices  to  disclose  the  rather 
obvious  intercomiections  of  agricultural  location  theory  and  urban  land-use 
theory.  In  each,  rent  functions  (surfaces)  guide  the  allocating  hand  of  the 
market.  For  both,  relations  to  transportation  facilities  and  systems  are 
critical  in  the  definition  of  effective  economic  distance;  and  changes  in  the 
transportation  grid  provoke  in  each  a  dynamic  pattern  of  adjustments  whose 
outline  is  difficult  to  unravel  ex  post,  let  alone  anticipate.  In  agricultural  loca- 
tion theory,  transport  outlays  are  explicitly  considered;  they  depress  net  farm 
price.  In  urban  land-use  theory,  transport  outlays  enter  into  the  picture  just 
as  forcefully,  though  only  implicitly.  Transport  outlays  in  terms  of  both  time 
and  cost  are  borne  by  the  consumer  but  strategically  condition  revenue  poten- 
tials of  the  business  firm  through  affecting  the  accessibility  of  his  location  to 
customers  and,  hence,  his  volume  of  sales. 

Both  agricultural  location  and  land-use  theory  must  be  concerned  with 
complementarity  and  competitive  relations.  On  the  farm,  complementarity 
revolves  around  the  full  utilization  of  the  farmer's  time,  equipment,  land, 
and  other  indivisible  units,  and  it  customarily  results  in  the  cultivation  of  a 
system  of  crops  rather  than  a  single  crop.  In  the  urban  setting,  comple- 
mentarity in  terms  of  configuration  of  uses  spatially  juxtaposed  critically 
affects  both  costs  and  accessibility. ^  6  Finally,  technology,  the  legal  frame- 
work, and  other  institutional  and  cultural  factors  in  their  full  dynamic  setting 
establish  constantly  changing  limits  to  which  a  given  unit  of  land,  whether 
rural  or  urban,  may  be  put.  In  many  cases,  these  hmits  are  rational  so  far 
as  the  commonweal  is  concerned;  in  other  instances,  irrational.  Where 
rational,  they  too  add  to  the  similarities  of  and  interconnections  between 
agricultural  location  theory  and  urban  land-use  theory. 

In  bringing  this  appendix  to  a  close,  we  wish  to  state  that  the  urban 
land-use  problem  can  be  presented  in  terms  of  substitution  analysis  and  as  an 
integral  part  of  general  location  theory,  much  as  agricultural  location  theory 
has  been.    In  essence  the  businessman  substitutes  among  various  outlays  and 

45  The  reader  is  referred  to  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  Figs.  11  and  12,  for  suggestive 
graphic  illustrations. 

To  avoid  complicated  diagrams  we  have  presented  the  analysis  in  terms  of 
effective  distance  along  only  one  line  radiating  from  core  point  0.  A  more  com- 
prehensive presentation  would  have  considered  units  of  land  along  all  possible 
lines  radiating  in  different  directions  both  directly  and  indirectly  from  point  0. 
Such  a  presentation  (in  which,  to  reiterate,  equal  physical  distances  would  corre- 
spond to  different  effective  distances)  would  have  yielded  rent  surfaces  for  each 
of  the  innumerable  uses.  However,  the  analysis  would  not  have  been  altered  and 
would  have  led  to  similar  general  results. 

46  The  complementarity  problem  is  as  difficult  to  attack  as  the  agglomeration 
problem.  In  many  respects,  these  two  problems  are  two  sides  of  the  same  coin. 
Both  require  an  analytical  approach  which  looks  at  each  individual  activity  not 
in  vacuum  but  as  an  element  of  a  complex  of  activities.  Such  a  complex  approach 
will  be  explored  in  a  future  volume. 


206  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

revenues  when  he  selects  both  the  commodity  (product  or  service)  to  be 
produced  and  his  location.  He  may  substitute  rent  outlays  for  advertising 
outlays  or  for  outlays  to  alter  the  quahty  of  his  commodity  when  he  considers 
shifting  his  location  to  any  site  closer  to  the  core;  or,  if  he  maintains  quality 
and  advertising  outlays,  he  incurs  additional  rent  outlays  to  acquire  addi- 
tional revenue  potentials.  In  weighing  the  several  commodities  wliich  he 
might  produce,  once  again  he  substitutes  among  the  outlays  and  revenues 
associated  with  the  several  commodities,  much  as  the  farmer  does  in  selecting 
the  particular  set  of  crops  to  be  cultivated.  And  so  forth.  Thus,  although 
the  typical  businessman  may  not  attack  his  problem  in  such  a  comprehensive 
fashion,  tracing  out  in  a  substitution  framework  what  his  logical  reactions 
would  be  allows  us  to  arrive  at  optimal  patterns  of  land  use. 

It  must  constantly  be  borne  in  mind,  however,  that  the  businessman 
operates  within  a  setting  of  restraints.  Certain  of  these  restraints  are  im- 
posed by  the  features  of  his  physical  environment,  such  as  topography  and 
existing  structures.  Certain  are  associated  with  social  and  economic  conditions 
which  relate  to  such  factors  as  total  demand,  total  income,  tastes,  and  cultural 
patterns,  whose  treatment  falls  within  the  scope  of  a  volume  on  regional 
analysis.  These  restraints  are  of  as  great  importance  in  shaping  land-use 
patterns  as  are  the  businessman's  own  decisions.  Since  these  restraints  differ 
from  urban  area  to  urban  area,  they  in  turn  induce  logical  patterns  of  land 
use  which  differ  from  area  to  area.  They  furnish  a  partial  justification  for 
the  kaleidoscopic  variety  of  reality. 


Chapter 


.9 


Some  Basic  Interrelations 
of  Location  and  Trade  Theory' 


1.     Preliminary  Remarks 

Heretofore,  we  have  treated  trade  rather  incidentally.  We  have 
focused  upon  the  location  of  the  individual  industrial  or  agricultural 
enterprise  (or  group  of  enterprises)  with  respect  to  markets,  whether 
one-point  or  areal.  We  have  implicitly  posited  that  once  locations 
are  determined,  the  associated  flows  of  commodities,  both  as  inputs 
and  products,  are  likewise  determined.  This  postulate  is  consistent 
with  the  statement  in  Chap.  2  that  "(1)  location  cannot  be  explained 
without  at  the  same  time  accounting  for  trade  and  (2)  trade  cannot 
be  explained  without  the  simultaneous  determination  of  locations." 

Although  trade  and  location  are  as  the  two  sides  of  the  same  coin, 
it  does  not  follow  that  the  general  location  theory  developed  thus  far 
is  adequate  to  explain  all  forms  of  trade.  First,  the  general  theory  of 
location  developed  in  this  volume  does  not  consider,  except  in  minor 
fashion,  the  aggregate  demand  and  income  side  of  the  picture,  par- 
ticularly as  they  relate  to  regions  and  to  interregional  trade.  These 
aspects  of  both  the  location  and  trade  problem  are  to  be  considered 
in  another  volume. ^ 

1  The  contents  of  this  chapter  are  largely  drawn  from  a  manuscript  written 
jointly  with  Merton  J.  Peck. 

-  The  reader  will  find  some  of  these  aggregative  demand  and  income  aspects 
treated  in  W.  Isard,  "Location  Theory  and  Trade  Theory:  Short-Run  Analysis," 
Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  LXVIII  (May  1954),  pp.  305-320. 

207 


208  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Second,  trade  may  be  international  as  well  as  intranational.  An 
international  setting  introduces  into  our  conceptual  framework  certain 
additional  basic  factors.  Nonetheless  some  of  these  factors  can  be 
incorporated  into  our  analysis,  as  we  shall  now  attempt  to  demonstrate 
in  this  chapter. 

In  Chap.  2  we  have  already  noted  that  Weber  criticized  classical 
trade  theory  for  ignoring  the  significant  amount  of  industry  which 
is  transport- oriented,  and  whose  geographic  distribution,  internation- 
ally speaking,  is  governed  primarily  by  considerations  of  transport 
cost  of  raw  materials,  fuel,  and  finished  product.  This  criticism  was 
undoubtedly  a  major  source  of  inspiration  for  Ohlin's  attempt  "to 
demonstrate  that  the  theory  of  international  trade  is  only  a  part  of 
a  general  localization  theory."^  This  attempt  has  already  been  dis- 
cussed in  Chap.  2.  Other  location  theorists — Furlan,  Englander, 
Weigmann,  Predohl,  and  particularly  Losch^ —  have  reiterated  Weber's 
contention.  But  despite  Ohlin's  excellent  formulation  of  the  problem, 
Williams'  classic  criticism  of  the  mobility  and  immobility  premises 
of  trade  theory, ^  and  Losch's  major  contribution  in  visualizing  and 
portraying  the  spatial  structure  of  an  economic  system,  the  presenta- 
tion of  the  basic  interrelations  which  should  logically  obtain  between 
location  and  trade  theories,  and  which  should  lead  to  improvements 
in  both,  is  still  wanting.  As  one  of  the  objectives  of  this  chapter  we 
hope  to  cast  additional  light  on  these  basic  interrelations. 


2.     A  Fusion  of  Opportunity  Cost  Doctrine  and 
Transport-orientation 

The  empirical  materials  presented  in  Chap.  3  testify  to  the  signifi- 
cance of  the  friction  of  distance  both  in  interregional  and  in  inter- 

3  Bertil  Ohlin,  Interregional  and  International  Trade,  Harvard  University  Press, 
Cambridge,  Mass.,  1933,  p.  vii. 

4  V.  Furlan,  "Die  Standortsprobleme  in  der  Volks-  und  Weltwirtschaftslehre," 
Weltwirtschaftliches  Archiv,  Vol.  II  (1913),  pp.  1-34;  O.  Englander,  "Kritisches 
und  Positives  zu  einer  allgemeinen  reinen  Lehre  vom  Standort,"  Zeitschrijt  fur 
Volkswirtschaft  und  Sozialpolitik,  Vol.  V  (Neue  Folge),  Nos.  7-9  (1926) ;  H.  Weig- 
mann, "Ideen  zu  einer  Theorie  der  Raumwirtschaft,"  Weltwirtschaftliches  Archiv, 
Vol.  XXXIV  (1931),  pp.  1-40;  and  "Standortstheorie  und  Raumwirtschaft"  in 
Johann  Heinrich  von  Thunen  zum  150  Geburtstag,  ed.  W.  Seedorf  and  H.  Jurgen, 
Rostock,  1933,  pp.  137-57;  A.  Predohl,  "Aussenwirtschaft,"  Grundriss  der  Sozial- 
wissenschaft,  Bd.  17  (Gottingen,  1949) ;  A.  Losch,  Die  rdumliche  Ordnung  der  Wirt- 
schaft,  Jena,  1944,  Part  III. 

5  J.  H.  Williams,  "The  Theory  of  International  Trade  Reconsidered,"  Economic 
Journal,  Vol.  XXXIX  (June  1929),  pp.  195-209. 


INTERRELATIONS  OF  LOCATION,  TRADE  THEORY     209 

national  trade.  The  "falling  off  with  distance"  effect  is  pronounced. ^ 
Yet  how  incorporate  this  effect  in  both  location  and  trade  theory? 

In  the  previous  chapters,  especially  in  Chap.  5,  the  distance  variable 
has  already  been  partly  incorporated  into  location  theory  via  the  con- 
cept of  transport  input.  Fuller  treatment  of  this  variable  by  location 
analysis  lies  in  that  direction  which  would  involve  the  development 
of  gravity  models  and  models  of  other  types.'''  (These  models  are  to  be 
discussed  in  a  subsequent  volume.)  In  contrast,  in  international  trade 
theory  the  distance  variable  has  hardly  been  explicitly  recognized.  This 
situation  reflects  the  fact  that  the  various  international  trade  doctrines 
have  been  pushed  along  certain  channels  to  extreme  refinement  but 
left  in  a  primitive  stage  of  development  in  other  channels.  Those 
aspects  of  trade  theory  which  have  remained  undeveloped  are  the  very 
ones  which  would  involve  the  explicit  treatment  of  the  distance  variable 
and  which  would  thereby  contribute  to  the  fusion  of  trade  theory 
and  location  theory.    Hence  an  attack  must  be  made  on  these  aspects. 

A  major  obstacle  to  such  an  attack  is  the  disagreement  among  trade 
theorists  as  to  what  is  "good  and  relevant"  trade  theory.  Into 
such  a  controversy  we  do  not  wish  to  enter,  particularly  since  we  feel 
that,  for  the  most  part,  whatever  the  trade  theory  considered,  im- 
provement can  be  effected  when  attention  is  paid  to  the  spatial  aspects 
of  the  economy  and  when  the  techniques  and  concepts  of  location 
theory  are  embraced.  For  our  purposes,  however,  it  seems  sufficient 
to  proceed  with  a  very  crude  classification  of  trade  doctrines,  namely, 
those  which  are  concerned  with  or  emphasize  long-run  effects  and  ad- 
justments, and  those  which  attribute  greater,  though  not  exclusive, 
significance  to  short-run  repercussions  and  forces.  Since  the  extension 
of  the  latter  set  of  trade  doctrines  to  incorporate  more  explicitly  the 
distance  variable  revolves  around  the  appropriate  development  of 
gravity  models,  modified  interregional  input-output  schemes  and 
activity  analysis,  which  are  to  be  discussed  in  a  subsequent  volume, 
we  shall  confine  ourselves  in  this  chapter  to  the  extension  of  the  first 
type  of  trade  doctrine.  ^  This  type  is  best  exemplified  by  Graham's 
work.  9 

6  Also,  see  W.  Beckerman,  "Distance  and  the  Pattern  of  Intra-European  Trade," 
Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  forthcoming. 

■^  See  W.  Isard  and  G.  Freutel,  "Regional  and  National  Product  Projections  and 
Their  Interrelations,"  Long-Range  Economic  Projection,  Studies  in  Income  and 
Wealth,  Vol.  XVI,  Princeton  University  Press,  Princeton,  N.J.,  1954,  pp.  434-439. 

8  For  some  preliminary  extension  of  the  latter  set  of  trade  doctrines  the  reader 
is  referred  to  W.  Isard,  op.  cit. 

9  Frank  D.  Graham,  The  Theory  of  International  Values,  Princeton  University 
Press,  Princeton,  N.J.,  1940. 


210  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Graham's  approach  has  strong  appeal  to  location  theorists  since  he 
adopts  a  multicountry,  multicommodity  approach  (one  which  until 
recently  has  not  been  common  among  trade  theorists)  and  since  he 
emphasizes  supply  and  cost  conditions. lo  However,  Graham  ignores 
the  very  heart  of  location  analysis,  namely,  that  sector  of  any  national 
or  international  economy  for  which  transport  costs  are  the  primary 
location  factor  and  which  is  characterized  as  transport-oriented.  As 
pointed  out  above,  if  there  is  any  significance  to  location  analysis,  it 
lies  in  the  fact  that  transport  costs  vary  systematically  with  distance 
and  thus  provide  an  underlying  stratum  for  systematic  analysis. 

Though  transport-orientation  analysis  should  be  included  in  trade 
doctrine  in  order  to  facilitate  the  understanding  of  flows  of  commodities, 
it  must  be  admitted  that  existing  location  theory  does  not  readily 
adapt  itself  to  being  so  included  since  it  treats  costs  only  in  terms  of 
a  given  currency.  We  wish  now  to  demonstrate  that,  by  extending  the 
analytic  framework  of  transport-orientation  to  consider  not  costs  in 
any  particular  currency  (as  dollars  or  sterling)  but  rather  opportunity 
costs,  it  is  possible  to  incorporate  transport-orientation  into  existing 
trade  theory.    We  illustrate  by  an  extended,  though  simple,  example. 

Assume  three  countries.  A,  B,  and  C,  each  possessing,  as  with 
Graham,  12  productive  units.  After  trade,  two  finished  goods,  steel  and 
textiles,  are  consumed  by  each.  To  produce  1  weight  unit  of  steel 
requires  2  weight  units  of  ore  and  4  weight  units  of  coal  and,  in  addi- 
tion, shipping  for  the  finished  steel  and  for  one  or  both  raw  materials. 
If  production  is  at  A,  coal  which  is  assumed  to  exist  in  B  alone  will  need 
to  be  shipped  as  well  as  finished  steel.  If  production  is  at  5,  ore  which 
is  assumed  to  exist  in  A  alone  will  need  to  be  shipped  as  well  as  steel. 
If  production  is  at  C  which  possesses  neither  coal  nor  ore,  both  raw 
materials  and  steel  will  need  to  be  shipped.  To  simplify  computations, 
shipping  requirements  on  textiles  are  assumed  to  be  negligible,  n 

10  By  and  large,  the  traditional  location  theory  of  the  Launhardt,  Weber, 
Palander,  and  Hoover  type  has  posed  the  problem  of  finding  the  point  of  minimum 
cost  for  assembling  raw  materials,  processing  them,  and  distributing  the  finished 
product  to  the  market  point  or  area.  For  the  most  part,  demand  has  been  taken 
as  given,  or  its  variation  as  of  minor  consequence  for  determining  the  optimum 
plant  location.  Even  agricultural  location  theory  of  the  Thijnen  tj^pe  takes  prices 
and  hence  demand  at  the  city  market  as  set.  The  problem  is  essentially  to  con- 
sider the  variation  in  transport  and  production  costs  associated  with  the  various 
possible  patterns  of  zones  in  the  cultivation  of  several  crops  and  to  select  that 
pattern  which  maximizes  rent  for  each  unit  of  land. 

11  The  reader  may  wish  to  consider  not  only  shipping  requirements  on  textiles, 
but  also  the  raw  material  and  other  factor  requirements  in  both  textile  and  steel 
production,  as  one  must  in  reality.  To  do  so  compHcates  manyfold  the  computa- 
tions and  does  not  affect  the  essential  nature  of  the  conclusions  to  be  derived. 


INTERRELATIONS  OF  LOCATION,  TRADE  THEORY    211 

In  each  country  let  a  productive  unit,  when  devoted  to  the  pro- 
duction of  a  given  commodity  alone,  produce  under  conditions  of 
pure  competition  and  constant  cost,  the  quantities  (in  standard  weight 
units)  of  each  commodity  as  listed  in  Table  I.  Shipping  is  necessarily 
expressed  in  terms  not  of  weight  units  but  of  transport  inputs  where 
a  transport  input  (say  a  ton-mile)  is  defined  as  the  movement  of  a 
weight  unit  (a  ton)  over  a  unit  of  distance  (a  mile) .  Also,  although 
a  productive  unit  in  each  country  can  produce  8  units  of  steel  when 
the  ore  and  coal  are  at  hand,  the  ore,  coal,  and  transportation  of  the 
ore,  coal,  and  finished  product  must  be  purchased.  Hence,  a  productive 
unit  in  countries  A,  B,  and  C  produces  respectively  8  —  Xa,  8  —  Xb, 
and  S  —  Xc  units  of  steel  where  Xa,  Xb,  and  Xc  correspond  to  the 
amounts  of  steel  (or  their  equivalents  in  terms  of  textiles  or  shipping) 

Table  I.     Amount  of  Each  Commodity  a  Productive 

Unit  in  Each  Country  Can  Produce  when  Devoted 

to  the  Production  of  One  Commodity  Alone 


Commodity 

Country 

A 

B 

C 

Ore 

Coal 

Textiles 

Shipping  (in  transport  inputs) 

30 

0 

5 

2500 

0 

20 

4 

600 

0 

0 

2 

600 

Steel  S  -  Xa  8  -  Xb  8  -  Xc 

exchanged  for  the  coal,  ore,  and  associated  shipping  required  if  a  par- 
ticular country  were  to  produce  and  deliver  the  steel.  The  figures  of 
Table  I,  once  the  values  of  the  variables  Xa,  Xb,  and  Xc  are  determined 
for  any  given  situation,  express  for  each  country  the  opportunity  costs 
in  the  use  of  a  productive  unit  for  the  production  of  any  commodity. 
In  determining  the  values  of  Xa,  Xb,  and  Xc  we  must  construct  a 
table  on  shipping  requirements  of  steel  in  terms  of  transport  inputs. 
For  this  to  be  done,  however,  the  distances  separating  countries  must 
be  specified.  For  the  moment,  posit  that  each  country  is  100  distance 
units  from  each  of  the  other  two,  so  that  their  geographic  position  is 

The  two  activities,  textile  and  steel  production,  are  purposefully  chosen.  The 
former  typifies  an  industry  usually  treated  by  trade  theorists  and  is  one  in  the 
location  of  which  labor  and  other  immobile  local  (national)  resources  are  domi- 
nant factors  while  transport  cost  is,  at  most,  minor.  The  latter  represents  a 
transport-oriented  industry,  in  the  location  of  which  labor  and  other  immobile 
resources  have  been  considered  incidental  (W.  Isard,  "Some  Locational  Factors 
in  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry  since  the  Early  Nineteenth  Century,"  Journal  of 
Political  Economy,  Vol.  LVI  (June  1948),  pp.  203-217). 


212 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


as  the  corners  of  an  equilateral  triangle.  See  the  figure  at  the  upper 
right  hand  corner  of  Table  II.  Immediately  Table  II  can  be  filled  in. 
Since  in  serving  any  market  B  has  less  shipping  expense  (incurs  fewer 
transport  inputs)  than  either  A  or  C,  and  A  less  than  C,  and  since  the 


Table  II. 


Transport  Input  Requirements  Per  Weight  Unit  of 
Steel,  Given  Relative  Position:        b 


100 


Country 
to  Wliich 
Delivered 

On  Coal 

On  Ore 

On  Steel 

Total 

A 

If  production  at  A 
If  production  at  B 
If  production  at  C 

400 

0 

400 

0 
200 
200 

0 

100 
100 

400 
300 
700 

B 

If  production  at  A 
If  production  at  B 
If  production  at  C 

400 

0 

400 

0 
200 
200 

100 

0 

100 

500 
200 
700 

C 

If  production  at  A 
If  production  at  B 
If  production  at  C 

400 

0 

400 

0 
200 
200 

100 

100 

0 

500 
300 
600 

mine  prices  of  ore  and  coal  wherever  steel  may  be  produced  will  be 
identical  for  the  three  countries,  12  it  follows  that: 

S-Xb>8-Xa>S-Xc. 

To  derive  the  values  of  X^,  Xb,  and  Xc  as  well  as  the  patterns  of 
production  and  trade,  demand  conditions  must  also  be  specified  since 
otherwise  exchange  ratios  cannot  be  obtained.  To  simplify  the  prob- 
lem assume,  within  the  range  of  variation  of  real  income  considered 
below,  that  each  country  desires  to  consume  twice  as  much  textiles  as 
steel.  1^    It  then  follows  that: 


12  The  mine  prices  of  ore  and  coal  in  terms  of  finished  steel  will,  of  course, 
depend  upon  which  country  or  countries  produce  steel. 

13  It  is  traditional  to  posit  that  variation  of  real  income,  within  definite  Hmits, 
does  not  affect  the  simplified  expenditure  (demand)  pattern  usually  assumed. 
See,  for  example,  Graham,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  V,  or  L.  Metzler,  "Graham's  Theory  of 
International  Values,"  American  Economic  Review,  Vol.  XL  (June  1950),  pp. 
304-13. 


INTERRELATIONS  OF  LOCATION,  TRADE  THEORY   213 

(1)  A  produces  all  the  ore  required;  also  she  furnishes  all  the  ship- 
ping (since,  given  demand  conditions,  her  12  productive  units  are  not 
completely  utilized  in  both  ore  production  and  in  shipping  and  since 
she  has  greater  advantage  compared  to  B  and  C  in  shipping  than  in 
any  other  activity  except  ore  production)  ;  and  in  addition  she  engages 
in  some  textile  production  (since  she  has  greater  comparative  ad- 
vantage in  textiles  than  in  steel  or  coal). 

(2)  B  produces  all  the  coal  required  and  some  textiles  (since  even 
if  B  were  to  produce  all  the  steel  required  in  addition  to  the  coal,  she 
would  have  left  over  some  productive  units,  given  the  demand  condi- 
tions, and  since  relative  to  A  she  has  less  disadvantage  in  the  produc- 
tion of  textiles  than  in  shipping  or  ore  production) . 

(3)  C  produces  some  textiles  (since  even  if  C  were  to  produce  all 
the  steel  required,  she  would  have  unutilized  some  productive  units, 
and,  since  relative  to  A  or  B,  she  has  less  disadvantage  in  the  produc- 
tion of  textiles  than  in  shipping  or  ore  production  or  coal  production) . 

Since  each  country  produces  textiles,  exchange  values  are,  as  with 
Graham,  1  unit  of  textiles  for  6  of  ore,  for  500  of  shipping, i^  for  5 
of  coal  and  for  (8  —  Zb)/4  or  (8  —  Xc)/2  of  steel.  However,  it  is  not 
clear  whether  B  or  C  will  produce  steel,  even  though  B  has  absolute 
advantage  over  C  in  steel  production  and  is  the  point  of  minimum 
transport  cost  for  serving  each  steel  market.  The  answer  hinges  upon 
whether  B's  productivity  in  steel  (8  —  Xb)  is  more  than  twice  C's 
(S  —  Xc).     Simple  calculation  shows  that  this  is  the  case.i^     As  a 

14  Traditional  location  theoiy  assumes  a  given  transport  rate  structure  which 
applies  to  the  movement  of  a  commodity  whether  or  not  the  commodity  repre- 
sents return  cargo  on  a  ship  which  otherwise  might  make  the  trip  empty.  This 
procedure  assumes  certain  monopolistic  elements  and  inefficiencies  in  rate-making 
which  to  some  extent  at  least  exist  in  reality. 

Logically,  the  entire  pattern  of  commodity  movements  and  requirements  for 
transport  sei-vices  in  all  directions  should  be  considered  in  setting  rates,  as,  for 
example,  Koopmans  has  done  (T.  C.  Koopmans  and  S.  Reiter,  "A  Model  of 
Transportation,"  in  Activity  Analysis  of  Production  and  Allocation,  ed.  by  T.  C. 
Koopmans,  New  York,  1951,  Chap.  XIV).  To  do  this  here,  however,  would  require 
an  extension  of  location  theory  in  a  direction  which  is  beyond  the  scope  of  this 
chapter.    The  rate  of  500  transport  inputs  for  1  unit  of  textiles  is  taken  as  fixed. 

15  From  Table  II  it  is  seen  that  in  producing  and  delivering  steel  to  any  market 
C's  absolute  disadvantage  relative  to  B  is  least  with  respect  to  the  market  in  C, 
the  absolute  disadvantage  in  this  case  being  measured  by  300  transport  inputs. 
Consider  then  the  question  of  productivity  in  producing  and  delivering  steel  to 
C.  To  produce  and  deliver  8  units  of  steel  to  C,  B  requires:  (1)  16  units  of  ore 
for  which,  according  to  the  above  exchange  ratios,  she  must  pay  A  2.7  units  of 
textiles  (or  its  equivalent) ;  (2)  32  units  of  coal  for  which  she  must  pay  her  coal 
producers  6.4  units  of  textiles;  and  (3)  2400  transport  inputs  for  which  she  must 


214  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

consequence,  B  produces  steel  and  C  textiles  since  C  has  comparative 
advantage  in  textiles  alone. 

It  is  not  necessary  to  show  here  how  one  derives  the  equilibrium 
situation  consonant  with  the  several  postulates  on  demand, ^^  oppor- 
tunity costs,  and  relative  position  of  countries,  i '^  Suffice  it  to  indicate 
that  country  C  consumes  5.7  units  of  steel  and  twice  as  much  textiles; 
B,  11.9  imits  of  steel,  and  twice  as  much  textiles;  and  A,  14.2  units  of 
steel  and  twice  as  much  textiles.  C  exports  to  B  12.7  units  of  textiles 
in  exchange  for  5.7  units  of  steel.  B  exports  to  A  14.2  units  of  steel  in 
exchange  for  63.5  units  of  ore,  4.4  of  textiles,  and  8331  transport  inputs. 
(These  data  together  with  data  on  outputs  and  raw  materials  and 
shipping  consumption  are  recorded  in  Table  IV.)  In  addition,  the 
exchange  ratio  of  textiles  for  steel  at  the  point  of  consumption  is  2.2 
to  unity  in  A  and  C,  and  2.0  to  unity  in  BA^ 

pay  A  4.8  units  of  textiles.  Thus,  to  obtain  the  ore,  coal,  and  shipping,  she  must 
pay  out  13.9  units  of  textiles  (or  its  equivalent)  which  requires  the  employment  of 
3.5  of  her  productive  units  since,  according  to  Table  I,  each  of  her  productive  units 
can  produce  4  units  of  textiles.  In  addition  another  productive  unit  is  engaged 
in  the  actual  manufacture  of  8  units  of  steel.  All  told,  B  must  devote  4.5  of  her 
productive  units  to  the  task  of  producing  and  delivering  8  units  of  steel  to  C.  Her 
productivity  in  steel  relative  to  the  market  in  C  is  1.8. 

To  produce  and  deliver  8  units  of  steel  to  C,  C  requires:  (1)  16  units  of  ore  for 
which  she  must  pay  A  2.7  units  of  textiles;  (2)  32  units  of  coal  for  which  she 
must  pay  B  6.4  units  of  textiles;  and  (3)  4800  transport  inputs  for  which  she  must 
pay  A  9.6  units  of  textiles.  Thus  she  must  pay  out  187  units  of  textiles  (or  its 
equivalent)  which,  according  to  Table  I,  requires  the  employment  of  9.3  of  her 
productive  units.  In  addition,  one  more  productive  unit  is  engaged  in  the  actual 
manufacture  of  steel.  All  told,  C  must  apply  10.3  of  her  productive  units  to  the 
job  of  producing  8  units  of  steel  for  her  own  consumption.  C's  productivity  in 
steel  relative  to  the  market  in  C  is  0.8.  Since  C's  productivity  in  this  case  is  less 
than  one-half  of  B's  (1.8),  B  has  comparative  advantage  in  producing  steel. 

If  B  has  comparative  advantage  over  C  in  producing  and  delivering  steel  to  the 
market  in  C,  for  which  market  B  has  least  absolute  advantage  over  C,  it  follows 
that  B  has  comparative  advantage  over  C  in  producing  and  delivering  steel  to 
the  markets  in  A  and  B,  for  which  markets  B's  absolute  advantage  is  greater. 
Hence,  B  produces  all  the  steel,  and  C  produces  onty  textiles.  (The  above  numer- 
ical results  and  those  to  follow  are  rounded  to  the  first  decimal  point.) 

16  The  reader  should  bear  in  mind  that  the  simplifying  assumption  concerning 
demand  is  not  basic  to  the  argument.  Any  other  assumption  is  equally  suitable, 
provided  it  does  not  unduly  complicate  computations. 

'^'^  The  reader  can  refer  to  Graham,  op.  cit.,  pp.  76-82,  for  a  demonstration  of 
how  a  final,  stable  exchange  situation  may  be  derived. 

It  should  also  be  noted  that  the  problem  can  be  set  up  in  a  linear  programming 
form.  This  has  been  done  by  John  S.  Chipman,  who  has  verified  in  this  maimer 
some  of  the  results  obtained. 

18  The  ratio  is  smaller  in  B  since  transport  input  requirements  are  smaller  in 
dehvering  to  the  market  in  B.    See  Table  II. 


INTERRELATIONS  OF  LOCATION,  TRADE  THEORY     215 

The  above  example  illustrates  how  the  basic  core  of  location  theory, 
namely,  transport-orientation,  can  be  fused  with  the  opportunity  cost 
doctrine  of  trade  theory  to  yield  a  superior  understanding  of  the 
simultaneous  determination  of  the  location  of  economic  activities  and 
of  trade.  Steel  production  is  concentrated  at  B.  This  result  is  ob- 
tained and  represents  a  case  of  transport-orientation,  whether  we  em- 
ploy the  traditional  (intranational)  location  approach  which  minimizes 
the  cost  of  transport  inputs  or  the  superior  approach  which  considers 
opportunity  cost  as  well.  From  the  standpoint  of  trade  theory  we  have 
introduced  explicitly  the  distance  factor  (in  the  concept  of  transport 
inputs)  and  shown  how  the  opportunity  cost  formulation  can  be  easily 
extended  to  embrace  industries  which  are  typically  transport-oriented 
intranationally.  The  extended  opportunity  cost  formulation  and  the 
improved  formulation  of  transport-orientation  are,  of  course,  one  and 
the  same. 

3.     The  Effects  of  a  Change  in  the  Distance  Variable  Upon 
Trade,  Industrial  Location,  and  Geographic  Specialization 

We  now  consider  the  implications  of  a  change  in  distance  relations. 
Are  trade  and  geographic  specialization  among  nations  and  regions 
significantly  dependent  upon  their  relative  position,  upon  the  absolute 
distances  separating  any  pair?i9  To  answer  this  basic  question,  alter 
the  relative  positions  of  the  three  countries  so  that  they  are  as  a 
straight  line,  200  distance  units  separating  A  and  B,  with  C  at  the 
midpoint,  100  distance  units  from  both  A  and  B.  See  the  line  diagram 
at  the  upper  right  hand  corner  of  Table  III.  Transport  input  require- 
ments are  simultaneously  changed  and  are  recorded  in  Table  III.  Note 
that  once  again  B  has  an  absolute  advantage  over  all  countries  in  pro- 
ducing steel  for  all  markets  because  (1)  the  prices  of  coal,  ore,  and 
transport  inputs  and  the  unit  requirements  of  coal  and  ore  are  the  same 
for  all  countries  as  potential  producers,  and  (2)  the  transport  input  re- 

19  Again  the  reader  is  reminded  that  provided  distances  are  not  so  great  as  to 
make  transport  cost  prohibitive  for  certain  commodities  and  thus  stifle  trade  in 
these  commodities,  trade  theory  (aside  from  Ohhn's  contribution)  has  usually 
presumed  that  variation  in  distances  and  hence  transport  costs  will  cause  variation 
in  the  divergences  of  exchange  values  in  the  several  countries  but  will  not  affect 
the  commodities  produced  and  traded  by  each  countrj'.  See,  for  example,  R.  F. 
Harrod,  International  Economics,  London,  1947,  p.  20;  Haberler,  op.  cit.,  pp.  140- 
42;  Viner,  op.  cit.,  pp.  314-18  and  467-70;  and  even  Graham,  op.  cit.,  pp.  139^6, 
who  perhaps  treats  transport  cost  more  realistically  than  any  of  the  above.  It 
should  be  noted  that  at  one  point  Viner  writes:  "In  fact,  differences  in  freight 
costs  may  create  a  comparative  advantage  which  in  the  absence  of  freight  costs 
would  not  exist  at  all"  (p.  470  note).  However,  this  pregnant  statement  is  left 
undeveloped. 


216 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


quirements  in  serving  each  market  are  least  for  B.  Thus,  B,  according 
to  orthodox  location  doctrine,  is  the  optimal  transport  point.  It  should 
be  the  point  of  steel  production  for  all  markets  (as  it  was  in  the 
triangular  situation)  provided  the  net  deviating  force  of  cheap  sites  of 

Table    III.     Transport    Input    Requirements    per    Weight    Unit    of 


Steel,  Given  Relative  Position: 


100 


100 


Country 
to  Which 
Delivered 

On  Coal 

On  Ore 

On  Steel 

Total 

A 

If  production  at  A 
If  production  at  B 
If  production  at  C 

800 

0 

400 

0 
400 
200 

0 
200 
100 

800 
600 
700 

B 

If  production  at  A 
If  production  at  B 
If  production  at  C 

800 

0 

400 

0 

400 
200 

200 

0 

100 

1,000 
400 
700 

C 

If  production  at  A 
If  production  at  B 
If  production  at  C 

800 

0 

400 

0 
400 
200 

100 

100 

0 

900 
500 
600 

labor  and  other  inputs  does  not  offset  the  transport  minimizing  force. 
The  resulting  stable  exchange  situation,  which  does  testify  to  the 
partial  dominance  of  the  deviating  force  of  cheap  labor  at  C,  is  pre- 
sented in  Table  IV,  along  with  the  old  exchange  situation  of  the 
triangular  setup. 20  The  new  situation  strongly  contrasts  with  the  old. 
C  now  produces  steel  for  both  itself  and  A.  There  are  new  geographic 
flows  of  ore,  transport  inputs,  and  textiles  from  A  to  C,  of  coal  from 
B  to  C,  of  steel  from  C  to  A,  and  of  textiles  from  B  to  A.  The  old  flows 
of  steel  from  B  to  A,  of  textiles  from  A  to  B,  and  of  steel  from  B  to  C 
have  been  eliminated.  The  only  flow  which  has  not  been  subject  to 
major  change  is  that  of  textiles  from  C  to  B.  In  sum,  changing  the 
distance  variable  as  we  did  almost  completely  revamps  the  geographic 
flow  of  commodities  and  the  structure  of  trade.     In  contrast,  the 

20 As  in  the  old  situation,  we  quickly  perceive  in  the  new  that:  (1)  A  should 
produce  all  the  ore,  all  the  shipping,  and  some  textiles;  (2)  B  should  produce  all 
the  coal  and  some  textiles;  and  (3)  C  should  produce  some  textiles.  Again,  the 
critical  question  is:  should  B,  C,  or  both  produce  steel?  If  he  cares  to,  the  reader 
can  make  the  necessary  computations  to  derive  an  answer  to  this  question  in  the 
same  manner  as  was  done  in  an  earlier  footnote  for  the  triangle  situation  (the 
following  footnotes  also  indicate  another  computational  approach).  The  results 
are:  {I)  B  produces  steel  for  its  own  market;  (2)  C  produces  steel  for  both  its 
own  and  A's  market. 


INTERRELATIONS  OF  LOCATION,  TRADE  THEORY    217 

resulting  changes  in  real  income  (consumption  of  the  finished  goods, 
textiles,  and  steel)   are  relatively  minor.21 

Thus  we  see  how,  once  trade  theory  is  extended  to  embrace  the 
realistic  situations  of  commodities  sensitive  to  differentials  in  trans- 
port cost,  the  distance  variable  can  have  a  major  influence  on  trade 
as  it  does  in  fact.  With  such  an  extension  the  criticisms  of  Weber  are 
met,  and  the  vague  intuitive  formulation  of  Ohlin  can  be  concretely 
expressed.  Although  one  example  (to  which  we  limit  ourselves  in  this 
chapter)  is  inadequate  to  point  up  in  full  the  implications  of  such  an 
extension,  it  develops  the  required  procedure  and  the  significance  of 
the  distance  factor. 

At  the  same  time  this  extension  represents  an  extension  of  location 
theory.  As  already  noted  in  the  line  position  case,  B  by  orthodox 
location  doctrine  is  the  optimal  transport  point  for  steel  production. 
However,  it  develops  that  B  produces  steel  for  its  own  consumption 
only  and  not  for  A  and  C.  This  result  obtains  because  B  has  compara- 
tive advantage  over  C  in  producing  steel  for  B's  internal  market  (costs 
being  expressed  in  terms  of  textiles)  but  comparative  disadvantage 
(though  still  absolute  advantage)  in  producing  steel  for  A  and  C.^^ 
The  required  restatement  of  location  doctrine  is  immediately  apparent: 
costs  must  be  expressed  as  opportunity  costs.  Thus,  a  transport- 
oriented  industry  must  be  defined  as  one  in  which  the  differential 
advantage  of  the  optimal  transport  point  completely  offsets  the  net 
differential  advantage  of  any  other  site  where  costs  are  expressed  in 
terms  of  a  commodity  produced  in  common  by  two  or  more  nationn. 
And  a  labor-oriented  industry  must  be  defined  as  one  in  which  the 
differential  advantage  of  a  cheap  labor  point  completely  offsets  the 
net  differential  advantage  of  any  other  site,  again  where  costs  are 
expressed  in  terms  of  a  commodity  produced  in  common.  In  the  tri- 
angle case,  B  was  the  optimal  transport  point,  and  in  terms  of  each 
market  its  transport  cost  advantage  more  than  offset  the  labor  cost 
advantage  of  C.  In  the  line  case  B  is  still  the  optimal  transport  point, 
but,  in  serving  the  markets  at  A  and  C  (but  not  at  5) ,  its  transport 

21  The  exchange  values  also  are  subject  to  some  change.  One  unit  of  textiles 
still  exchanges  for  6  of  ore,  for  500  of  shipping,  and  for  5  of  coal.  However,  in 
A,  1  unit  of  textile  exchanges  for  0.359  units  of  steel  as  against  0.448  of  steel  in 
the  triangular  situation;  in  B,  for  0.411  as  against  0.492;  and  in  C,  for  0.387  as 
against  0.448. 

22  In  terms  of  the  market  at  B,  1  productive  unit  in  B  (whose  opportunity  cost 
is  4  units  of  textiles)  can  produce  1.64  units  of  steel;  and  1  in  C  (whose  oppor- 
tunity cost  is  2  units  of  textiles),  0.72  units  of  steel.  In  terms  of  the  markets  at 
A  and  C,  1  productive  unit  in  B  can  produce  respectively  1.41  and  1.52  units  of 
steel;  and  in  C,  0.72  and  0.77  units  of  steel. 


218 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


I  § 
o  o 


^  o 
o   M 

Q     03 


Eh 

n  o 

Eh 


f^  l-H 


11 

o 
O 

0^.2 
CI  -tf 

t^  00  t^  CO 
1-1  O  ^  CO  (M 
(N  >— 1  (M  '^  CO 

10.5 

5.2 

35.5 

71.1 

11,916 

s*.2 
H.2 

CO  ca 

00  05  tq  o 
ci  ^  S  (M  CO 

'"S3 

CO  1> 

'S 

.a 

i 

a 

a 
1— 1 

o 

o 

<u   o 

^  a 
E^f2 

cq 

§1 

p-i 

00 

t>. 

II 

to 

^ 

a 
«.2 

"^    O 

^          lO 

i6       i6       CO 

bJO  O 

Ttl          lO 

^     2     ^ 
S3 

£3 

^1 

t^           t>^           00 

^        to        ^ 

t^  00          ^ 

05  d        ^" 

to  00 

II 

(M'           CO           ^ 
CO           CO           CO 

00  t^        o 

o 

a 
a 

6 

Textiles 

Steel 

Ore 

Coal 

Shipping 

Textiles 

Steel 

Ore 

Coal 

Shipping 

Textiles 

Steel 

Ore 

Coal 

Shipping 

> 

S-i 

<3 

^ 

CQ 

O 

INTERRELATIONS  OF  LOCATION,  TRADE  THEORY     219 

cost  advantage  is  more  than  offset  by  C's  labor  cost  advantage. 2  3 
Hence  the  steel  industry  in  the  straight  line  case  is  partially  transport- 
oriented  and  partially  labor-oriented.  Incidentally,  expressing  costs 
as  opportunity  costs  brings  out  the  significant  conclusion  that  industries 
which  have  traditionally  been  considered  transport-oriented  within 
a  national  framework  may,  because  the  international  set  of  cost 
differentials  diverge  considerably  from  the  national,  be  oriented  other- 
wise within  an  international  framework. 


4.     Some  Conclusions 

For  long-run  analysis  it  is  shown  how,  with  the  use  of  the  concept 
of  transport  inputs,  transport-orientation  and  the  opportunity  cost 
doctrine  can  be  fused  to  yield  a  superior  set  of  tools.  It  becomes 
possible  to  trace  the  impact  of  change  in  the  distance  variable  upon 
the  industrial  structure  (geographic  specialization)  of  each  country, 
the  composition  of  trade,  exchange  values,  and  the  magnitude  and 
characteristics  of  other  significant  elements  associated  with  the  simul- 
taneous determination  of  location  of  economic  activities  and  com- 
modity flows.  At  the  same  time  this  fusion  represents,  on  the  one  hand, 
an  extension  of  location  theory  since  the  traditional  cost  approach  of 
location  theory  is  reformulated  in  terms  of  opportunity  costs,  and,  on 
the  other  hand,  an  extension  of  long-run  trade  theory  since  commod- 
ities sensitive  to  differentials  in  transport  costs  are  introduced  into 
the  traditional  comparative  cost  framework.  By  this  achievement 
the  way  is  paved  for  each  type  of  theory  to  take  over  many  of  the 
sound  doctrines  of  the  other.  Practically  all  location  doctrine,  such 
as  labor  orientation,  power  orientation,  agglomeration,  etc.,  can  now  be 
adapted  and  employed  in  trade  theory;  and,  similarly,  all  developments 
in  long-run  trade  theory  can  be  adapted  and  employed  in  location 

-3  In  the  triangle  case,  to  produce  and  deliver  8  units  of  steel  to  C  requires : 
(1)  shipping  which  costs  4.8  units  of  textiles  if  production  is  at  B  and  9.6  units 
of  textiles  if  at  C ;  (2)  1  productive  unit  which  costs  4  units  of  textiles  at  B  and 
2  at  C;  and  (3)  ore  and  coal  whose  prices  are  identical  for  both  B  and  C.  Thus, 
B  has  a  differential  advantage  of  4.8  units  of  textiles  with  regard  to  transport  and 
a  differential  disadvantage  of  2  units  of  textiles  with  regard  to  labor  and  other 
resources  contained  in  a  productive  unit.  The  transport  differential  is  the  greater; 
hence,  the  industry  is  transport-oriented  at  B. 

In  the  straight  line  case,  shipping  costs  8  units  of  textiles  if  production  is  at  B 
and  9.6  units  if  at  C;  1  productive  unit  is  still  required  whose  cost  is  4  at  5  and 
2  at  C.  The  differential  in  the  cost  of  the  productive  unit  is  now  greater.  As  a 
result,  in  serving  the  market  at  C  the  industry  becomes  oriented  (presumably 
labor-oriented)  to  the  cheap  site  of  the  productive  unit,  namely  C. 


220  LOCATION  AKD  SPACE-ECONOMY 

theory.    Actually  to  perform  this  adaptation,  however,  would  require 
more  extended  treatment  than  is  possible  in  this  volume. ^  4 

24  The  reader  is  again  reminded  that  other  relations  of  location  theory  and 
trade  theory,  particularly  the  short-run  aspects  of  trade  theory,  will  be  discussed 
in  a  second  volume.  Certain  of  these  have  been  pointed  up  in  W.  Isard,  "Location 
Theory  and  Trade  Theory  .   .   .,"  op.  cit. 

Also  the  reader  is  referred  to  Gottfried  von  Haberler's  "A  Survey  of  Inter- 
national Trade  Theory,"  Special  Papers  in  International  Economics,  No.  1, 
September  1955,  Princeton  University  Press,  Princeton,  New  Jersey,  for  a  brief, 
but  penetrating,  statement  on  the  directions  in  which  one  should  approach  the  goal 
of  fusing  trade  and  location  theory. 


Chapter 


10 


Aspects  of  General  Location 

Theory:    A  Mathematical 

Formulation 


The  previous  chapters,  particularly  Chaps.  5  to  8,  have  treated  several 
types  and  elements  of  location  theory  in  a  manner  which  emphasized 
their  interrelations  and  interconnections.  The  substitution  framework 
was  advanced  as  a  means  of  pointing  up  these  interrelations  and  inter- 
connections better.  In  this  chapter  we  shall,  in  one  sense,  repeat  the 
argument,  though  more  explicitly  and  cogently  through  the  use  of 
mathematical  symbols.  Yet,  more  important,  we  shall  try  to  probe 
deeper  and  indicate  more  effectively  how  the  substitution  framework 
coupled  with  the  concept  of  transport  inputs  permits  at  least  a  partial 
fusion  of  the  several  location  dogmas  not  only  with  each  other  but  also 
with  much  of  production  theory.  We  hope  (1)  to  demonstrate  more 
satisfactorily  the  pervasiveness  of  a  general  principle  of  an  optimum 
space-economy,^  and  (2)  to  signify  how,  when  supported  by  appropriate 

^  The  space-economy  will  be  assumed  to  operate  imder  a  set  of  conditions  cus- 
tomarily postulated  by  economists.  To  the  same  extent  that  the  postulates  are 
unacceptable  to  the  reader,  the  ensuing  analysis  wiU  be  devoid  of  significance.  For 
a  dissent  from  the  profit  maximization  (or  cost  minimization)  principle  tj^pical  of 
human  ecologists  and  economists  of  similar  inclinations,  see  Kenneth  E.  Boulding, 
A  Reconstruction  of  Economics,  John  Wiley  &  Sons,  Inc.,  New  York,  1950,  Chaps. 
1  and  2. 

Also,  it  is  recognized  that  the  term  optimum  can  be  interpreted  in  several  different 
ways.  The  analysis  that  follows  will  be  concerned  with  an  optimum  space-economy, 
primarily  from  a  location  standpoint  with  emphasis  on  transportation  costs.  Further, 
we  approach  the  problem  only  in  terms  of  an  economy  with  given  transport  facilities 
and  rate  structure.    Equally  important,  however,  is  an  approach  which  attempts  to 

221 


222  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

side  conditions  and  other  hypothesized  relations,  this  principle  implies 
various  existing  location  theories,  and  therefore  must  be  considered  a 
core  element  of  a  general  theory  of  location. 

1.  Weberian  Theory  Restated  and  Generalized 

Imagine  a  general  spatial  transformation  function  as 

(1)    (j){yi,  yo,  •  ■  •  ,  Vk)  niASA,  niBSB,  ■  ■  ■  ,  mLSL]  Xk+i,  Xk+2,  ■  ■  ■  ,  Xn)  =0 

where  the  variables  yi,  Vz,  •  ■  •  ,  Vk  represent  quantities  of  various  inputs 
other  than  transport  inputs;  ulaSa,  msSB,  •  •  •  ,  miSL  represent  quanti- 
ties of  various  transport  inputs,  and  Xk+i,  Xk+2,  •  ■  •  ,  Xn  represent 
quantities  of  various  outputs.  In  this  formulation,  niA,  rriB,  •  •  •  ,  rriL 
represent  the  weights  of  various  raw  materials  and  finished  products 
subject  to  shipment,  and  Sa,  Sb,  •  ■  ■  ,  sl  represent  the  distances  the 
respective  raw  materials  and  products  are  moved.  By  definition,  miSi 
represents  transport  inputs  (say,  ton-miles  of  transportation)  involved 
in  the  shipment  of  the  raw  material  I  from  its  source  (s)  to  the  site  of 
production,  or  the  product  /  from  this  site  to  the  consumption  point  (s). 
Transport  inputs  are  explicitly  set  apart  in  this  function,  for  a  study 
of  their  variation  is  basic  to  an  understanding  of  the  operation  of  the 
space-economy.  To  facilitate  this  study,  we  shall  start  the  analysis  at  a 
very  simple  level  and  assume  the  Weberian  problem  of  transport 
orientation.2  Given  the  locational  triangle  IJC  in  Fig.  42  where  points  / 
and  J  each  represent  a  unique  source  of  a  raw  material  and  C  the  mar- 
ket point,  find  in  this  enclosed  area  the  location  for  the  point  of  pro- 
duction that  minimizes  total  transportation  costs  per  unit  of  output. 
This  problem  is  subject  to  the  postulate  that  prices  and  the  required 
amounts  per  unit  of  output  of  all  inputs  (including  raw  materials) 
except  transport  inputs  are  invariant  with  the  site  of  production.    The 

determine  the  transport  network  and  rate  structure  simultaneously  with  the  location 
of  economic  activities.  Excellent  analyses  of  an  optimum  transportation  system, 
given  the  geographic  distribution  of  economic  activities,  are  to  be  found  in  T.C. 
Koopmans,  "Optimum  Utilization  of  the  Transportation  System,"  Econometrica, 
Vol.  17  (July  1949),  Supplement,  pp.  136-46;  and  T.  C.  Koopmans  and  S.  Reiter, 
"A  Model  of  Transportation"  and  G.  B.  Dantzig,  "Apphcation  of  the  Simplex 
Method  to  a  Transportation  Problem,"  in  Activity  Analysis  of  Production  and  Alloca- 
tion (ed.  by  T.  C.  Koopmans),  John  Wiley  &  Sons,  Inc.,  New  York,  1951,  Chaps. 
XIV  and  XXIII,  respectively.  Also,  see  M.  Beckmann,  "A  Continuous  Model  of 
Transportation,"  Econometrica,  Vol.  20  (October  1952),  pp.  643-60. 

It  seems  very  likely  that  the  analysis  developed  in  this  chapter  will  also  prove 
valid  for  an  optimum  space-economy  where  the  character  of  the  transport  rate 
structure  is  also  viewed  as  variable  and  to  be  determined. 

^  Alfred  Weber's  Theory  of  Location  of  Industries,  ed.  by  C.  J.  Friedrich,  University 
of  Chicago  Press,  Chicago,  1929,  Chap.  III. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     223 

only  variables  are  the  three  transport  inputs  miSi,  mjSj,  and  mcSc; 
since  mi  and  mj  are  fixed  and  mc  is  taken  as  unity,  transport  inputs  vary 
simply  because  distances  vary. 

Since  total  revenue  and  costs  on  all  inputs  (except  transport  inputs) 
are  thus  fixed,  the  firm's  customary  problem  of  maximizing  profits 


V 


Piyi  -  P2y2 


PkVk   —  TaMaSa   —  VBiriBSB 


(2) 


—  rLiriLSL  +  Pk+lXk+l   +  Pk+2Xk+2   +   •   •   •   +  PnXn, 


Fig.  42.    A  locational  triangle. 


where  pi,  p2,  •  •  •  ,  Pn  are  prices,  and  va,  Tb,  •  •  •  ,  tl  are  transport  rates, 
is  reduced  to  the  problem  of  minimizing  transport  costs, 

(3)  K  =  rtmisi  +  rjirijSj  +  rcmcSc- 

Either  in  maximizing  profits  or  minimizing  transport  costs,  the  firm  is 
restrained  by  the  spatial  transformation  function  of  Eq.  1  which  in  the 
latter  case  becomes  simply 


(4) 


f(si,  sj,  sc)  =  0, 


and  implies  that  the  firm  must  choose  quantities  of  transport  inputs  con- 
sistent with  measuring  the  three  distances  Si,  sj,  and  sc  from  a  com- 
mon point  P  within  the  locational  triangle  (see  Fig.  42). 

A  necessary  and  sufficient  condition  that  within  the  locational  tri- 
angle P  be  a  stationary  point  of  K  is  that 


(5) 


dK  =  d{rimisi)  -{-  dirjmjSj)  -f-  d(rcmcSc) 


224  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

or  that 

ri  d{mjSj) 


(6) 


rj  d{misi) 

ri  _  d(mcSc) 

re  dimiSi) 

rj  d{mcSc) 


(mcSc)  =  const. 
(mjSj)  =  const. 
(miSi)  =  const. 


re  d{mjsj) 

Equations  (6)  obtain  since 

(7)  diriMiSi)  =  rid{miSi)  {i  =  /,  J,  C), 

for,  by  definition,  ri  is  fixed.  The  right-hand  terms  in  Eqs.  6  represent 
the  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  the  respective  transport 
inputs.  Of  Eqs.  6,  any  two  conditions  are  necessary  and  sufficient, 
since  with  Eq.  4  any  two  imply  the  third. ^  We  thus  have  three  equa- 
tions to  determine  the  three  unknowns. 

For  the  stationary  value  to  be  a  minimum,  i.e.,  a  point  of  minimum 
transport  cost,  it  is  sufficient  that  the  second  derivative  be  positive  along 
any  arbitrary  straight  line  through  P.^    Since  along  any  such  line 

(8)  d^'^^  {i  =  I,J,C), 

where  u  is  the  arc  length  on  an  arbitrary  line  along  which  the  derivative 
is  evaluated  and  where  the  equality  cannot  hold  for  all  values  of  i  in 
this  Weberian  problem  of  fixed  Wi  and  ri, 

The  transport  cost  surface  is  everywhere  convex  downward  and  of 
necessity  there  is  only  one  minimum  point. 

In  terms  of  the  space-economy,  Eqs.  6  state  the  important  condition 
that  at  the  point  of  minimum  transport  cost,  the  marginal  rate  of  substi- 
tution between  any  two  transport  inputs,  the  other  held  constant,  must 
equal  the  reciprocal  of  the  ratio  of  their  prices,  namely,  the  corresponding 
transport  rates. 

^  For,  since  all  directional  derivatives  of  the  transport  cost  function  are  con- 
tinuous, the  vanishing  of  the  derivative  of  the  function  in  two  directions  at  point 
P  (in  our  case,  let  us  say  along  the  two  arcs  where  sc  and  sj  in  turn  are  constant) 
implies  that  the  derivative  vanishes  in  all  directions  (for  example,  along  the  arc 
where  s/  is  constant). 

■*  If  such  is  the  case,  it  follows  that  in  a  neighborhood  of  P,  total  cost  increases 
with  any  arbitrary  movement  away  from  P.  Therefore  P  must  be  a  minimum  point. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     225 

The  above  condition,  it  must  be  emphasized,  holds  when  the  mini- 
mum transport  cost  point  is  not  at  one  of  the  vertices  of  the  triangle, 
i.e.,  when 

{rimiY  <  (vj-mj  cos  dtj  +  rkruk  cos  diu)^ 

(10)  +  irjUij  sin  dij  +  Vkmic  sin  Oik)^ 

{i^j^  k;i,j,k  =  I,J,C), 

where  dij  and  dik  are  angles  cut  off  by  an  arbitrary  straight  line  through 
i  and  directions  i  toj  and  i  to  k,  respectively.^ 

In  words,  if  we  conceive  the  problem  as  one  of  the  equilibrium  of 
forces,^  the  magnitude  of  the  resultant  of  the  forces  (locational  pulls) 
acting  from  any  two  corners  on  the  third  corner  is  greater  than  the 
magnitude  of  the  force  (locational  pull)  acting  from  the  third. ^ 

The  fact  that  any  one  of  the  inequalities  of  Eqs.  10  does  not  hold  is 
necessary  and  sufficient  that  the  point  corresponding  to  i  be  the  minimum 
transport  cost  point.  In  a  movement  away  from  i  the  marginal  rate  of 
substitution  between  transport  inputs  associated  with  i  and  transport 
inputs  associated  with  any  other  corner  y  is  then  given  by: 

(11)  '-1  ^    ''('"'■^'■) 


d{miSi) 


rrikSk  =  const. 


Economically  speaking,  this  means  that  any  small  movement  away  from 
the  transport  optimum  point  along  a  path  for  which  transport  inputs  to 

^  In  Fig.  42  we  illustrate  for  i  =  J,  j  =  C,  and  k  =  I. 

^  See  Alfred  Weber's  Theory  of  Location  of  Industry,  op.  cit.,  pp.  227-32. 

'  When  any  one  of  the  inequaUties  of  Eqs.  10  does  not  hold,  and  this  can  be  true  of 
only  one  of  the  three  which  compose  the  set,  three  types  of  cases  may  be  dis- 
tinguished (1)  when  viin  >  mp-j  +  rrihrk.  This  corresponds  to  the  Weberian  cate- 
gory where  one  raw  material  or  the  product  is  dominant;  (2)  when  one  of  the 
inequalities  of  Eqs.  10  becomes  an  equaUty.  Here,  in  the  direction  of  the  resultant 
force,  the  slope  of  the  transport  cost  surface  vanishes  as  point  i  is  reached  from  within 
the  triangle.  However,  in  all  other  directions,  the  directional  derivative  f^  0 
as  i  is  approached;  (3)  when  one  of  the  inequalities  of  Eqs.  10  is  reversed  but  type 
(1)  does  not  obtain.  Here,  as  in  type  (1),  all  directional  derivatives  5^  0  as  t  is 
approached. 

As  Dean  has  neatly  pointed  out,  in  cases  of  type  (1)  Weber's  emphasis  on  weight 
loss,  purity,  and  addition  of  ubiquities  is  correctly  placed;  however,  in  cases  of 
types  (2)  and  (3)  "the  only  pertinent  concerns  are  relative  gross  weight  and  rela- 
tive distance."  (W.  H.  Dean,  Jr.,  The  Theory  of  the  Geographic  Location  of  Economic 
Activities,  Selections  from  the  doctoral  dissertation,  Edward  Brothers,  Inc.,  Ann 
Arbor,  Mich.,  1938,  p.  19.)  Tliis  is  clear  from  inequaUties  of  Eqs.  10.  Weber  and 
others  who  have  employed  his  concepts  have  "...  seriously  overestimated  the  deter- 
minate influence  upon  location  of  weight-losing  materials,  when  they  are  not 
dominant,  and  underestimated  the  attractiveness  of  pure  materials,  which  are 
never  dominant"  (ibid.). 


226  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

or  from  k  is  constant  involves  savings  of  transport  cost  on  one  set  of 
transport  inputs  which  are  smaller  than  (or  in  an  extreme  case,  equal 
to)^  the  additional  outlays  on  the  other  set  of  transport  inputs. 

We  now  extend  the  problem  and  consider  the  shipment  of  many  raw 
materials  to  a  production  point  and  of  product  (s)  to  many  consuming 
points  (i'  variable  distances). 

The  transport  cost  equation  with  f  terms 

(12)  K  =  TAtnASA  +  rsniBSB  +  •  •  •  +  rimLSL 
is  subject  to  (i"  —  2)  restraints 

(13)  0^(s^,  SB,  •  •  •  ,  Sl)  =  0         (t  =  1,  ■  •  •  ,  i-  -  2), 

since  the  determination  of  the  values  for  any  two  of  the  distance  vari- 
ables necessarily  determines  the  values  of  all  the  others.  There  are 
only  two  independent  variables. 

As  in  the  case  of  thi^ee  distance  variables,  a  necessary  and  sufficient 
condition  that  a  point  P,  not  coinciding  with  any  raw  material  or  con- 
sumption site,  be  a  stationary  point  is  that 


Ti  d{mjsj) 


Tj  diniiSi) 


L 


XI  ricnikSk  =  const. 

■.=A 


Of  these  equations,  any  two  imply  the  rest.®  These  two  together  with 
the  f  —  2  restraints  determine  the  f  unknowns. 

For  the  stationary  point  to  be  a  minimum  it  is  sufficient  that  the 
second  derivative  be  positive  along  any  arbitrary  straight  line  through 
P,  which  is  the  case  as  shown  above. 

However,  the  above  conditions  exist  only  when  P  does  not  coincide 
with  any  raw  material  or  consumption  site.  The  sufficient  and  neces- 
sary conditions  that  P  does  coincide  with  any  such  site  are  exactly 
analogous  to  those  stated  above  for  three  distance  variables  except 
that  there  are  (i'  —  1)  terms  in  each  of  the  parentheses  of  inequalities 
of  Eqs.  10.     In  a  movement  away  from  corner  i  the  marginal  rate  of 

^  This  extreme  case  occurs  when  one  of  the  inequaUties  of  Eqs.  10  becomes  an 
equaUty  and  when  the  movement  is  at  the  same  time  along  the  path  of  the  result- 
ant acting  on  corner  i. 

^  Except  in  the  extreme  case  where  the  curve  (defined  by  2Za=4  rkmuSk  =  const.; 
j  9^  k  7^  i)  along  which  the  first  of  the  derivatives  is  taken  is  tangent  at  P  to  the 
other  curve  along  which  the  second  of  the  derivatives  is  taken.  In  such  a  case  the 
two  equations  are  not  independent,  and  a  second  independent  equation  must  be 
introduced. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     227 

substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs  is  then  given  by: 


^       dinijSj) 


(15)  Tj  d{miSi) 


L 

^  rkVikSk  =  const. 


U^k^i){i,j  =  A,---  ,L). 

In  words,  Eqs.  14  state  that  at  the  point  of  minimum  transport  cost,  the 
marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs,  total 
cost  on  all  other  transport  inputs  being  held  constant,  must  equal  the 
reciprocal  of  the  ratio  of  their  prices,  namely,  the  corresponding  transport 
rates.  This  statement  applies,  however,  only  to  a  minimum  transport 
cost  point  which  does  not  coincide  with  a  raw  material  or  consumption 
site.  Such  correspondence  will  exist  when  the  locational  pull  at  any  site 
exceeds  (or  in  an  extreme  case,  just  equals)  the  combined  locational 
pulls  of  other  sites.  Then,  according  to  Eqs.  15,  any  small  movement 
away  from  such  a  site  along  any  path  for  which  total  costs  on  all  trans- 
port inputs  but  two  are  constant  may  involve  a  saving  on  expenditures 
for  one  of  these  transport  inputs,  but  a  saving  which  is  less  than  (or,  in 
an  extreme  case,  just  equal  to)  the  additional  expenditures  on  the  second 
of  these  transport  inputs. ^° 

Equations  14  have  some  interesting  implications.  If  the  P  transport 
inputs  are  arbitrarily  divided  into  any  two  groups,  ^^  say,  for  example, 
transport  inputs  on  raw  materials  and  transport  inputs  on  products, 
and  if  for  each  group  a  set  of  constant  total  cost  curves  (generalized 
isotims)  is  constructed,  the  point  of  minimum  transport  cost  P  is  a 
point  of  tangency  between  two  of  these  constant  total  cost  curves,  one 
from  each  set.    For,  employing  vector  notation,  at  P 

F  L 

(16)  grad  K  =  grad  ^  miViSi  +  grad  XI  f^^j^jSj  =  0 

i=A  j=G 

and  by  hypothesis  each  constant  total  cost  curve  in  groups  one  and 
two  is  of  the  form 

F 

(17)  E  niiViSi  =  Ci 

i=A 
L 

(18)  XI  mjTjSj  =  C2 
i  =  G 

^^  See  Chap.  5  for  some  parallel  geometric  presentation. 

^^  It  is  relevant  to  consider  this  phase  of  the  problem  since  in  reality  there  are 
marked  differentiations  in  transport  rate  structures.  For  example,  on  the  whole 
raw  materials  bear  a  significantly  lower  rate  than  finished  products;  movement  in 
one  direction  may  entail  rates  markedly  different  from  those  for  movement  in  a 
second  direction;  shipments  over  one  major  type  of  transport  facility  usually  incur 
charges  different  from  those  for  shipments  over  a  second  major  type.  We  shall 
merely  sketch  how  analysis  of  substitution  between  groups  of  transport  inputs  may 
proceed. 


228  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

respectively,  where  Ci  and  C2  are  constants.     Since  at  each  point  of 

F 

any  curve  defined  by  Eq.  17,  grad    ^3    miTiSi  has  a  direction  normal 

L 

to  the  curve,  and  likewise  for  grad  ^  mjTjSj  at  each  point  of  each  curve 

j  =  G 

defined  by  Eq.  18,  these  two  gradients  can  be  in  opposite  directions  at 
a  point  (as  required  by  Eq.  16)  only  when  the  respective  curves  passing 
through  that  point  are  tangent  to  each  other.  In  terms  of  the  familiar 
Edgeworth-type  box  diagram,  ^^  where  the  two  families  of  curves  may 
be  for  illustrative  purposes  alone  taken  to  represent  Eqs.  17  and  18,  it 
is  always  possible  to  reduce  total  costs  on  each  of  the  two  groups  of 
transport  inputs  by  shifting  location  from  a  point  not  a  point  of  tangency 
to  some  point  which  is  a  point  of  tangency.  However,  in  contrast  to 
the  Edgeworth  solution  Eq.  16  states  more.  Of  all  the  possible  points 
of  tangency  there  is  one  which  is  the  best,  namely,  the  one  at  which  the 
two  gradients  are  not  only  opposite  in  direction,  but  also  equal  in 
magnitude. 

For  policy  purposes,  a  more  generally  useful  approach  in  treating 
groups  of  transport  inputs  is  to  replace  actual  weights  by  ideal  weights 
a  la  Weber.  A  finished  product  with  a  representative  transport  rate 
may  be  taken  as  the  standard  for  all  finished  products.  The  weight 
of  any  given  finished  product  can  be  adjusted  upward  or  downward 
according  as  its  rate  is  greater  or  smaller  than  that  for  the  standard 
finished  product.  One  thousand  tons  of  product  X  moving  at  a  rate 
three-quarters  that  of  the  standard  product  would  have  an  ideal  weight 
of  750  tons.  Likewise,  ideal  weights  of  raw  materials  can  be  derived 
with  respect  to  a  standard  raw  material. 

It  then  follows  from  Eq.  12  that  since  the  rates  are  the  same  for  all 
transport  inputs  of  a  group,  at  P 

L 

(19)  '-^--^^ 


dT. 


mrsi 


where  Wi*  and  rrij*  are  ideal  weights. 

Under  this  circumstance,  at  the  optimum  location,  the  marginal 
rate  of  substitution  between  the  two  groups  of  transport  inputs  must 
be  equal  to  the  reciprocal  of  the  ratio  of  the  corresponding  transport 
rates. 

Hitherto,    transport   rates   proportional   to   distance   and   a   space- 

^^  For  example,  see  W.  F.  Stolper  and  P.  A.  Samuelson  "Protection  and  Real 
Wages,"  Review  of  Economic  Studies,  Vol.  IX  (November  1941),  p.  67. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     229 

economy  which  is  continuous  transportationwise  have  been  postulated. 
Needless  to  say,  the  real  world  differs  considerably  from  such  a  fiction 
and  accordingly  it  is  important  to  explore  needed  modifications  of  the 
above  analysis.    We  wish  to  make  a  few  preliminary  comments  here. 

Typically,  with  modern  transport  media,  there  is  an  initial  terminal 
and  loading  charge  incurred  by  any  shipment,  invariant  with  distance 
of  the  shipment,  and  in  addition  a  line  charge  where  the  rate  per  ton-mile 
tends  to  be  a  decreasing  function  of  distance.  Consider  first  the  effect 
of  the  line  charge  alone. 

Letting,  Vi  =  Vi  (si),  from  Eq.  12  we  have: 

L 

(20)  dK  =    J2  '^iiri  +  Sir/)dsi 

where  r^   =  -—  • 
asi 

The  necessary  and  sufficient  condition  that  P  not  coinciding  with  any 
raw  material  or  market  site  be  a  stationary  point  of  K  is  that  the 
following  relations  hold  at  P:^^ 

Ti  +  Sir/  dimjSj) 

(zlj 


^i  +  SjTj'  d{miSi) 


L 

^  TknikSk  =  const. 

k=A 


i,j  =  A,---  ,L. 

Here,  in  contrast  with  the  situation  where  transport  rates  are  propor- 
tional to  distance  there  need  not  be  one  and  only  one  stationary  point 
and  a  stationary  point  which  is  necessarily  a  minimum.  For  along  any 
arbitrary  straight  line  through  P, 

L 

(22)        d^K  =    X^  mdin  +  Sir/)(d^Si)  +  (2r/  +  s^r/'){dsiy]. 

i  =  A 

The  first  term  in  the  brackets  is  necessarily  non-negative,  whereas  the 
second  term  can  be  both  positive  and  negative,  though  usually  nega- 
tive.^* Thus  d^K  can  be  both  positive  and  negative.  For  point  P  to  be 
a  transport  optimum  point,   the  usual  second-order  quadratic   form 

^^  Provided  the  two  relations  are  independent.     See  footnote  9  of  this  Chapter. 

^^  The  first  term  is  non-negative  since  d'^Si  is  non-negative,  and  since  to,-  (ri  +  Si  r/) 
is  the  partial  derivative  of  total  transport  cost  (K)  with  respect  to  Sj  and  thus 
necessarily  positive. 

The  expression  (2ri'  +Siri")  measures  the  rate  of  change  of  slope  of  nii  ri  Sj 
as  Si  and  r,  alone  vary.  In  modern  rate  structures  r/  tends  to  be  negative.  Also, 
Ti"  is  typically  positive  but  not  sufficiently  so  that  s,- r/'  >  —  2ri';  i.  e.,  miViSiis 
typically  concave  downward  as  a  function  of  Sj. 


230  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

conditions  for  a  minimum  must  be  satisfied;  if  more  than  one  stationary 
point  satisfy  these  conditions,  then,  obviously,  by  direct  calculation,  of 
these  points  P  must  incur  least  total  transport  cost.^^ 

In  economic  terms,  the  first-order  conditions  of  Eqs.  21  state  that  the 
marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs  must 
equal  the  reciprocal  of  the  ratios  of  their  modified  transport  rates,  each 
modified  transport  rate  being  equal  to  the  actual  transport  rate  for 
distance  Si  adjusted  for  the  saving  or  added  expense  per  ton-mile  result- 
ing from  the  change  in  the  rate  that  would  ensue  from  a  small  change  in 
the  distance  variable  Si. 

When,  in  addition  to  a  line  charge,  there  is  an  initial  terminal  and 
loading  charge,  a  minimum  must  exist  at  each  raw  material  and  market 
site.  An  infinitesimal  movement  in  any  direction  from  such  a  site 
involves  a  significant  initial  charge  which,  in  reality,  far  exceeds  the 
transport  cost  savings  that  may  be  realized  by  diminishing  other 
transport  inputs.  Also,  for  the  same  reason,  a  minimum  will  exist  at 
each  point  corresponding  to  a  break  in  the  transportation  network, 
where  an  additional  transshipment,  loading,  or  other  charge  is  levied. 
However,  the  conditions  that  P  not  coinciding  with  any  raw  material 
or  market  site  or  break  be  a  minimum  point  remain  unaltered. ^^ 

Thus,  terminal  and  loading  charges,  transshipment  expenses  at  breaks, 
special  transit  privileges  at  particular  junction  points,  and  other  trans- 
port rate  abnormalities  introduce  discontinuities  into  the  transport  cost 
surface.  Pictorially  the  entire  transport  cost  surface  is  raised  by  the 
sum  of  all  the  initial  terminal  and  loading  charges,  transshipment 
expenses,  and  the  like  except  at  each  raw  material,  market,  junction,  or 
special  privilege  site  where  the  surface  is  punctured.  Each  punched  out 
point  is  raised  not  by  the  sum  of  these  charges  and  expenses  but  by  the 
sum  less  the  charge  or  expense  encountered  in  movement  from  the 
corresponding  site.  As  a  consequence,  the  space-economy  tends  to 
comprise  a  hierarchical  set  of  focal  points  of  different  degrees  of  domi- 


^^  The  full  statement  of  second-order  conditions  may  be  found,  for  example,  in 
P.  A.  Samuelson,  op.  cit.,  Mathematical  Appendix  A. 

It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  in  a  specific  location  problem  one  can  avoid 
the  cumbersome  quadratic  form  conditions  with  complicated  side  relations  by 
calculating  d'^K  directly  with  d~Si  and  dsi  expressed  as  trigonometric  functions  of 
angles  formed  at  P  by  the  lines  from  P  to  Pi  and  the  line  along  which  d'^K  is 
evaluated. 

A  necessary  and  sufficient  condition  that  P  coinciding  with  a  raw  rnaterial  or 
market  site  Pi  be  a  minimum  point  is  that  the  inequalities  of  Eqs.  10  extended  to 
embrace  f  variables  is  not  valid  where  ry  is  replaced  by  (ry  +  Sj  r/),  j  =  A,  ■  ■  ■,  L. 

^^  However,  it  is  unlikely  with  modern  rate  structures  that  P  will  be  an  absolute 
minimum  point.    For  full  elaboration  of  this  point  see  Chap.  5. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     231 

2.  Inclusion  of  Market  and  Supply  Areas  as  Variables 

In  the  previous  section  the  market  points  to  be  served  are  stipulated 
beforehand.  To  the  extent  that  there  are  many,  and  particularly  if 
there  is  an  infinite  number  in  an  area  of  approximately  continuous 
density,  the  above  location  analysis  may  be  said  in  a  sense  to  embrace 
market  area  theory.  But  in  a  major  respect  such  a  statement  would  be 
invalid.  Market  area  analysis  has  as  its  essential  core  the  problem  of 
demarcating  boundaries  and  consumers  to  be  served.  The  problems  of 
determining  transport  relations  and  sites  of  production  are  also  vital, 
but  only  in  a  framework  where  the  area  itself  is  a  variable.  ^^  The 
analysis  hitherto  developed  posits  a  fixed  market  area  and  is  thereby 
inapplicable. 

However,  it  is  not  difficult  to  extend  the  analysis  to  encompass  the 
market  area  (and  later,  the  supply  area)  as  a  variable.  The  initial  step 
is  to  state  the  condition  of  indifference  that  defines  the  market  boundary, 
which  we  take  to  be: 

F 

(23)  r*s*  +   X)  biriSi  =  T, 

i=A 

where  r*  represents  transport  rate  (with  regard  to  the  unit  of  product) 
to  the  boundary  line,  being  invariant  with  direction;^^  s*  represents 
radius  of  circle  defining  boundary  line;  A,  •  ■  ■  ,  F  denote  the  various  raw 
materials  required;  hi  represents  a  constant  coefficient  indicating  the 
number  of  units  of  raw  material  i  used  per  unit  of  product;  ri  represents 
transport  rate  on  a  unit  of  raw  material  i;  and  T  represents  the  difference 
between  the  maximum  price  po  the  consumer  is  willing  to  pay  and  the 
unit  costs  of  production  t  (excluding  transport  costs)  which  are  held 
constant  throughout  this  section  of  the  analysis.  Equation  23  states  that 
at  the  market  boundary  the  sum  of  the  transport  costs  on  the  unit 
product  and  on  the  raw  materials  required  to  yield  the  unit  product  is 

^^  See,  for  example,  W.  Launhardt,  Mathematische  Begriindung  der  Volkswirtschafts- 
lehre,  Leipzig,  1885,  Part  III;  F.  A.  Fetter,  "The  Economic  Law  of  Market  Areas," 
Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  XXXVIII  (May  1924),  p.  525;  O.  Englander, 
Theorie  des  Guterverkehrs  und  der  Frachtsdtze,  Jena,  1924;  T.  Palander,  Beitrdge  zur 
Standortstheorie,  Uppsala,  1935,  Chaps.  IX  and  XII;  E.  Schneider,  "Bemerkungen 
zu  einer  Theorie  der  Raumwirtschaft,"  Econometrica,  Vol.  Ill  (January  1935), 
pp. 79-89;  E.Hoover,  Location  Theory  and  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Industries,  Cambridge, 
Mass.,  1937,  Chaps.  Ill  and  V;  A.  Losch,  Die  rdumliche  Ordnung  der  Wirtschaft, 
Jena,  1944,  Part  II;  and  C.  D.  Hyson  and  W.  P.  Hyson,  "The  Economic  Law  of 
Market  Areas,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  LXIV  (May  1950),  pp.  319-327. 

^^  When  r*  is  not  invariant  with  direction,  the  resulting  market  area  is  non- 
circular.  The  ensuing  analysis,  however,  is  not  altered  save  that  visual  concep- 
tion becomes  more  difficult. 


232  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

just  equal  to  the  difference  between  unit  costs  of  production  and  the 
maximum  price  the  consumer  is  wilUng  to  pay. 

For  the  moment  it  is  useful  to  consider  the  simplified  case  where  each 
consumer  purchases  one  and  only  one  unit  of  product,  for  which  he  is 
wilHng  to  pay  a  maximum  price  po,  {po  =  T  +  ir),  but  for  which  he 
actually  pays  a  delivered  cost  price  (i.e.,  t  plus  transport  costs  on  raw 
materials  and  the  unit  of  product  he  purchases).  The  resulting  total 
(consumer  or  social)  surplus  is:^^ 


F  f* 

(24)  Tm  -  K  =^  Tm  -    Y.  miUSi  -    j  rs#(i 

i  =  A  d 


where  m  represents  number  of  units  produced  (consumed),  r  represents 
transport  rate  (with  regard  to  the  unit  of  product),  s  represents  distance 
from  P  to  the  consumer,  -^{s)  represents  the  quantity  consumed  inside 
circle  with  radius  s  and  center  at  P,  and  the  Stieltjes  integral  is  evaluated 
over  an  area  with  P  as  center  and  s*  as  radius. 
Since,  by  definition, 

(25)  m  =  r#(s) 
we  rewrite  Eq.  24: 

F 

(26)  Tm  -  K  =  Tm  -    X)  ^i^iSi  -  nirs 

i=A 

where  rs  represents  the  average  unit  cost  of  transporting  the  product 
from  P  to  all  consumers. 

To  maximize  surplus,^°  we  set: 

F 

(27)  d{Tm  -  K)  =  d{Tm)  -    ^  rid{miSi)  -  d{mTs)  =  0 

i=A 

which  with  Eq.  23  is  subject  to  (/  —  2)  restraints  expressing  as  before 
the  fact  that  only  two  of  the  Si  can  be  independent.    Equation  27  implies: 


(28)  (i^/c^^■)(^,i  =  ^,  •••,P) 


Ti 

d{mjSj) 

F 

rj 

d{miSi) 

Tm  - 

X)  fkiUkSk  —  mrs  =  const. 

k=A 

r 

d(mjsj) 

F 

rj 

d{ms) 

Tm  - 

12  rkmkSk  =  const. 

^^  See  below  in  text  and  footnote  25  for  some  discussion  of  the  concept  of  surplus. 

^^  The  problem  is  not  to  minimize  total  transport  cost  subject  to  Eq.  23  and 
the  (/  —  2)  restraints.  For  in  such  a  problem  P  would  tend  to  be  a  center  in  a 
market  area  containing  as  sparse  a  population  as  the  restraints  permit.  Clearly, 
this  is  not  optimum  from  a  social  standpoint. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     233 

Of  Eqs.  28  any  two  independent  ones  imply  all  the  rest.^^  These  two 
in  addition  to  Eq.  23  and  the  (/  —  2)  restraints  on  the  variation  of  the 
Si  determine  the  /  unknown  distances  and  s*.  Equations  28,  however, 
are  only  necessary  and  not  sufficient  conditions  for  a  maximum  point 
except  where  the  density  of  consumption  is  constant  throughout  the 
region, 22  and  perhaps  certain  other  special  cases.  It  is  easily  seen,  for 
example,  that  variation  in  consumer  density  over  a  region  may  lead  to 
relative  maxima  at  points  tending  to  be  central  with  respect  to  districts 
of  heavy  density  and  to  relative  minima  in  sparsely  populated  districts 
in  between.  As  before,  second-order  conditions  can  be  stated  to  dis- 
tinguish between  stationary  points,  and  the  best  of  the  maxima  can  only 
be  determined  by  direct  computation. 

Equations  28  state  that  at  the  point  of  maximum  surplus  the  marginal 
rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs  (transport  inputs 
on  the  product  being  equal  to  the  sum  of  transport  inputs  involved  in 
delivering  each  individual  unit  from  P)  is  equal  to  the  reciprocal  of  the 
ratio  of  their  transport  rates,  the  difference  between  Tm  and  total  costs 
on  all  other  transport  inputs  held  constant.^^  Also,  it  logically  follows 
that  the  point  of  maximum  surplus  is  the  point  of  minimum  total 
transport  cost  for  serving  the  market  area  defined  with  P  as  center. ^^ 

^^  Equations  27  and  28  and  others  to  follow  which  are  based  upon  Eq.  24  and 
others  which  employ  the  Stieltjes  integral  are  valid  only  when  the  Stieltjes  integral 

Irs  dip  (s)  is  differentiable  in  the  relevant  region.     The  Stieltjes  integral  rather 

than  the  Riemann  is  employed  since  the  Riemann  is  a  special  case  of  the  Stieltjes 
and  since  the  Riemann  cannot  be  used  as  the  Stieltjes  can  for  cases  where  discrete 
consumption  points  exist  at  finite  distances  from  the  boundary  line  within  a  market 
(or  supply)  area. 

^^  When  such  is  the  case,  the  point  of  minimum  transport  cost  on  raw  materials 
is  the  point  of  maximum  surplus  P.  Any  movement  away  from  P  increases  average 
cost  (K/m)  and  decreases  m,  and  thereby  decreases  surplus  {Tm  —  K).  Thus 
P  is  a  maximum. 

^^  Any  movement  away  from  P  resulting  from  the  substitution  of  a  transport 
input  on  one  raw  material  for  a  transport  input  on  a  second  raw  material  may 
involve  a  shrinking  or  expansion  of  the  circular  market  area  and  change  in  m  as 
well  as  change  in  the  other  distance  variables.  The  market  area  itself  can  of  course 
encompass  raw  material  sites. 

^*  Suppose  the  m  consumers,  contained  in  the  circle  with  P  as  center  and  s* 
as  radius,  could  be  served  with  lower  total  transport  costs  from  P',  necessarily 
not  forming  a  circular  area  around  P'.  P'  would  then  yield  greater  surplus.  But 
since  a  circular  area  with  center  at  a  production  site  will,  by  our  equations,  al- 
ways yield  greater  surplus  than  a  noncircular  area  around  the  same  point,  a  cir- 
cular area  around  P'  must  then  yield  still  greater  surplus  than  that  around  P. 
But  this  contradicts  the  fact  that  P  is  the  point  of  maximum  surplus.  Thus  P 
must  be  the  point  of  minimum  transport  cost  for  the  m  consumers. 

It  also  follows  that  at  P  average  transport  cost  (K/m)  for  the  given  market  is 


234  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

The  simplification  that  each  consumer  purchase  one  and  only  one  unit 
can  now  be  relaxed.  Without  specifying  the  nature  of  each  consumer's 
demand  function,  we  can  conceive  of:  (1)  a  firm,  located  at  one  site 
only,  levying  a  fixed  profit  a  per  unit;  or  (2)  each  consumer,  except 
when  he  is  on  the  boundary,  obtaining  per  unit  product  purchased  a 
surplus  jS  measured,  let  us  say,  by  the  difference  between  some  given 
price  and  the  lower  delivered  price  (tt  plus  costs  of  transportation) ;  or 
(3)  society  attributing  a  value  y  (in  addition  to  the  delivered  price  the 
consumer  pays)  to  the  consumption  of  each  unit.^^  In  each  of  these 
cases  and  a  multitude  of  others  that  the  reader  may  wish  to  construct, 
the  form  of  the  necessary  conditions  for  equilibrium  is  not  altered  though 
their  content  is. 

In  the  first  case  we  maximize 

(29)        am  =    j  {a  -\-  p  -  it)  #(s)  -  K  =   (a  -\-  p  -  7r)w  -  K 

where  p  represents  the  delivered  price  (excluding  the  profit  charge)  to 
consumers  at  s,  the  distance  from  P,  and  p  represents  an  average 
delivered  price  (excluding  profit  charge)  over  all  units  sold.  In  effect, 
Eq.  29  resembles  Eq.  26  except  that  (a  -\-  p  —  t)  has  been  substituted 
for  T.  The  form  of  the  necessary  conditions  for  a  maximum  in  this 
problem  resemble  those  expressed  in  Eqs.  27  and  28  for  the  previous 
problem,  save  that  (a  +  ^  —  tt)  is  always  substituted  for  T.^^  How- 
ever, the  path  along  which  substitution  of  transport  inputs  on  raw 
material  i  for  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  j  can  take  place  is  totally 
different.  In  such  a  substitution,  the  market  area  tends  to  shift,  expand, 
or  contract;  each  consumer  tends  to  alter  the  number  of  units  he  pur- 


at  a  minimum  which,  since 

d(-)  =d  Y.  binsi  +  d{rs)  =0 
\m/           i=A 

yields  the  relations, 

n            d{bjSj)       p                                          (■  ^]-  ^  i)(i    ■ 
Tj            d{hiSi)     Yl   h^kSk  +rs  =  const. 

=  A,-- 

■,F). 

These  relations  which  are  implied  by,  but  do  not  imply,  Eqs.  28  may  facilitate  test- 
ing the  stationary  character  of  points. 

^^  We  fully  appreciate  the  unreality  of  these  conceptions.  However,  since  eco- 
nomics has  not  yet  reached  the  stage  where  the  welfare  of  a  group  of  consumers 
can  be  quantitativelj'^  evaluated,  and  since  the  validity  of  the  relations  emphasized 
in  this  paper  is  independent  of  the  nature  of  any  welfare  function,  these  simple 
conceptions  suffice  for  the  immediate  purpose. 

^®  Also,  a  must  be  subtracted  from  T  in  Eq.  23. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     235 

chases;  and  thus  p  and  m  tend  to  change.  To  determine  a  path  of 
substitution  becomes  more  difficult. 

In  the  case  of  (2)  or  (3)  above,  we  merely  substitute  ;3  or  7  for  a  in 
all  the  equations.  The  form  of  the  necessary  equihbrium  conditions 
remains  the  same,  although  again  the  content  differs.^^ 

Heretofore,  we  have  posited  that  each  raw  material  originates  at  a 
single  point.  The  analysis  can  now  be  extended  to  embrace  raw  material 
supply  areas,  each  composed  of  any  number  of  originating  sites.  To  do 
so  with  respect  to  any  raw  material  i  requires  the  substitution  of 
y  TiSi  d\l/i{si)  or  miTiSi  for  the  term  miTiSi  in  the  above  equations  where 
\l/i{Si)  is  the  quantity  of  raw  material  i  supplied  within  a  circle  of  radius  Si 
and  P  as  center.  With  the  introduction  of  a  supply  (or  purchasing)  area 
for  any  raw  material  the  problem  is  changed  in  a  way  exactly  analogous 
to  the  way  it  was  changed  with  the  introduction  of  a  market  area.  The 
reader  will  find,  if  he  cares  to  reformulate  the  problem  mathematically, 
that  the  fundamental  form  of  the  substitution  relations  remains  un- 
changed, though  these  relations  bear  upon  different  paths  and  have 
different  content.  ^^ 

3.  The  Analysis  Extended  to  the  Case  of  Many  Producers 

Having  generalized  the  analysis  to  embrace  a  market  area,  variation 
in  consumption  patterns  over  space,  and  a  supply  area  for  each  raw 
material  where  such  areas  overlap  so  that  a  point  may  be  both  a  market 
site  and  a  site  at  which  several  raw  materials  originate,  we  now  proceed 
to  allow  more  than  one  production  site.  In  doing  this  we  could  maintain 
the  postulate  of  constant  unit  production  cost  (excluding  transporta- 
tion). We  would  then  obtain  a  statement  implying  geographic  patterns 
such  as  those  depicted  in  Palander  and  Hoover"^  where,  for  example, 
we  may  have  at  one  and  the  same  time  production:  (1)  at  raw  material 
sites,  each  serving  a  district  of  consumers,  (2)  at  each  point  along  a 
closed  elliptical-shaped  curve,  each  point  serving  the  consumers  in  the 

^^  Where  no  raw  materials  are  required  in  production,  Eqs.  23  and  27  become 
r*s*  =  T  and  d{Tm  —  K)  =  d(Tm)  —  d{mrs)  =  0.  The  radius  s*  is  thus  invar- 
iant with  production  site.  However,  if  we  wish  to  express  equihbrium  condi- 
tions in  terms  of  transport  inputs  and  not  in  terms  of  the  vanishing  of  the  partial  de- 
rivatives in  the  x  and  y  directions,  we  can  divide  transport  inputs  on  the  product 
into  three  or  more  subdivisions  of  transport  inputs,  each  corresponding  to  a  set 
of  consumers  asymmetrically  located.  The  analysis  would  proceed  as  above  where 
there  are  several  transport  inputs  to  consider. 

^^  Of  course,  substitution  can  now  involve  change  in  one  raw  material  supply 
area  vis-a-vis  change  in  another  raw  material  supply  area,  or  in  the  market  area, 
and  so  forth. 

2^  T.  Palander,  op.  ait.,  Chap.  VI;  and  E.  M.  Hoover,  op.  cit.,  pp.  53-55.  Also 
see  Fig.  44  below  and  the  accompanying  discussion  in  Chap.  11. 


236  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

hinterland  along  its  pole  line  only,  and  (3)  at  each  consumption  site 
contained  in  the  elliptical-shaped  curve,  each  such  site  meeting  its  ovm 
needs  only. 

However,  we  shall  not  dwell  upon  this  unrealistic  situation  which 
can  be  considered  a  special  case  of  the  more  general  type  which  allows 
variation  in  the  unit  cost  of  production  (as  Losch  does).  A  region  may 
be  conceived  as  divided  into  several  market  areas,  each  served  from  a 
production  site  and  bounded  on  all  sides.  As  before,  any  boundary  hne, 
not  a  boundary  hne  between  two  producers,  is  defined  by  a  condition 
corresponding  to  Eq.  23,  namely, 

F 

(30)  a,  +  r^*s,*  +   X  bi^iSi,  =  po,         (m  =  1,  •  •  •  ,  7?), 

where  a^  represents  the  marginal  production  costs  (excluding  trans- 
portation) at  site  P^,  and  Sj>  represents  the  distance  between  P^  and  the 
site  of  raw  material  i.^'^ 

Our  problem  is  to  maximize,  let  us  say,  social  surplus: 

7?n  ^  m{y  -\-  p  —  t)  —  K 
(31) 

F  V  V  _ 

=  w(7  +  p-7f)—    X)Z)  ^'''ii^^iSi^  -    J2  m^rs^, 

where  p  represents  the  average  delivered  price  on  all  units  produced 
(consumed) ;  if  represents  the  average  unit  production  costs  on  all  units; 
mt>  represents  the  total  weight  of  raw  material  i  used  by  producer  n; 
m^  represents  the  total  units  (weight)  of  product  consumed  in  market 

area  served  by  producer  ix;  and  rs^  =  —  /   rs^  #m(sm)  represents  the 

average  transport  cost  per  unit  of  product  in  shipping  the  product  from 
P„  to  customers  in  the  corresponding  market  area. 

^•^  We  have  defined  the  boundary  in  terms  of  marginal  production  cost  plus 
unit  transport  cost  rather  than  average  unit  production  cost  plus  unit  transport 
cost.  This  ensures  an  optimum  spatial  arrangement  for  society  as  a  whole,  but 
involves  a  net  loss  for  each  producer  when  he  is  producing  on  the  faUing  section 
of  his  average  cost  curve  and  when  dehvered  price  is  based  on  marginal  cost  at 
P^.  The  reader  may  substitute  ir^  (average  unit  production  cost)  for  a^  in  Eqs.  30 
and  in  subsequent  equations  which  define  boundary  conditions  among  producers. 
This,  however,  would  not  be  consistent  with  an  optimum  space-economy,  though 
of  course  it  would  be  consistent  with  an  optimum  space-economy  subject  to  the 
restraint  that  dehvered  prices  be  based  on  average  vmit  production  cost. 

Ttiis  problem,  which  hes  outside  the  scope  of  this  book,  has  been  treated  at  length 
in  the  hterature  on  welfare  economics.  Refer,  for  example,  to  A.  Bergson,  "Sociahst 
Economics,"  in  A  Survey  of  Conteviporary  Economics,  ed.  by  H.  S.  EUis,  Blakiston, 
Philadelphia,  1948,  pp.  424-28,  and  the  literature  cited  therein. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     237 

First,  it  should  be  noted  that  since  there  is  an  infinity  of  market  sites 
(consumers)  in  our  wholly  or  partially  continuous  areas,  one  may  treat 
an  infinity  of  variables,  the  distance  from  any  consumer  to  a  correspond- 
ing producer  being  a  variable.  However,  it  is  immediately  possible  to 
reduce  the  infinity  of  variables  to  a  finite  number  through  considering 
each  market  area  as  a  whole  and  introducing  boundary  conditions 
between  the  market  areas  of  any  two  producers.  Imagine  that  any  two 
producers  shift  their  common  boundary  within  any  small  element  of 
area  without  affecting  the  market  areas  and  outputs  of  other  producers. 
Let  the  first  obtain  dnip  new  sales  from  this  element  while  the  second 
lose  dmp  (=  —dm^)  sales.  If  ym  is  a  maximum,  such  a  shift  should  not 
reduce  total  costs  when  through  some  pricing  arrangement  the  intensity 
pattern  of  consumption  of  all  other  elements  in  the  two  market  areas  is 
held  unchanged,  as  it  can  be.  For,  if  this  were  not  so,  the  resulting 
decrease  in  total  costs  would  make  possible  an  increase  in  m  and  thus 
in  ym.    Therefore,  with  such  a  shift,  for  d(ym)  =  0,  we  must  have: 

diirpnip)  +  d(rpnipSp)  +  d[7np  ^  biriSipj 
(32) 

=  —diiTpmy)  —  diryniySv)  —  dim:,  ^  biriSipj 

where  Wp  and  Wy  represent  the  average  unit  production  costs  (excluding 
transportation)  of  producers  at  sites  Pp  and  Py,  respectively.     Since 

diiTpmp)  =  (Tp  dmp, 
(33) 

(dwymy)  =  (Tydmy  =  —ay  dmp, 
and  since 

d{mpSp)  =  Sp^  dnip, 
(34) 

d(mySy)  =  Sy^  dmy  =  —Sy^  dmp, 

where  Sp^  and  Sy^  represent  the  distances  from  Pp  and  Py,  respectively, 
to  any  point  on  their  common  boundary  line,  Eq.  32  becomes,  after 
cancelling  dmp, 

F  F 

(Tp  +  TpSp^  +    X)  biViSip  =  0-,  +  TySy^  +    X)  biViSiy 
(35)  *=^  '■=-' 

{p   9^   v){p,V    =    I,'   •   •  ,7]). 

Equations  35  furnish  the  boundary  (indifference)  conditions  dividing 
a  market  domain  between  any  two  producers,  each  boundary  repre- 
senting a  locus  of  points  of  equal  deUvered  prices. 


238  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

The  problem  is  now  reduced  to  one  involving  a  finite  number  of  vari- 
ables, namely,  to  that  of  maximizing  ym  (where  the  r?  market  areas  are 
defined  by  Eqs.  30  and  35),  subject  to  i7(/  —  2)  restraints  on  the  variation 
of  the  distances,  which  express  for  each  producer  the  fact  that  in  choosing 
his  production  site  only  two  of  his  /  distance  variables  can  be  inde- 
pendent. Thus  ym  can  be  considered  as  a  function  of  independent 
coordinates  in  2j?  dimensional  space. 

In  this  new  framework,  setting  d(y7n)  =  0,  we  obtain: 


(36)                                       '■■=       y^'^^'l 

evaluated  along  the  path 

F           V                                    V 
k=A    /x=l                                M=l 

=  const. 

Up  9^  kfx  9^  iv). 

Of  Eqs.  36,^^  each  of  which  holds  in  2?/  —  1  independent  directions, 
and  yields  2??  —  1  independent  equations,  any  two  together  holding  in 
2t?  and  only  2??  independent  directions  are  required  to  provide  necessary 
and  sufficient  conditions  for  a  stationary  point.  These  provide  the 
equations  for  determining  the  2??  independent  unknowns.  Again, 
complex  second-order  conditions  are  required  to  distinguish  among 
maxima  and  other  stationary  points,  and  only  direct  computation  will 
yield  the  best  of  the  maxima  points. 

Economically  speaking,  Eqs.  36  state  that  in  a  small  variation 
of  any  production  site  from  its  corresponding  position  in  a  geographic 
pattern  of  production  sites  which  yields  maximum  surplus,  the  mar- 
ginal rate  of  substitution  of  one  transport  input  for  another  must  be 
equal  to  the  reciprocal  of  the  ratio  of  their  transport  rates,  social  surplus 
plus  total  revenue  less  total  production  costs  and  less  total  cost  on  all 
other  transport  inputs  being  held  constant.  It  should  be  emphasized 
that  variation  of  any  production  site  tends  to  entail  variation  in  all 
production  sites,  as  well  as  market  areas,  and  so  forth. 

In  order  to  avoid  further  complications  in  detailing  the  above  rela- 
tions, it  has  been  postulated  that  each  raw  material  originated  from  one 
fixed  site  only.  However,  just  as  we  have  treated  many  producers  serv- 
ing a  spatially  extended  market,  we  can  treat  many  producers  procur- 
ing their  supplies  of  each  raw  material  from  a  spatially  extended  supply 
area.    New  unknown  boundary  equations  are  introduced,  but  so  are  new 

^^  Analogous  to  the  second  of  the  Eqs.  28  the  ratios  in  Eqs.  36  should  be  viewed 
as  involving  transport  inputs  on  product  [e.g.  d{m^s^)  vis-a-vis  d(mi^iy)  or  vis-a-vis 
d(mySy)]  as  weU  as  transport  inputs  on  raw  materials. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     239 

conditions  to  determine  them.     The  reader  can  easily  develop  analysis 
in  this  direction. 

One  further  salient  point  must  be  noted.  The  derived  boundary 
(isotant)  Eqs.  35  contain  market  area  theory,  developed  by  Launhardt, 
Fetter,  Palander,  Hyson,  and  others.^^  j^  the  usual  case,  only  two 
producers,  each  at  a  particular  site,  are  considered,  and  transport  costs 
on  raw  materials  are  neglected  or  assumed  to  be  zero  or  already  ac- 
counted for  in  the  price  which  each  producer  charges.  Where  marginal 
cost  is  the  basis  for  determining  the  price  at  the  factory^^  then  Eqs.  35 
are  relevant  and  they  will  yield  (1)  straight  line  boundaries,  when 
dp  =  a^  and  fp  =  Ty,  (2)  hyperbolic  boundaries  when  ap  9^  ay  and  Vp  =  r^, 
(3)  circular  boundaries  when  cxp  =  ay  and  fp  7^  r^,  and  (4)  Descartes 
ovals  or  hypercircles  as  boundaries  when  ap  9^  ay  and  Vp  9^  r^.^* 

4.  LoscH  Market  Area  Analysis  Encompassed 

In  this  section  we  ^^dsh  to  demonstrate  that  the  principle  and  general 
analysis  thus  far  developed  logically  embraces  the  Losch  system  of 
market  areas. 

In  Chap.  2  we  have  sketched  Losch's  elaborately  developed  theory 
of  market  areas  based  upon  empirical  evidence  and  deductive  reasoning. 
Assuming  raw  materials  equally  and  adequately  present  at  any  site, 
population  uniformly  distributed  and  having  like  tastes  and  of  Uke 
stamp,  full  technical  knowledge  and  other  resources  available  to  every- 
one, transportation  possible  in  all  directions  at  a  fixed  rate,  and  complete 
freedom  of  entry  and  exit  for  producers,  Losch  has  demonstrated  how 
a  regular  hexagonal  net  of  market  areas  will  evolve. ^^  It  can  be  shown 
that  such  a  net  of  market  areas,  given  Losch's  restraining  postulates,  is 
implied  by  the  general  relations  in  Eqs.  35  and  36. 

First,  the  assumption  of  raw  materials  equally  and  adequately  present 
at  every  site  reduces  transport  inputs  on  raw  materials  to  zero  and 

^^  See  footnote  17. 

^^  Where  another  method  of  pricing  is  employed,  the  process  of  maximizing 
social  surplus  ym  wall  be  constrained  by  such  a  method  and  will  jdeld  boundary 
equations  similar  to  Eqs.  35  except  that  the  factory  price  charged  the  peripheral 
consumer  by  each  producer  will  substitute  for  marginal  cost.  The  boundaries 
^'ielded  by  these  new  equations  /will  still  be  of  the  same  tj^pe  as  those  derived  b}' 
traditional  market  area  analysis. 

^^  Where  the  transport  rate  is  a  function  of  distance,  then  the  hyperbolic,  cir- 
cular, and  hj-i^ercircular  boundaries  become  distorted  and  need  to  be  described 
bj'  more  complex  functions. 

^^  Losch,  op-  cii-1  Part  III.  Also  contrast  vidth  the  empirical  materials  in;  W. 
Christaller,  Die  zentralen  Orte  in  Siiddeutschland,  Jena,  1935;  and  E.  Ullman,  "A 
Theory  of  Location  of  Cities,"  American  Journal  of  Sociology,  Vol.  XL VI  (May  1941), 
pp.  853-64. 


240  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

eliminates  transport  inputs  on  any  raw  material  as  a  variable.    Equa- 
tions 36  can  now  be  simply  stated: 

d{mpSp) 

m(y  -\-  p  —  tt)  —    ^  mf,rs^  =  const. 


(37)         1 


d{mvSy) 


p  9^  fJi  9^  V 

p,  V  =  1,  '  ■  •  ,  n 

where  r^  =  Vp  =  r,  a  constant  rate  per  unit  product;  or  the  marginal 
rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs  on  product  from 
any  two  production  points  is  unity  along  a  path  where  social  surplus  plus 
total  revenue  less  total  production  costs  less  total  costs  on  all  other 
transport  inputs  is  held  constant.    Boundary  Eqs.  35  become 

(38)  (Tp  +  rsp(^  =  (T,  +  rs.o 

p,v  =  1,  •  •  •  ,n 

Losch's  assumption  of  free  entry  and  exit  of  producers  ensures  that 
there  will  be  no  profits,  namely,  that  price  will  equal  average  unit 
production  cost  for  any  producer.  Furthermore,  in  Losch's  schema  the 
delivered  price  is  equal  to  average  unit  production  cost  (factory  price) 
plus  transport  cost  (the  consumer  is  responsible  for  the  transportation 
of  the  product  he  purchases).  Hence,  the  boundary  (indifference)  line 
between  the  market  areas  of  any  two  producers,  which  is  a  locus  of 
points  of  equal  delivered  price,  is  given  by: 

(39)  TTp  +  rSpO  -  TT,  +  rs,o 

Consider  for  the  moment  all  situations,  whether  optimum  or  not, 
where  Eqs.  38  are  satisfied.  If  the  Loschian  schema  necessitating 
the  conditions  of  Eq.  39  is  to  be  simultaneously  satisfied,  then,  by 
subtraction: 

(40)  TTp    —    O-p    =    TTy   —    O-y 

p,V=    1,  ■  •  •  ,71 

This  states  that  the  difference  between  average  and  marginal  costs  is 
the  same  for  all  producers.  Such  can  be  the  case,  when  each  producer 
confronts  the  same  regular  demand  and  U-shaped  average  cost  functions, 
if,  and  only  if,  as  Losch  posits,  the  outputs  of  all  producers  are  of  the 
same  size;  and  thus  where  each  produces  at  a  point  where  the  demand 
curve  is  tangent  to  the  average  cost  curve.  Furthermore,  with  a  uniform 
distribution  of  consumers  and  producers  of  the  same  size,  Eqs.  38  as 
derived  from  the  general  problem  ensure  a  straight  fine  boundary 
between  any  two  producers  which  is  a  perpendicular  bisector  of  the 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION      241 

straight  line  joining  the  two.  Of  the  various  regular^^  geometric  shapes 
which  possess  such  boundary  hues,  only  the  equilateral  triangle,  square, 
and  regular  hexagon  can  exhaust  any  given  domain,  as  required  by  Losch. 
Equations  38  do  not  constitute  sufficient  conditions  for  an  optimum 
areal  distribution.  A  distribution,  under  Losch's  restraint  that  all 
producers  be  of  the  same  size,  must  also  satisfy  the  relations  in  Eqs.  37 
to  ensure  necessary  (though  still  not  sufficient)  conditions  for  a  maxi- 
mum.   We  do  find  that  the  distribution  of  a  domain  into  squares  verti- 


ri 


1^- 


U. 


n 


Fig.  43.    Change  in  market  boundary  pattern  with  shift  of  production  points 
in  a  square  matrix. 


cally  and  horizontally  aligned  as  in  Fig.  43  (unbroken  lines)  does, 
because  of  pattern  symmetry,  satisfy  Eqs.  37  as  well  as  boundary 
Eqs.  38  and  39  and  Losch's  other  postulates.  However,  we  can  easily 
demonstrate  that  this  distribution  is  not  a  maximum  one. 

Let  all  producers  and  their  associated  consumers  in  the  second 
row  of  Fig.  43  shift  their  positions  equally  to  the  right  by  a  small 
arbitrary  amount  so  that  the  dashed  lines  become  the  boundary  lines 
separating  the  market  areas  of  producers  in  the  second  row.  Since 
any  consumer  is  no  more  distant  from  his  respective  producer  in  the 

^®  Competition  compresses  irregular  shapes  into  regvdar  areas. 


242  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

new  situation  than  in  the  old,  m  and  m^  are  unaffected  and  hkewise 
a^^,  TTy,,  and  the  profit  of  each  producer.  It  also  follows  that  since  con- 
sumers of  like  tastes  and  stamp  are  uniformly  distributed  throughout 
the  area,  the  same  variables  are  unaffected  if  no  consumers  are  shifted 
when  all  producers  in  the  second  row  and  their  mutual  boundary  lines 
are  shifted  as  above. ^^  But  this  new  situation  does  not  fulfill  Eqs.  38 
and  39.  These  equations  require  that  the  boundary  separating  any  two 
producers  be  a  perpendicular  bisector  of  the  line  connecting  the  two, 
and  require  that,  given  the  new  (shifted)  pattern  of  production  sites, 
the  market  area  of  any  producer  in  the  second  row  take  on  an  irregular 
hexagonal  shape  as  indicated  for  the  producer  at  P;,  in  Fig.  43.  Therefore 
the  new  pattern  of  production  sites  Avith  irregular  hexagonal  market 
areas  for  the  second  row  producers  involves  a  greater  m  and  a  greater 
social  welfare  than  the  same  pattern  of  production  sites  with  rigid 
square  market  areas  and  thus  than  the  old  pattern  of  production  sites 
with  square  market  areas  vertically  and  horizontally  aligned.  Hence 
this  latter  square  pattern  is  not  a  maximum  one.  Likewise  with  the 
pattern  where  a  domain  is  divided  into  equilateral  triangles. 

A  distribution  into  regular  hexagons,  too,  satisfies  Eqs.  37  because  of 
pattern  symmetry.  However,  unlike  the  square  and  equilateral  triangle 
distributions,  it  does  represent  a  maximum,  given  producers  of  like  size. 
Any  substitution  of  transport  inputs  on  the  product  of  one  producer  for 
that  on  the  product  of  another  which  entails  small  shifts  of  a  number  of 
production  sites  leads  to  six-sided  polygons  which  are  not  regular  hex- 
agons^* (as  can  be  easily  verified  by  the  reader).  Since  a  regular 
hexagon  is  more  efficient  (requires  less  transport  inputs)  in  serving  any 
area  of  given  size  than  any  other  six-sided  polygon,  the  regular  hexagonal 
pattern  corresponds  to  a  minimum  transport  cost,  or  maximum  surplus 
arrangement.  Thus,  given  Losch's  restricting  postulates,  the  regular 
hexagonal,  and  only  the  regular  hexagonal,  pattern  is  implied  by  the 
derived  general  location  principle  and  analysis.^^ 

^^  Producers  in  the  second  row  will,  it  is  true,  serve  different  consumers;  and 
some  consumers  will  become  worse  off,  while  others  better  off.  However,  overall 
consumption  and  social  welfare  will  not  have  been  changed  by  the  shift. 

^^  This  contrasts  with  the  situation  where  in  certain  directions  small  shifts  in 
production  sites  transform  a  square  or  equilateral  triangle  pattern  into  a  pattern 
of  more-sided  polj^gons  which  is  more  efficient  than  the  initial  pattern. 

^^  However,  the  Losch  hexagonal  pattern  is  not  in  general  consistent  with  an 
optimum  space-economy  if  Losch's  restraining  postulates  are  relaxed. 

Imagine  average  unit  production  cost  falls  in  such  a  way  with  increase  in  output 
(engendered  by  extending  the  radius  of  a  circular  market  area)  that  the  sum  of 
average  unit  production  cost  and  average  transport  cost  of  product  to  consumers 
contained  in  any  size  market  area  yields  a  cost  function  which  decreases  only 
slightly  as  the  size  of  the  circular  market  area  increases.  Also,  for  simphcity, 
imagine  each  consumer  buys  one  and  only  one  unit.    The  market  domain  then  can 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION      243 

5.     Agriculture  Location  Theory   Embraced  and  Generalized 

Another  major  branch  of  location  theory,  stemming  from  the  work  of 
von  Thtinen,  developed  by  Aereboe  and  Brinkmann  and  most  recently 
by  Dunn,'*o  has  as  its  object  the  explanation  of  the  geographic  pattern 
of  agricultural  activities.  Immediately,  it  is  seen  that,  since  the 
von  Thtinen  problem  concerns  itself  with  the  formation  of  zones  each 
devoted  to  the  cultivation  of  a  particular  crop  or  combination  of  crops, 
the  general  location  statement  hitherto  developed  must  be  extended  to 
treat  more  than  one  commodity  if  it  is  to  encompass  agricultural 
location  theory. 

As  in  the  previous  analysis,  we  shall  abstract  from  price  changes, 
prices  being  determined  and  fixed  beforehand.  However,  this  position 
is  much  less  tenable  in  the  case  of  agricultural  location  theory.  Since 
several  commodities  vie  for  the  purchasing  potential  of  the  city  market 
and  since  significant  changes  in  the  outputs  of  the  various  agricultural 
commodities  may  be  involved  in  spatial  (zonal)  shifts,  it  is  only  by  price 
changes,  direct  and  indirect,  and  their  resultant  effects  upon  the  several 
outputs  that  appropriate  and  complete  adjustments  can  be  made  to 
locational  shifts.  To  account  for  repercussions  through  price  changes, 
as  a  truly  general  equilibrium  system  would,  is,  however,  beyond  the 
scope  of  this  chapter.^ ^  Since  agricultural  location  theorists  have  tra- 
ditionally omitted  price  changes  from  their  formulations  of  concrete 

be  overlain  with  non-overlapping  circles  of  different  sizes,  tangent  to  one  another, 
and  which  at  the  same  time  satisfy  boundary  conditions  in  Eqs.  38.  Any  unfilled 
gap  between  any  three  circles,  each  tangent  to  the  other  two,  can  be  partially  filled 
with  a  circle  of  still  smaller  size,  even  to  the  extreme  where  the  circles  themselves 
become  infinitesimal  in  area.  For  practical  purposes,  however,  we  can  allow  slight 
distortions  of  the  circles  well  before  such  an  extreme  is  reached.  Since  a  circle  can 
more  efficiently  serve  a  given  size  area  (consumers)  than  a  regular  hexagon  (see 
Losch,  op.cit.,  pp.  76-78)  and  since,  in  this  example,  the  distortions  of  circular  form 
are  minor  and  the  variation  in  total  average  cost  (including  transport)  associated 
with  the  various  sizes  of  circles  is  but  slight,  each  size  circle  is  more  efficient  than 
any  regular  hexagon  which  may  be  derived  as  optimum  size.  Hence,  a  pattern  of 
circles,  slightly  distorted  to  exhaust  the  area,  serves  the  area  more  efficiently  than 
any  pattern  of  regular  hexagons. 

^•^  J.  H.  von  Thiinen,  Der  isolierte  Staat  in  Beziehung  auf  Landwirtschaft  und 
Nationalokonomie,  Hempel  and  Parey,  Berlin,  1895;  F.  Aereboe,  Allgemeine  land- 
wirtschaftsliche  Betriebslehre,  P.  Parey,  Berlin,  1923;  E.  T.  Benedict,  H.  Stippler 
and  M.  R.  Benedict,  Theodor  Brinkmann' s  Economics  of  the  Farm  Business,  University 
of  California  Press,  Berkeley,  1935;  and  Edgar  S.  Dunn,  Jr.,  The  Location  of 
Agricultural  Production,  University  of  Florida  Press,  Gainesville,  1954. 

*^  The  reader  may  refer  to  the  non-operational  general  equihbrium  statements, 
involving  the  simultaneous  determination  of  price  and  spatial  structure,  in  Losch, 
op.  cit.,  1st  ed.,  1940,  pp.  57-63,  and  Dunn,  op.  cit..  Chap.  2. 


244  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

equilibrium  conditions,  there  is  no  inconsistency  in  demonstrating  how 
their  analysis  is  implied  by  our  general  analysis. 

We  shall  proceed  from  the  simple  to  the  more  complex.  Imagine  a 
single  city,  surrounded  by  land  of  uniform  quality,  consuming  commodi- 
ties k  -\-  1,  ■  ■  ■  ,  n  whose  prices  {pk+i,  •  •  •  ,  Pn)  are  set.  Our  problem 
is  to  determine  the  location  and  the  quantities  {nik+i,  •  •  •  ,  w„)  of  the 
agricultural  commodities  which  will  be  produced,  given  the  freight 
rate  (rk+i,  •  •  •  ,  r„)  and  cost  function  for  each  commodity,  7rA;+i,  •  •  •  , 
TTn,  and  (Tk+i,  •  •  •  ,  an  representing  their  average  unit  and  marginal 
costs,  respectively. 

Discarding  the  assumptions  of  constant  yield  of  a  given  crop  per  acre, 
regardless  of  distance  from  the  city,  and  of  constant  average  unit  cost — 
assumptions  which  have  characterized  the  algebraic  statements  of  Brink- 
mann,  Losch,  and  Dunn^^ — ^^g  have  for  the  given  commodity  a  unique 
marginal  rent  function,  which  traces  out  the  amount  of  rent  which 
would  be  yielded  by  each  unit  circumferential  band  of  land  as  we  pro- 
ceed radially  outward.  Each  marginal  rent  function  declines  continu- 
ously since  local  price  (net  of  transport  cost)  falls  off  with  distance 
from  the  city  market  and  since,  too,  as  a  result  intensity  per  unit  of  land 
falls  off  given  uniform  fertility  of  land  and  hence  a  production  function 
invariant  with  distance.*^  However,  since  only  one  commodity  (or  one 
combination  of  commodities  that  is  fixed  proportionally  and  thus  can 
be  viewed  as  a  single  commodity)  can  be  cultivated  on  any  given  piece 
of  land,  it  is  necessary  to  think  in  terms  of  stretches  of  land  devoted  to 
the  cultivation  of  one  and  only  one  commodity. 

Consider  total  rent  for  society 


(41) 


R   =      J2       \£^r(Pr    -    TT,)  dW    -   £  TrVrS  dJv] 


under  the  simplification  that  no  transportation  costs  are  incurred  on 
raw  materials,  labor,  and  other  inputs'*'*  and  where  the  Riemann  integral 

^^  As  previously  noted,  Dunn  has  pushed  the  analysis  on  to  the  individual  firm 
level  and  has  shown  the  inconsistency  of  these  assumptions  for  firm  analysis. 
Thereby,  he  has  been  able  to  sketch  graphically  the  approximate  character  of  the 
necessary  modifications  of  analysis  on  the  industry  level.  A  revision  of  his  mathe- 
matical statement,  however,  was  not  made. 

''^  Under  the  usual  assumption  that  the  farmer  is  not  incurring  loss  and,  thus, 
is  operating  at  a  point  on  the  rising  section  of  his  marginal  cost  curve. 

^^  The  simpUfication  is  made  merely  to  facilitate  presentation.  As  will  be  shown 
later,  another  term  representing  transport  costs  on  raw  materials  and  on  labor 
can  be  brought  into  the  brackets  of  Eq.  41;  the  analytical  technique  remains 
unaffected. 

It  should  be  noted  that  von  Thiinen  and  Brinkmann  would  insist  upon  two 
additional  terms,  a  negative  one  for  transport  costs  on  industrially  produced  goods 


modity,  Tr  representing  the  intensity  of  production  of  r  associated  with 
the  element  of  area  dW^^    Setting  dR  =  0,  we  obtain 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION      245 

/    is  taken  over  the  area  devoted  to  the  production  of  the  rth  com- 

le  intensity  of  p 
Setting  dR  = 

d  f  Tjs  dW 

(42)  ^<  =  -4 

'  dJT.sdW 

evaluated  along  the  path 

X;         f    r^iPr   -    Trr)dW   -      E        f   "^rVrS  dW    =    COUSt. 

ihj  =  k  +  I,-  •  •  ,n). 

Immediately,  it  is  seen  that  these  relations  imply  a  concentric  circular 
zone  (in  the  extreme  case  approaching  a  line)  pattern  of  cultivation. 
First,  zones,  whatever  their  shape,  must  be  contiguous  to  each  other  and 
to  the  city  market.  Otherwise,  there  would  be  empty  spaces  which 
would  then  permit  a  shifting  of  some  zone  closer  to  the  city  market 
thereby  reducing  transport  costs  on  one  commodity  without  affecting 
transport  costs  on  any  other  commodity.  But  this  is  inconsistent  with 
Eqs.  42.  Second,  since  the  transport  rate  is  independent  of  direction, 
the  contiguous  zones  must  also  be  concentric  and  circular  because 
Eqs.  42  also  imply  pattern  symmetry.'*^ 

Of  Eqs.  42,  only  n-k  are  independent,  and  they  determine  the  n-  k 
variable  boundaries  separating  the  zones  in  which  the  n-k  commodities 

used  as  inputs  and  shipped  from  the  city  market,  and  a  positive  one  for  transport 
costs  of  the  agriculturally  produced  inputs  from  any  element  of  area  to  the  city 
market.  The  latter  positive  term  represents  the  differential  price  advantage  any 
element  of  area  has  over  the  city  market  in  procuring  agricultural  raw  materials 
(including  food  for  labor),  since  the  difference  between  the  price  at  the  city  market 
and  the  local  price  at  the  element  of  area  for  any  such  raw  material  is  the  cost  of 
shipping  that  raw  material  from  the  element  of  area  to  the  market. 

■^^  We  employ  the  Riemann  integral  throughout  this  section  since  intensity  of 
production  on  any  element  of  area  (farm)  is  a  critical  issue  in  agricultural  loca- 
tion theory.  The  use  of  the  Stieltjes  integral  would  conceal  the  intensity  variable. 
Also,  since  agricultural  production  tends  to  assume  a  continuous  character,  the 
Stieltjes  integral  would  in  any  case  tend  to  reduce  to  a  Riemann  integral.  However, 
in  the  latter  part  of  this  section  where  a  continuous  market  area  is  considered,  the 
use  of  the  Stieltjes  integral  would  have  definite  advantage  in  an  extension  of  the 
analysis  to  include  cities  as  discrete  consumption  points  viithin  the  market  area, 
provided  the  integral  is  differentiable  in  the  relevant  region. 

^®  Thus  the  analysis  in  its  more  vital  aspects  can  be  reduced  to  the  problem  of 
examining  relations  along  any  straight  line  through  the  point  representing  the 
city  market. 


246  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

are  produced.  These  equations  are  only  necessary  conditions  for  maxi- 
mum rent.  Elaborate  second-order  conditions  are  required  to  dis- 
tinguish a  maximum  from  other  stationary  points.  With  marginal  rent 
functions  for  all  commodities  plotted  on  a  single  graph  (marginal  rent 
measured  along  the  ordinate),  the  absolute  maximum  obtains  when  the 
commodity  produced  on  any  given  unit  of  land  corresponds  to  the  mar- 
ginal rent  function  having  the  highest  ordinate  for  that  unit  of  land.*^ 

Economically  speaking,  Eqs.  42  state  that  for  maximum  rent  the 
marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs,  each  on 
a  particular  crop,  must  equal  the  reciprocal  of  the  ratio  of  their  transport 
rates,  the  sum  of  rent  on  all  other  commodities  plus  the  total  difference 
between  sales  value  and  production  costs  for  the  two  crops  being  held 
constant.  It  must  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  path  along  which  the  sum 
is  held  constant  may  involve  shifts  of  the  zonal  boundaries  of  other 
crops  as  well  as  of  the  tAvo  explicitly  considered  and  may  call  for  changes 
in  the  intensity  of  cultivation  and  in  unit  production  costs  of  other  crops 
as  well  as  of  these  two.    Thus  the  path  may  be  quite  complex. 

Despite  this  complexity,  Eqs.  42  imply  relatively  simple  boundary 
determining  equations.  Imagine  that  only  two  boundaries  shift,  namely, 
those  Sp  and  s,,  distances  from  the  city,  representing  respectively  the 
outer  boundaries  of  the  zones  producing  crops  p  and  m-  Further,  let  at 
least  one  other  zone  intervene,  p  being  nearer  the  city.  From  Eqs.  42 
where  i  =  p  and  j  =  (j.  we  w^ould  have  with  a  small  change  of  Sp  and 
corresponding  change  of  Sp,: 

(43)  VpVpSp^dSp  =  -r^VpS^^dSp 

where  27rs  ds  substitutes  for  dW  and  27r  is  cancelled.  Also  from  the 
restraint  of  Eqs.  42  defining  the  path,  w^e  have,  after  cancelling  27r,^^ 

Vpipp  —  Trp)Sp  dSp  —  Tp+i(pp+i  —  Tp+i)Sp  dSp  +  T^ipp,  —  Tp.)s^  ds,, 
(44) 

- T^+i(p^+i  —  7r^+i)s^  dSf,  +  rp+iTp+iSp^  dSp  +  r^+iT^+is^^  ^^^  ^  q 

where  Tp+i  and  Xp+i  are  evaluated  at  Sp,  and  F^+i  and  tt^+i  at  s^.  Simi- 
larly two  equations  of  like  form  are  obtained  when  in  Eqs.  42  we  let 

^^  Given  any  position  other  than  the  absolute  maximum  already  described,  there 
is  always  at  least  one  way  in  which  a  substitution  of  transport  inputs  on  one  commod- 
ity for  transport  inputs  on  another  can  increase  rent.  This  may  involve  a  shift 
of  some  element  of  area  from  the  cultivation  of  one  crop  to  the  other,  the  formation 
of  new,  or  deletion  of  old,  zones,  and  a  corresponding  increase  or  decrease  in  the 
number  of  boundary  variables. 

^*  In  Eq.  44  are  contained  all  the  elements  which  change  in  the  restraint  governing 
the  path,  namely,  the  sales  revenue  and  production  costs  associated  with  crops 
p,  p  +  1,  /i,  and  ju  +  1  and  transport  costs  associated  with  crops  p  +  1  and  /x  +  1. 
Since  the  path  defines  a  constant  sum,  the  total  of  these  changes  must  be  zero. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION      247 

i  =  p  and  ^  =  /x  +  1,  and  where  as  before  distances  Sp  and  s^  only  are 
varied.  These  latter  two  equations,  with  Eqs.  43  and  44,  yield  alge- 
braically:*^ 

(45)  r^s^r^  -  r^+is^r^+i  =  T^{j)^  -  tt^)  -  r^+i(p^+i  -  x;,+i). 

Equations  of  the  type  of  Eqs.  45  represent  another  way  of  expressing 
necessary  conditions  for  maximum  rent.^°  Each  such  equation  states 
that  with  a  small  shift  of  the  boundary  line  between  any  two  zones,  the 
change  in  over-all  transport  costs  for  the  two  crops  is  equal  to  the  change 
in  the  sum  of  the  difference  between  sales  value  and  production  costs 
for  each  of  the  two  crops.  Or,  if  in  each  of  Eqs.  45  the  first  term  on  the 
left  side  is  carried  over  to  the  right  and  the  last  term  on  the  right  to  the 
left,  the  necessary  conditions  for  maximum  rent  are  that  with  any 
infinitesimal  shift  of  the  boundary  between  two  zones,  marginal  rent  on 
the  one  crop  must  equal  marginal  rent  on  the  other.  In  graphic  terms, 
the  marginal  rent  functions  of  the  two  crops  must  intersect  or  be  tangent 
at  the  boundary  line.^^ 

These  boundary  conditions,  implied  by  Eqs.  42,  are  identical  with 
those  obtained  by  Losch  and  Dunn,^^  except  that  Vi  and  tt^  are  con- 
stants in  Losch's  and  Dunn's  schema  whereas  they  are  variables  in  our 
formulation.  Treating  intensity  and  unit  production  costs  as  variables 
not  only  is  realistic  but  has  the  distinct  advantage,  as  Dunn  noted,  of 
facilitating  the  unification  of  theory  for  the  industry  and  for  the  indi- 
vidual farm  unit.^^  Postulating  Vi  and  in  as  constants  throughout  a 
zone  precludes  any  such  thing  as  a  firm  adjustment  to  a  lower  or  higher 
local  (net)  price  for  product  and  rent  payment  for  land  and,  thus,  in 
essence  is  inconsistent  with  customary  firm  analysis.  However,  with  Vi 
and  TTi  as  variables,  we  derive  that,  since  a  farmer  will  produce  on  the 
rising  section  of  his  marginal  cost  curve  up  to  the  point  where  his 
marginal  costs  {(n)  just  equals  the  local  (net)  price  (pi  —  riSi),  dai/dsi  = 
—  Vi;  and  therefore,  dVi/dsi  =  —ridVi/dai.  As  dVi/dai  is  positive  on 
the  rising  section  of  the  marginal  cost  curve,  dVi/dsi  is  negative.  Thus 
intensity  of  cultivation  falls  off  in  any  zone  from  land  unit  to  land  unit, 
or  farm  unit  to  farm  unit  with  increase  of  distance  from  the  market.  ^^ 

*^  By  eliminating  the  three  unknowns  dsp,  ds^,  and  Sp. 

^^  These  equations  are  also  obtainable  when  more  than  two  boundaries  are  shifted. 

^^  This  condition  also  characterizes  stationary  points  other  than  the  absolute 
maximum,  including  relative  maxima  when  each  crop  is  restricted  to  production 
within  one  zone  onl3^ 

^^  Losch,  op.  cit.,  pp.  28-32;  Dunn,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  2. 

^^  Though,  of  course,  when  there  is  no  definite  bunching  of  firms  with  respect 
to  similarity  of  product  or  output  mix,  there  may  not  be  any  justification  or  mean^ 
ing  in  the  distinction  between  firm  and  industry. 

^*  However,  because  of  differences  in  production  cost  functions,  transport  rates, 


248  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

And  thus  we  have  an  adjustment  to  the  fall  in  local  price  appropriate 
to  both  firm  and  industry  analysis. 

When  within  any  zone  it  is  desirable  to  consider  each  firm  by  itself, 
because  outputs  or  output  combinations  for  various  firms  are  too 
heterogeneous  or  for  other  reasons,  each  firm  can  be  considered  an 
industry.  More  boundary  variables  are  introduced  but  so  are  more 
equations  to  determine  the  boundaries.  Boundary  Eq.  45  comes  to 
hold  between  firms  whether  or  not  they  produce  a  homogeneous  output 
as  well  as  between  groups  of  firms  (industries),  each  corresponding  to  a 
zone.  Thus  firm  and  industry  analysis  are  mutually  consistent  in  this 
spatial  framework,  and  in  the  extreme  case,  may  be  considered  as  one 
and  the  same  thing. 

Hitherto,  we  have  excluded  consideration  of  transport  costs  on  raw 
materials.  Such  can  easily  be  introduced  explicitly  into  the  analysis  by 
inserting  into  the  brackets  of  Eq.  41  the  term 


■J  T.TrhirriSidW, 


where  Si  is  the  distance  of  the  source  of  raw  material  i  from  the  element 
dW.  With  this  term  inserted,  marginal  rates  of  substitution  between 
transport  inputs  on  raw  materials,  and  between  transport  inputs  on  a 
raw  material  and  transport  inputs  on  a  product,  are  obtainable  from  the 
required  revision  of  Eqs.  42.  It  should  be  noted  that  in  general  the 
zonal  boundaries  will  no  longer  be  concentric  circles  because  pattern 
symmetry  will  have  been  lost.^^ 

If,  however,  raw  material  i  is  supplied  not  from  a  single  point  source 
but  from  an  area,  Si  becomes  a  variable  for  any  given  element,  dW^ 
representing  the  distance  from  dW  of  the  element  of  the  raw  material 
supply  area,  dU,  which  furnishes  the  i  required  by  dW.  As  a  result 
additional  equations  of  the  order  of  Eqs.  42  result  which  relate,  for 
example,  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  i  used  by  crop  r,^^ 


X 


TiSirdU, 
u 


and  market  prices,  intensity  per  land  unit,  however  measured,  need  not  fall  ofif 
from  zone  to  zone  or  from  a  farm  unit  in  one  zone  to  a  contiguous  farm  unit  in  the 
next  zone. 

^^  Hence,  it  becomes  necessary  to  think  in  terms  of  a  boundary  defined  by  an 
equation  rather  than  by  a  radial  distance  alone.  Analysis  along  a  straight  line  is 
in  general  no  longer  valid. 


Tins  is,  of  course,  equivalent  to    I    TrbirSi  dW. 


to    /   Trb 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION      249 

and  transport  inputs  on  raw  material  i  used  by  crop  r  +  1, 

riS,v+i  dU. 


I 


+1 


These  determine  the  boundary  Hnes  cutting  off  the  portion  of  the  supply 
area  of  raw  material  i  which  serves  each  crop.^^ 

A  still  more  general  framework,  encompassing  more  than  one  city 
market,  can  be  handled.  Consider  first  a  relatively  small  number  of  city 
markets  close  enough  to  compete  for  the  potential  crops  of  at  least  some 
land.  Here  an  industry  (agricultural  activity)  and  its  corresponding 
zone  of  cultivation  must  be  defined  not  only  in  terms  of  the  crop  pro- 
duced but  also  the  city  market  served.  The  number  of  industries  is 
thus  multiplied  but  so  also  is  the  number  of  Eqs.  42  to  determine 
boundary  lines.  ^^ 

Where  the  number  of  city  markets  becomes  large  and  attains  the 
approximate  continuity  of  a  market  area,  we  reach  the  most  general 
type  of  framework,  that  is,  many  markets  each  consuming  many 
products,  many  producers  of  any  given  product,  many  raw  materials 
used  by  each  producer,  and  many  sources  (a  supply  area)  of  each  raw 
material.  An  alternative  approach  to  this  most  general  framework 
follows  from  the  analysis  of  Sect.  3.  There  we  considered  many  pro- 
ducers of  a  single  commodity  demanded  by  a  population  spread  over  an 
area  and  requiring  many  raw  materials,  each  furnished  from  a  supply 
area.  By  introducing  many  commodities  in  this  framework  we  reach 
the  same  problem  as  when  we  inject  the  market  area  into  the  Thiinen 
type  of  framework.  It  seems,  however,  more  desirable  to  generalize 
from  the  Thiinen  type  of  framework.  In  this  framework  prices  are 
explicitly  assumed  as  given  and  we  avoid  the  problem,  which  thus  far 
has  not  been  satisfactorily  handled,  of  relating  social  surpluses,  or 
consumer  utilities,  or  satisfactions  derivable  from  several  commodities.^® 

^^  Also,  dR  =  0  implies  equations  guaranteeing  the  appropriate  pairing  off 
of  elements  of  area  in  any  portion  with  the  elements  in  the  crop  zone  which  the 
portion  serves. 

^^  In  the  case  of  only  two  cities,  in  which  the  ruling  market  prices  are  different, 
there  will  tend  to  be  two  hinterlands,  one  corresponding  to  each  city.  In  each 
hinterland,  zonal  pattern  symmetry  will  exist  with  respect  to  the  cultivation  of 
any  given  crop  when  no  raw  materials  are  employed.  However,  on  the  two  sides 
of  any  smaU  stretch  of  the  border  separating  the  two  hinterlands,  in  general  different 
types  of  crops  wiU  be  cultivated  at  different  intensities  per  unit  of  land,  though 
marginal  rent  is  the  same. 

^^  In  essence,  the  Thiinen  framework  assumes  away  this  subjective  evaluation 
problem.  It  treats  only  objective,  measurable  elements  and,  on  the  basis  of  these 
latter  alone,  yields  a  spatial  pattern  of  economic  activity  and  land  use. 


250  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

This  problem  would  confront  us  if  we  were  to  proceed  from  the  analysis 
of  Sect.  3. 

Generalizing  the  Thiinen  analysis  w^e  have  for  total  rent: 


(46)  ,  -. 

-    J       VHrTrSr  ^^   -    J      ^    ^rhirfiSi  dW      , 

where  Tht  represents  the  intensity  of  the  effective  demand  for  product 
T  in  the  element  dH  of  the  consumption  market  area  at  the  price  pr, 
Pr  being  fixed  for  each  element  but  varying  from  element  to  element; 
TTr  represents  the  average  production  cost  of  r  at  the  element  dW,  where 
an  element  dW  may  serve  more  or  less  than  one  element  dH;  and  Sr 
represents  the  distance  from  the  element  dH  of  the  element  dW  produc- 
ing the  T  which  is  demanded  at  element  dH. 

Setting  dR  =  0  yields  again  equations  of  the  order  of  Eqs.  42,  though 
more  complex.  These,  nonetheless,  can  be  easily  set  down  by  the  reader. 
A  whole  new  set  of  substitution  relations,  however,  is  embraced.  For 
example,  there  may  be  substitution  between  transport  inputs  on  the 

product  T  going  to  city  A,    I    TrSri  dW,^^  and  transport  inputs  on  the 

product  T  going  to  city  B,    I    TrSrB  dW,  or  on  the  product  t  -\-  1  going 

to  city  B,  etc.  More  generally,  the  consumption  market  area  may  be 
divided  into  any  two  or  more  meaningful  parts  and  transport  inputs 
on  product  r  going  to  any  a  part  can  be  considered  vis-a-vis  transport 
inputs  on  any  other  product  going  to  any  area  or  meaningful  part  of  an 
area,  or  on  any  raw  material  going  to  any  production  area  or  meaningful 
part  of  a  production  area  of  any  good,^i  and  so  forth.  In  this  way,  within 
the  hypothesized  framework  of  the  space-economy,  one  can  make  the 
most  comprehensive  statements  concerning  equilibrium  conditions  and 


JThtSt  dH  where  the  integral    / 
H  Jh 


^'^  Equivalent  to    /    TffrST  dH  where  the  integral    /    is  evaluated  over  the  area  of 

city  A. 

^^  As  a  consequence,  if  attention  is  paid  to  a  given  crop  alone  without  regard 
to  destination  or  market,  multiple  zones  of  cultivation  will  appear,  each  in  gen- 
eral asymmetrical  with  respect  to  any  selected  focal  point. 

Where  a  given  good  is  produced  at  a  finite  number  of  plants,  as  in  the  analj'sis 
of  Sect.  3,  the  cultivation  zone  or  production  area  of  that  good  has  in  effect  been 
reduced  to  a  finite  number  of  points,  the  intensity  of  cultivation  or  production 
at  other  points  being  zero.  Any  one  point  may  still  be  a  potential  site  of  production 
of  all  other  goods,  a  potential  source  of  all  raw  materials,  and  a  potential  market 
for  all  goods. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION     251 

substitution  relations  among  transport  inputs.  This  the  reader  can 
easily  do  by  setting  down  equations  of  the  order  of  Eqs.  42  that,  however, 
correspond  to  total  rent  as  defined  in  Eq.  46. 

6.  Concluding  Remarks 

We  have  treated  what  may  be  called  a  continuous  space-economy, 
continuous  transportationwise  and  continuous  to  some  extent  at  least 
with  respect  to  market  and  supply  areas.  This  stands  in  strong  contrast 
to  the  highly  discontinuous  realistic  one.  We  have  noted  how  modern 
rate  structures  in  effect  yield  a  transport  cost  surface  punctured  at 
terminal  sites,  the  transport  cost  for  each  such  point  being  significantly 
below  that  for  points  contiguous  in  space.  The  fact  that  in  reality 
transport  routes  radiate  from  one  point  not  in  all  directions  but  in  only 
a  few,  particularly  in  modern  industrial  societies  with  a  relatively  small 
number  of  fixed  trunk  routes,  means  that  the  transport  cost  surface  is 
punctured  linearly,  too.  Each  locus  of  points  corresponding  to  an  exist- 
ing transport  route  lies  significantly  below  any  locus  of  points  through 
which  no  transport  route  courses.  The  presence  of  junction  and  trans- 
shipment points,  of  loading  and  unloading  facilities,  of  various  auxiliary 
transport  services,  and  of  the  whole  complex  of  agglomeration  econ- 
omies, as  well  as  of  varying  topography,  back-haul  and  other  abnormal 
rates,  special  transit  privileges,  and  other  factors,  imposes  still  larger 
discontinuities  and  distortions  upon  the  transport  cost  surface  derived 
from  simplifying  assumptions.  Hence  we  discover  in  the  space-economy 
of  reality  hierarchies  and  different  degrees  of  dominance  in  sets  of  focal 
points  and  channels  of  movement. ^^  To  a  large  extent  substitution 
among  transport  inputs  is  not  in  the  small  but  rather  in  the  large,  en- 
tailing geographic  shifts  over  substantial  distance  from  one  focal  point  to 
another.  To  this  extent  the  preceding  analysis  is  not  directly  relevant. 
However,  the  extent  of  discontinuity  must  not  be  exaggerated.  The 
demarcation  of  many  agricultural  and  raw  material  supply  areas  and 
many  industrial  market  areas  can  be  handled  in  terms  of  substitution  in 
the  small.  Likewise  with  many  industrial  location  problems.  It  should 
be  kept  in  mind  that  the  extent  to  which  spatial  continuity  and  dis- 
continuity exist  is  yet  to  be  determined  or  even  approximately  estimated 
by  empirical  study. 

^^  For  an  excellent  pictorial  presentation,  refer  to  "Interregional  Highways," 
House  Document  379,  78th  Congress,  2nd  session,  Wasliington  1944,  Fig.  22.  For 
discussion,  see  A.  Hawley,  Human  Ecology;  A  Theory  of  Community  Structure, 
New  York,  1950;  D.  J.  Bogue,  The  Structure  of  the  Metropolitan  Community,  Ann 
Arbor,  1949;  and  W.  Isard  and  G.  Freutel,  "Regional  and  National  Product  Projec- 
tions and  their  Interrelations"  in  Long-Range  Economic  Projection,  National  Bureau 
of  Economic  Research,  Studies  in  Income  and  Wealth,  Vol.  16,  Princeton  University 
Press,  Princeton,  1954,  pp.  427-471. 


252  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

To  analyze  the  space-economy  in  terms  of  geographic  shifts  in  the 
large,  from  focal  point  to  focal  point,  is  highly  desirable  and  will  be 
partially  attempted  in  a  future  volume.  In  this  chapter  we  have  tried  to 
demonstrate  the  usefulness  of  the  concept  of  transport  inputs  in  deriving 
conditions  for  the  efficient  operation  of  a  space-economy.  A  basic 
principle — in  a  sense  an  intuitively  obvious  one — has  emerged,  namely, 
that  the  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport  inputs 
or  groups  of  transport  inputs,  however  the  transport  inputs  or  groups 
of  transport  inputs  may  be  defined,  must  equal  the  reciprocal  of  the 
ratio  of  their  transport  rates,  social  surplus  (however  defined)  less 
transport  costs  on  all  other  transport  inputs  being  held  constant.  This 
principle  impHes  a  large  part  of  existing  location  theory.  Weberian 
transport  orientation  is  embodied  in  such  a  principle,  and  with  this 
principle  we  are  better  able  to  take  transport  orientation  out  of  the  nar- 
row geometric  framework  in  which  it  has  hitherto  been  confined  and 
determine  the  optimal  transport  point  for  the  more  generafized  case  when 
many  raw  material  and  market  points  are  involved.  The  principle,  too, 
encompasses  all  market  (and  purchasing)  area  theory,  implying  the 
customary  boundary  conditions  which  separate  the  market  areas  of 
producers  (and  hinterlands  of  focal  points).  Likewise,  Losch's  spatial 
designs  are  embraced  as  well  as  the  von  Thiinen  type  of  agricultural 
location  theory.  Both  the  Losch  and  the  von  Thiinen  types  of  theory 
can  be  generalized  to  harbor  a  much  broader  range  and  a  more  reaHstic 
set  of  situations. 

More  important,  this  general  principle  fuses  the  separate  partial 
location  theories.  It  thus  serves  as  a  basic  core  of  a  general  location 
theory  from  which,  for  the  most  part,  existing  location  theories  are 
derived  as  special  cases  of  the  most  general  situation,  embracing  many 
market  points,  each  consuming  many  commodities,  each  of  which  is 
produced  by  many  producers,  each  of  whom  uses  many  raw  materials 
and  inputs,  each  of  which  is  furnished  by  a  supply  area.^^ 

Perhaps  most  important  is  that  this  principle  allows  existing  location 
theory  to  be  stated  in  a  form  comparable  to  that  of  production  theory. 
By  incorporating  transport  inputs  into  the  transformation  function,  and 
thereby  yielding  a  spatial  transformation  function,  we  can  extend  exist- 
ing production  theory  so  that  to  a  large  extent  it  embodies  the  location 
factor  explicitly.  At  the  same  time  location  theory  can  now  consider 
change  in  a  number  of  parameters.    For  example,  the  relation  between 

^^  For  example,  one  can  derive  Weber's  theory  of  transport  orientation  by  making 
assumptions  such  as  the  existence  of  a  single  market  point,  consuming  one  unit  of 
one  commodit}^,  produced  by  a  single  producer,  using  two  raw  materials,  each 
obtainable  at  a  single  source. 


LOCATION  THEORY:  MATHEMATICAL  FORMULATION      253 

economies  of  scale  and  the  number  and  geographic  distribution  of  plants 
can  be  examined  through  substitution  between  transport  inputs  and  all 
other  inputs  as  a  whole;  or  the  relation  between  the  spatial  extent  and 
capital  intensity  (time  extent)  of  production,  through  substitution 
between  transport  inputs  and  capital  inputs.  Thus  a  more  compre- 
hensive framework  emerges  for  both  types  of  theory. 


Chapter 


11 


Partial  Graphic  Synthesis 
and  Summary 


We  must  now  take  stock.  What  has  been  accomplished?  In  attack- 
ing this  question  we  shall,  where  the  use  of  illustrations  makes  it 
possible,  attempt  a  finer  integration  of  the  materials  than  has  thus  far 
been  achieved.  However,  in  order  to  keep  repetition  at  a  minimum 
we  shall  be  brief.  We  shall  assume  that  the  reader  has  thoroughly 
digested  previous  materials. 

In  Chap.  2  we  have  envisaged  the  general  theory  of  location  and 
space-economy  as  embracing,  within  a  temporal  (dynamic)  framework, 
the  total  spatial  array  of  economic  activities  and  their  interrelations, 
both  aggregatively  and  atomistically,  with  attention  paid  to  the  geo- 
graphic distribution  of  inputs  and  outputs  and  to  the  variations  over 
space  in  prices  and  costs.  This  theory  eschews  the  narrow  framework 
of  Marshallian  doctrine.  In  many  ways  it  includes  modern  general 
equilibrium  theory  as  but  a  special  case;  in  other  respects  it  becomes 
synonymous  with  a  broadly  defined  trade  theory  and  a  broadly  defined 
theory  of  monopolistic  competition. 

The  empirical  materials  of  Chap.  3  strongly  testify  to  the  fact  that 
there  are  significant  regularities  associated  with  the  distance  variable 
and  that  in  many  important  respects  there  is  a  basic  structure  to  a 
space-economy.  To  understand  this  structure  and  to  analyze  the  cur- 
rent and  anticipate  the  future  functioning  of  a  space-economy,  we 
adopt  a  substitution  approach  as  initially  suggested  by  Predohl.  The 
substitution  approach,  covering  substitution  in  the  large  as  well  as 
substitution  in  the  small,  is  familiar  to  economists  and  needs  no  further 
comment. 

254 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       255 

Coupled  with  the  substitution  approach  is  the  concept  of  transport 
inputs.  A  transport  input  is  defined  as  the  movement  of  a  unit  weight 
over  a  unit  distance.  In  the  growth  of  a  simple  nucleus  of  population, 
transport  inputs  early  become  basic  elements.  They  permit  the  in- 
creased productivity  which  accrues  from  (1)  postponing  and  mitigating 
diseconomies  from  excessive  agglomeration  and  the  forces  of  diminish- 
ing returns  and  (2)  exploiting  the  unequal  distribution  of  natural 
resources.  These  same  basic  forces  operate  in  our  modern  world- 
economy  with  its  complex  hierarchy  of  cities  and  spatial  distributions 
of  population. 

As  with  capital  inputs,  transport  inputs  can  be  thought  of  as 
derived  and  as  indicating  roundaboutness  in  the  production  process. 
Corresponding  to  transport  inputs  there  are  such  concepts  as  spatial 
extent  of  production,  space  discount,  and  space  preference.  The 
transport  rate  is  the  price  of  a  transport  input.  The  determination  of 
this  price  may  be  accounted  for  by  a  conventional  demand  and  supply 
analysis  for  transport  inputs.  A  fall  in  the  price  of  a  transport  input 
induces  a  spatial  lengthening  of  production  and  may  be  associated  (as 
is  historically  the  case)  with  both  a  scale  and  substitution  effect. 

In  Chap.  5  we  couple  the  substitution  approach  and  the  concept 
of  transport  inputs  in  order  to  restate  and  reformulate  transport- 
orientation  doctrine.  The  problem  of  finding  the  transport  optimal 
point  reduces  to  a  problem  of  finding  the  correct  substitution  points 
between  pairs  of  transport  inputs.  This  is  so  whether  one  treats 
simplified  transport  rate  structures  or  the  complicated  ones  of  reality, 
whether  one  assumes  uniform  transport  facilities  radiating  in  all  direc- 
tions from  all  points  or  the  discontinuous  and  heterogeneous  network 
of  reality,  whether  one  analyzes  a  process  using  one  localized  raw 
material  or  many,  and  whether  one  considers  one  market  point  or 
many.  It  is  demonstrated  how  the  various  geometric,  graphic,  and 
physical  solutions  propounded  are  translatable  into  substitution  points 
among  transport  inputs.  The  most  rigorous  presentation  of  the 
solution  to  the  transport-orientation  problem  in  terms  of  substitutions 
among  transport  inputs  is  found  in  Sect.  1  of  Chap.  10.  The  formula- 
tion of  the  transport-orientation  problem  as  well  as  other  problems  of 
location  in  terms  of  substitution  among  transport  inputs,  where  trans- 
port inputs  are  viewed  as  any  other  set  of  inputs  embraced  by  a 
transformation  function,  has  the  decided  advantage  of  permitting  at 
least  a  partial  fusion  of  production  theory  and  location  theory. 

Much  of  the  argument  of  Chap.  5  centers  around  the  locational 
triangle,  as  has  historically  been  the  case  with  transport-orientation 
analysis.    However,  the  argument  does  embrace  more  than  one  market 


256 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


point  and  a  single  source  of  each  of  two  raw  materials,  n  market 
points  and  raw  materials  are  considered,  and  in  Sect.  1  of  Chap.  10 
this  extension  of  the  argument  is  most  rigorously  presented.  Yet 
another  useful  way  of  presenting  the  problem  of  transport-orientation 
when  no  weight  is  dominant  and  when  there  exist  many  market  points, 
or  in  essence  an  area  of  consumers,  has  been  developed  by  Launhardt 
and  Palander.  Their  graphic  presentation  can  be  extended  to  portray 
in  a  forceful  manner  the  interrelations  and  influences  of  the  various 
location  factors. 

In  constructing  his  basic  diagram  which  we  largely  depict  in  Fig.  44, 
Palander,  following  Launhardt,  in  effect  postulates  (1)  the  absence  of 


Fig.  44.    The  Launhardt-Palander  construction. 


the  various  agglomeration  economies  and  of  geographic  variations  in 
the  prices  of  various  inputs  and  outputs  except  those  resulting  from 
transport  cost  on  the  product  and  on  the  two  raw  materials  con- 
sidered, and  (2)  uniform  transport  facilities  radiating  in  all  directions 
from  all  points,  i  Given  ilfi  as  the  only  source  of  the  first  raw 
material  and  M2  as  the  only  source  of  the  second  raw  material,  at 
what  points  should  production  occur  to  serve  consumers?  Starting 
with  consumer  at  C,  we  construct  the  locational  triangle  CMiMo  and 
the  corresponding  weight  triangle  OM1M2  erected  upon  the  side  M1M2 
of  the  locational  triangle.  0  is  ori'fe  of  Launhardt's  poles.  We  circum- 
scribe a  circle  around  the  weight  triangle  and  connect  the  pole  0  with 
the  point  of  consumption  C  by  a  straight  line.  P,  the  point  of  inter- 
section of  the  pole  line  OC  and  the  circumscribed  circle,  is  the  desired 
location,  the  transport  optimal  point,  for  serving  the  consumer  at  C. 
1  Palander,  op.  cit.,  pp.  143-146. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       257 

Take  another  consumer  at  Ci.  We  could  construct  a  second  loca- 
tional  triangle  CiMiMo-  Its  weight  triangle,  too,  would  be  OMiM^- 
We  find  that  the  relevant  pole  line  OCi  coincides  with  pole  line  OC. 
Since  the  point  of  intersection  with  the  unchanged  circumscribed  circle 
remains  the  same,  P  is  the  logical  production  point  to  serve  not  only 
C  but  also  Cj.  Likewise,  it  can  be  demonstrated  that  P  is  the  optimal 
transport  point  for  all  consumers  along  the  pole  line  OCi  from  P  to  Ci 
and  beyond. 

Take  still  another  consumer  at  Co-  We  could  construct  the  loca- 
tional  triangle  C2M1M2.  Its  weight  triangle  erected  upon  side  M1M2 
would  as  before  be  OM-^Mo,  since  the  relevant  weights  have  not 
changed.  The  corresponding  circumscribed  circle  therefore  remains 
the  same.  Thus,  to  derive  the  production  point  for  serving  C2,  we 
need  not  construct  locational  triangle  C2M1M2.  We  simply  connect 
the  pole  0  and  C2  with  a  straight  line  and  locate  P2,  the  point  of 
intersection  of  the  pole  line  OC2  with  the  circumscribed  circle. 

Take  a  fourth  consumer  at  C3.  Connecting  C3  with  the  pole  0 
yields  pole  line  OC3  with  M2,  the  source  of  the  second  raw  material, 
as  the  point  of  intersection  and  thus  the  logical  production  point  for 
C3.  For  C4,  M2  is  the  transport  optimal  point,  too.  This  is  so  even 
though  the  pole  line  OC4  does  not  intersect  the  circumscribed  circle 
at  M2  but  rather  at  a  point  outside  the  locational  triangle  C4M1M2. 
At  M2  the  external  angle  of  the  locational  triangle  is  less  than  the 
corresponding  angle  of  the  weight  triangle.  This  fact  indicates  pro- 
duction at  M2. 

As  with  C3  and  C4,  we  derive  that  consumption  points  C5  and  Cq 
should  be  served  by  a  producer  at  a  raw  material  source,  this  time  Mi , 
the  source  of  the  first  raw  material.  When  we  consider  the  consumer 
at  C7,  once  more  we  have  the  situation  where  the  pole  line  OC7  does 
not  intersect  the  circumscribed  circle  at  a  point  within  the  locational 
triangle  C7M1M2.  Angle  conditions  yield  C7  as  the  logical  point  of 
production  for  the  consumer  at  Cj. 

Smce  it  can  be  demonstrated  that  the  breakdown  of  situations  for 
the  consumer  field  lying  below  a  straight  line  coursing  through  Mi 
and  M2  is  an  exact  reflection  of  the  breakdown  of  situations  above 
the  line,  we  can  generalize.  For  pU  consumers  in  the  horizontally 
dashed  area,  including  the  boundary  lines,  production  should  be  at  M2. 
For  all  consumers  in  the  vertically  dashed  area,  production  should  be 
at  Ml .  For  all  consumers  along  any  given  pole  line,  production  should 
be  at  the  intersection  of  that  pole  line  and  the  relevant  circumscribed 
circle.  For  each  point  of  consumption  in  the  dotted  area,  production 
should  be  located  at  that  very  point.     Thus  we  obtain  an  infinite 


258 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


number  of  logical  production  points  contained  within  and  lying  on  the 
two  relevant  circular  arcs  of  Fig.  44.  In  this  way  the  graphic  presenta- 
tion of  transport-orientation  when  a  weight  triangle  generally  exists 
is  extended  to  embrace  an  area  of  consumers,  whether  or  not  consumers 
are  actually  spread  continuously  throughout  the  area.  2 


Fig.  45.    The  effects  of  a  weight  change. 


Despite  its  unreality,  this  derivation  of  Launhardt  and  Palander 
can  yield  fruitful  insights,  as  Palander  has  demonstrated.  For  ex- 
ample, consider  the  effect  of  technological  change.  Such  change  may 
result  in  the  use  of  a  new  raw  material  source,  or  the  use  of  a  new 
process  of  production  utilizing  the  same  or  different  raw  materials,  or 
some  other  change  in  the  transformation  function.  Suppose  we  take 
a  situation  where  the  efl&ciency  in  the  use  of  a  material,  say  coal,  is 
increased,  ceteris  paribus.  Coal  is  located  at  M^  in  Fig.  45  drawn 
largely  from  Palander.  ^  Before  the  technological  change,  the  spatial 
production  and  market  patterns  are  given  by  the  heavy  lines.  (For 
the  moment  ignore  the  unmarked  area  around  L.)  The  new  spatial 
patterns  consequent  to  the  reduction  in  the  weight  of  coal  per  unit 
product  are  given  by  the  dashed  lines.  The  shaded  areas  indicate 
changes.  The  area  tributary  to  M^  (the  source  of  coal)  contracts, 
that  to  M2  increases.  The  area  in  which  production  is  market- 
oriented  also  expands.    Simultaneously,  all  the  production  points  de- 

2  When  a  weight  triangle  does  not  exist,  i.e.,  when  the  weight  of  a  raw  material 
or  the  product  is  dominant,  production  for  all  consumers  whether  they  are  con- 
centrated at  a  point  or  scattered  takes  place  at  a  raw  material  source  (when  a 
raw  material  is  dominant)  or  always  at  the  market  (when  the  product  is  dominant) . 

3  Palander,  op.  cit.,  p.  153. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       259 

pendent  on  markets  along  a  pole  line  shift  position,  e.g.,  P3  loses  its 
market  along  a  pole  line  and  P3'  comes  to  serve  consumers  along  such 
a  line. 

It  could  have  been  the  case  that  before  the  technological  change  coal 
was  dominant.  The  entire  area  under  consideration  would  have  been 
tributary  to  Mi  (vertically  dashed).  With  technological  change  coal 
loses  its  dominance,  and  this  Palander-type  diagram  suggests  a  theo- 
retical location  pattern  that  might  emerge.  Or,  given  the  situation 
as  initially  depicted,  the  technological  change  might  have  completely 
eliminated  the  use  of  the  raw  material  at  Mi.  The  resulting  new 
pattern  would  not  have  a  vertically  dashed  area. 

In  this  way  and  others  the  Launhardt-Palander  construction  can 
give  insights  into  locational  shifts.  It  particularly  points  up  some 
of  the  dynamic  locational  implications  of  changing  weight  relations 
whether  the  changes  are  due  to  technological  advance  or  to  other  forces. 
It  also  can  be  employed  theoretically  to  anticipate  some  of  the 
locational  effects  of  the  exploitation  of  a  new  raw  material  source* 
or  market  potential. 

In  Chap.  6  we  treat  the  case  of  labor  and  other  similar  types  of 
orientation.  The  shift  of  a  production  process  from  the  transport 
optimal  point  to  a  cheap  labor  point  lying  within  the  critical  isodapane 
of  the  relevant  locational  figure  is  depicted  as  the  substitution  of  trans- 
port outlays  for  labor  outlays.  In  addition  to  permitting  both  a  more 
direct  attack  upon  the  problem  when  several  cheap  labor  points  exist 
and  a  more  comprehensive  presentation  of  the  interrelations  of  labor 
outlays  and  other  types  of  production  outlays  as  well  as  of  the  different 
kinds  of  labor  outlays,  the  substitution  approach  allows  a  closer  tie 
with  production  theory  in  general. 

Somewhat  similar  statements  relate  to  orientation  to  a  cheap  power 
site,  to  a  low  tax  site,  to  a  low  rent  site,  or  to  any  site  at  which  a 
significant  saving  in  a  given  type  of  production  outlay  (or  increase 
in  revenue)  is  obtainable.  Substitution  between  transport  outlay 
(which  tends  to  vary  systematically  with  distance  from  a  given 
reference  point)  and  any  other  outlay  or  revenue  (which  tends  to  vary 
haphazardly  with  distance  from  a  reference  point),  whether  or  not 
depicted  in  terms  of  outlay-substitution,  iso-outlay,  and  other  lines 
of  like  character,  is  a  fruitful  alternative  to  the  critical  isodapane 
technique.  It  can  be  extended,  though  with  decreasing  returns,  to 
embrace  meaningful  groups  of  outlays  (and  revenues). 

Incorporation  of  labor  or  a  similar  type  of  orientation  into  the 
Launhardt-Palander  construction  is  easily  achieved.     In  Fig.  45  let 

4  In  this  connection,  see  Palander,  op.  cit.,  pp.  157-162. 


260  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

L  be  a  cheap  labor  location.  For  each  of  the  innumerable  points  in  the 
market  region,  we  construct  a  locational  triangle  as  before.  Around 
each  locational  triangle,  we  construct  the  critical  isodapane  with 
reference  to  point  L.  We  group  together  those  locational  triangles 
within  whose  critical  isodapanes  point  L  falls.  The  market  points 
corresponding  to  these  locational  triangles  together  comprise  the 
consumer  market  served  by  the  cheap  labor  location.  They  are  indi- 
cated in  Fig.  45  by  the  unmarked  area  centering  around  L.  The 
boundary  line  between  the  market  area  tributary  to  L  and  that  to  M-^ 
is  a  locus  of  market  points  corresponding  to  the  locational  triangles 
whose  critical  isodapanes  course  through  point  L. 

Clearly,  if  the  labor  cost  advantage  of  L  increases,  the  consumer 
market  tributary  to  L  expands.  At  one  extreme  the  total  area  becomes 
tributary  to  L.  At  the  other  extreme,  as  the  labor  cost  advantage  of  L 
diminishes,  the  consumer  market  served  by  L  is  entirely  regained 
by  Ml. 

In  like  manner,  we  can  insert  other  cheap  labor  sites,  cheap  power 
sites,  cheap  tax  sites,  etc.  into  Fig.  45  and  determine  the  consumer 
points,  if  any,  which  might  be  served  by  these  sites.  In  this  way,  the 
transport-orientation  problem  already  extended  to  embrace  many 
market  points,  is  converted  into  a  more  generalized  location  problem 
which  considers  the  pull  of  sites  possessing  advantages  with  reference 
to  factors  other  than  transport  and  relative  spatial  position. 

Viewed  from  a  different  angle,  the  location  of  production  at  L  plays 
up  another  phase  of  location  theory,  namely,  market  area  analysis. 
The  market  area  variable  does  not  crop  up  when  we  consider  the  typical 
Weberian  problem  where  the  market  is  concentrated  at  a  point.  Point 
L  either  is  or  is  not  the  best  site  at  which  to  produce  to  serve  that  point. 
When  many  market  points  exist,  the  identification  of  those  points  to  be 
served  by  production  at  L  becomes  a  problem  of  defining  a  boundary 
line  cutting  across  a  market  region.  In  Fig.  45  we  need  not  adopt  the 
cumbersome  procedure  of  constructing  for  each  market  point  a  loca- 
tional triangle  and  its  critical  isodapane  to  determine  points  to  be 
served  by  L.  Rather  we  can  view  L  and  Mj  as  two  points,  each 
producing  at  constant  though  different  unit  costs  and  competing  for 
the  market  in  Mj's  hinterland.  This  is  a  customary  market  area 
problem. 

In  Chap.  7,  we  treat  market  and  supply  area  analysis.  Once  again 
it  is  demonstrated  that  all  such  analysis  can  be  embraced  by  a  general 
substitution  framework  involving  substitution  among  transport  inputs 
and  among  outlays  and  revenues.  This  can  be  shown  whether  we 
consider  a  single  isolated  monopolist,  a  set  of  competing  firms  pro- 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       261 

ducing  at  constant  or  variable  unit  costs,  a  single  consumption  market, 
or  several  competing  markets  offering  the  same  or  different  prices  for 
a  commodity.  The  substitution  relations  among  various  types  of 
transport  inputs  in  the  analysis  of  market  and  supply  areas  are 
particularly  pointed  up  in  Sect.  2  of  Chap.  10. 

As  already  indicated,  the  introduction  of  a  cheap  labor  point  into 
the  Launhardt-Palander  construction  can  simultaneously  introduce 
a  market  area  problem.  It  is  instructive,  however,  to  inject  the  market 
area  problem  into  this  construction  in  another  way. 


::L  L- 


:;i;:::::;4;Mi:::::::::::::i::: 


Fig. 


46.    Division  of  a  market  region  between  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw 
materials. 


Suppose  we  have  a  situation  where,  owing  to  the  addition  of 
ubiquities,  the  weight  of  product  becomes  dominant.  Production 
becomes  market-oriented,  except  for  a  small  area  tributary  to  L.  The 
dotted  area  bounded  by  the  two  circular  arcs  in  Fig.  45  expands  to 
include  almost  the  entire  region.  See  Fig.  46.  Into  this  situation  we 
now  allow  a  second  deposit  of  each  raw  material,  which  we  designate 
Ml'  and  M2  respectively.  Since  we  still  postulate  that  the  transport 
rate  structure  is  proportional  to  weight  and  distance  and  since  we  take 
the  price  (unit  cost)  of  the  first  raw  material  to  be  less  at  ilf  1  than  at 
Ml'  we  obtain  a  hyperbola  as  a  boundary  line  (the  locus  of  equal 
delivered  prices) .  It  delineates  the  market  area  of  industrial  consumers 
tributary  to  source  Mi  and  that  tributary  to  Mi'.  Additionally,  since 
we  take  the  price  of  the  second  raw  material  to  be  the  same  at  both 
M2  and  M2',  we  obtain  a  straight  line  boundary  which  marks  off 
the  market  areas  of  industrial  consumers  served  by  each  of  these  two 
sources.    Except  for  the  small  district  of  household  consumers  oriented 


262 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


to  production  at  L,  we  demarcate  altogether  four  districts  of  industrial 
consumers,  each  employing  the  same  combination  of  raw  materials,  but 
each  procuring  them  from  a  different  combination  of  sources.  Since 
production  is  market-oriented,  there  is  spatially  coincident  with  each 
district  of  industrial  consumers  a  district  of  household  consumers.  It 
is  hardly  necessary  to  repeat  that,  if  an  industrial  consumer  procures 


Fig.  47.    Spatial  production  patterns:  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw  materials, 
one  labor  location. 


any  raw  material  from  a  source  other  than  indicated,  he  will  find  it 
profitable  to  switch  his  allegiance.  In  doing  so,  he  will  effect  the 
socially  desirable  substitutions  between  transport  inputs  on  raw 
material  from  one  source  and  the  other  and  between  production  outlays 
at  one  source  and  the  other. 

Figure  46  presents  a  rather  simple  and  conventional  case  of  market 
delineation.  It  is  fruitful  to  investigate  a  more  complicated  situation. 
Suppose  we  eliminate  the  ubiquities  required  in  production  and  postu- 
late that  equal  weights  of  the  two  raw  materials  and  finished  product 
are  pertinent.  Further,  let  us  follow  Palander  and  add  to  Fig.  45,  as 
he  has  done,  an  additional  source  of  the  first  raw  material  at  M^';  and 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       263 

of  the  second  at  M2'.  Accordingly,  we  derive  Fig.  47  which  is  largely 
taken  from  Palander.  Once  again,  aside  from  the  district  of  household 
consumers  served  from  the  cheap  labor  point  L,  we  obtain  four 
groupings  of  industrial  consumers,  whose  respective  districts  of  house- 
hold consumers  are  indicated  by  double-weight  solid  lines.  ^  This 
time,  however,  production  in  each  of  these  four  districts  need  not  be 
market-oriented. 

In  district  a,  households  are  served  by  producers  who  utilize  raw 
materials  from  sources  M^  and  ^2'.^  Production  takes  place  at  the 
raw  material  sources,  at  market  points,  and  at  points  where  relevant 
pole  lines  intersect  with  an  arc  of  a  circle  circumscribed  about  the 
relevant  weight  triangle.  At  the  lower  right,  district  a  is  partly  bounded 
by  district  c.  In  district  c  producers  at  raw  material  sources,  market 
points,  and  intersection  points  procure  their  raw  materials  from  Mi' 
and  M2.  District  a  is  also  partly  bounded  by  district  d.  In  district  d 
all  producers  are  market-oriented;  they  obtain  raw  materials  from  Mi' 
and  M2'.  Because  this  pair  of  raw  material  sources  is  separated  by  a 
greater  distance  than  any  other  relevant  pair,  its  competitive  ability 
is  not  so  great.'''  The  district  of  household  consumers  which  this  pair 
of  sources  can  indirectly  serve  with  economy  is  the  most  restricted  of 
the  four.  It  contrasts  with  the  pair  of  sources,  M^'  and  M2,  which 
being  the  closest  of  any  relevant  pair  serves  indirectly  the  largest 
district  of  household  consumers. 

Finally  at  the  upper  right,  district  a  is  bounded  by  district  b.  Since 
M2  and  M2'  are  equally  distant  from  Mj  and  since  they  supply  the 
second  raw  material  at  the  same  price,  it  is  indifferent  whether  produc- 
tion at  Ml  is  based  upon  either  of  these  sources  of  the  second  raw 
material.  Therefore,  the  subdistrict  served  by  Mi  can  be  part  of  either 
a  or  b. 

Figure  47  neatly  illustrates  how  a  market  region  of  household 
consumers  can  be  indirectly,  via  industrial  producers,  assigned  to  the 
market  areas  of  competing  raw  material  sources.  For  example,  in 
district  c  none  of  the  ultimate  consumers  procures  his  raw  materials 
directly  from  Mi'  and  M2.  Rather,  household  consumers  are  served 
by  industrial  producers  who  directly  consume  the  raw  materials  from 
Ml'  and  M2  and  who  at  times  may  be  located  at  the  point  of  ultimate 

5  These  lines  are  loci  of  equal  delivered  prices  to  household  consumers. 

6  Sources  Mi  and  ilf  2'  also  furnish  the  raw  materials  for  the  production  of  the 
goods  consumed  by  households  in  the  unmarked  area  tributary  to  L. 

■^  Palander's  diagram  and  discussion  suggest  that  he  postulates  for  the  first  raw 
material  the  same  price  at  each  of  its  two  sources,  and  likewise  for  the  second 
raw  material. 


264  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

consumption.  Thus,  boundary  lines  which  pertain  here  to  the  division 
of  a  market  region  of  ultimate  consumers  are  more  complex  than  those 
discussed  in  the  first  two  sections  of  Chap.  7  and  illustrated  in  Fig.  46. 
This  is  so  because  a  complex  transport-orientation  problem  as  well  as 
a  market  area  problem  is  involved.  Boundary  lines  come  to  be  defined 
by  substitution  points  which  have  reference  to  transport  inputs  on  the 
finished  product,  transport  inputs  on  the  first  raw  material,  transport 
inputs  on  the  second  raw  material,  and,  if  a  cheap  labor  location 
exists,  labor  outlays  and  transport  outlays. 

It  is  to  be  noted  that  when  we  consider  the  market  of  industrial 
producers  who  are  supplied  with  raw  materials  we  find  it  to  be 
discontinuous  because  of  the  transport-orientation  problem  which  is 
involved.  Industrial  production  occurs  only  on  the  four  pairs  of 
circular  arcs,  or  within  the  areas  contained  by  them,  and  at  L.  The 
sole  section  at  which  there  is  effective  competition  between  alternative 
sources  of  a  raw  material,  of  the  sort  illustrated  by  Fig.  46,  is  along 
the  straight  line  from  M-^  to  A.  Along  this  stretch,  industrial  producers 
are  indifferent  as  to  the  source  of  their  second  raw  material.  ^ 

As  is  widely  recognized,  the  sharpness  of  the  boundary  lines  presented 
in  Fig.  47  as  well  as  in  preceding  figures  is  much  exaggerated. 
Producers  who  compete  for  the  household  market  do  not  behave 
according  to  the  criteria  which  have  been  implicitly  assumed.  They 
generally  do  not  establish  at  the  factory  a  single  price  based  on  unit 
cost  and  applicable  to  all  customers.  They  typically  are  able  to 
influence  price,  to  discriminate  among  consumers,  to  induce  consumers 
by  advertising,  price  cuts,  or  other  means  to  shift  their  allegiance 
from  a  competitor.  Producers  relocate  at  times,  take  cognizance  of 
each  other's  reactions,  form  coalitions,  set  prices  and  quotas.  All  these 
types  of  monopolistic  and  oligopolistic  behavior  tend  to  invalidate 
the  simple,  clear-cut  boundary  lines  customarily  depicted.  At  best 
boundary  lines  are  blurred  and  tend  to  degenerate  into  overlapping 
zones. 

Even  if  we  were  to  allow  zonal  types  of  boundaries,  cross-hauling,  and 
market  interpenetration  in  the  above  diagrams,  we  must  recognize  that 
the  geographic  patterns  of  production  which  they  would  depict  have 
limited  validity.  When  we  treated,  in  Sect.  3  of  Chap.  7,  the  simple 
case  of  locational  equilibrium  along  a  line  where  pricing  policy  and  firm 

8  When  the  raw  material  sources  are  pulled  farther  apart,  even  this  competitive 
stretch  disappears.    See  Palander,  o-p.  cit.,  Figs.  27  and  28. 

It  should  also  be  noted  that  along  stretch  BD  of  Fig.  47,  the  two  producers 
located  at  M\'  and  M2'  compete  for  household  consumers  in  a  way  consistent 
with  the  simpler  framework  discussed  in  Chap.  7. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       265 

location  were  variables,  as  they  are  in  reality,  we  noted  that  many 
types  of  location  patterns  were  possible,  depending  upon  one's  set  of 
initial  assumptions.  Even  the  application  of  the  powerful  tools  of  game 
theory  does  not,  at  the  present  time,  cast  additional  light  on  the  elusive 
problem  of  rational  behavior  for  a  group  of  firms  in  terms  of  their 
pricing  and  location  policies.  Thus  we  must  contantly  bear  in  mind 
that  Fig.  47  and  similar  diagrams  pertain  to  a  situation  which  abstracts 
from  interest  conflicts,  undercutting  and  retaliation,  advertising 
strategies,  collusive  action,  market  encroachment,  and  similar 
phenomena  characteristic  of  firm  behavior. 

In  addition  to  exaggerating  the  sharpness  of  boundary  lines  and  the 
detenninateness  of  locational  equilibrium,  we  greatly  overstate  in 
Fig.  47  the  number  of  producers.  We  derive  this  unrealistic  result 
because  Fig.  47  is  a  theoretical  construction  which  abstracts  from  a 
number  of  forces,  especially  economies  of  scale  both  in  production  and 
transportation. 

In  Chap.  8  we  treat  economies  of  scale  as  a  subset  of  agglomeration 
factors,  localization  economies  and  urbanization  economies  being  the 
other  two  subsets.  We  recognize  that  these  three  subsets  are  not  always 
clearly  distinguishable  from  one  another.  Section  1  of  Chap.  8  demon- 
strates how  the  economies  of  scale  factor  can  be  frequently  embodied 
in  a  substitution  of  transport  outlays  for  production  outlays  in  gen- 
eral. The  achievement  of  these  economies  of  scale  can  be  visualized 
in  many  instances  as  a  movement  along  an  outlay- substitution  line 
on  to  a  lower  iso-outlay  line. 

The  impact  of  economies  of  scale  can  be  easily  portrayed.  In  Fig. 
47  the  smallest  scale  of  output  is  associated  with  those  producers 
who  are  market-oriented.  Granted  significant  economies  of  scale,  we 
have  postulated  that  output  in  each  of  the  three  largest  market-oriented 
production  areas  will  be  concentrated  at  a  single  (central)  point. 
These  points  are  designated  as  I^,  h,  and  /o  in  Fig.  48. ^  We  also 
assume  that  the  smallest  market-oriented  production  area,  the  d  dis- 
trict, does  not  have  a  demand  sufficient  to  justify  a  production  point 
within  its  bounds  when  economies  of  scale  exist. 

In  Fig.  47,  the  production  points  serving  consumers  along  one  and 
only  one  pole  line  also  operate  at  a  small  scale.  In  a  setting  in 
which  there  are  significant  scale  economies,  we  postulate  that  along 
any  one  arc  production  will  be  concentrated  at  a  single  point.    Thus 

9  These  points  as  well  as  others  which  are  identified  are  only  roughly  located. 
We  do  not  attempt  in  this  and  the  following  figures  to  determine  a  set  of  produc- 
tion points  and  market  areas  consistent  with  a  given  scale  economy  function. 
These  figures  are  for  illustrative  purposes  only. 


266 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


we  account  for  points  Pi,  P2,  P3,  P^,  and  P5  of  Fig.  48. 10  Finally, 
we  posit  that  the  scale  of  output  at  each  of  the  raw  material  points 
and  the  cheap  labor  point  in  Fig.  47  is  large  enough  to  warrant  the 
retention  of  each  as  a  production  point  in  Fig.  48. 


Fig.  48.    Spatial  production  patterns:  scale  economies  introduced. 


Thus  Fig.  48  depicts  a  situation  reflecting  the  impact  of  the  scale 
variable.  It  portrays  a  much  more  realistic  production  pattern 
than  that  of  Fig.  47.  Because  only  a  relatively  few  production  points 
are  justified,  each  production  point  comes  to  serve  a  market  area. 
The  cases  of  production  for  a  single  market  point  or  a  single  pole 
line  are  eliminated.  Market  boundary  lines,  of  the  type  illustrated  in 
Fig.  46,  become  significant  once  again,  as  they  are  in  blurred  form 
in  reality.  However,  since  there  are  many  competing  production  sites 
surrounding  any  given  producing  location,  the  boundary  line  determin- 
ing the  market  area  served  by  this  location  is  a  connected  series  of 
different  types  of  boundary  stretches,  where  each  stretch  pertains 

10  We  do  not  allow  for  any  production  points  on  the  circular  arcs  enclosing  dis- 
trict d  and  on  the  lower  circular  arc  of  district  b.  There  is  no  pole  line  market 
for  the  former  and  too  small  a  market  to  justify  the  latter. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYT^THESIS  AND  SUMMARY       267 

to  the  competition  between  the  given  location  and  one  other  producing 
site.  11 

As  the  next  step  in  our  graphic  presentation,  imagine  that  the  sources 
of  the  two  raw  materials  are  multiplied  many  times  so  that  for  all 
practical  purposes  the  two  raw  materials  become  ubiquities,  each 
available  everywhere  at  the  same  price.  Further,  take  consumers 
of  like  taste  and  stamp  to  be  uniformly  distributed,  and  adopt  Losch's 
various  other  assumptions  and  conditions  pertaining  to  his  market  area 
analysis,  which  we  have  noted  several  times.  One  can  easily  visualize 
how  the  pattern  of  production  sites  takes  on  a  uniform  character  such 
as  to  yield  the  logically  derived  pattern  of  hexagonal  market  areas.  12 
Thus,  from  this  angle,  the  Losch  derivation  can  be  considered  as  a 
special  case  of  the  Launhardt-Palander  construction  into  which  the 
factor  of  economies  of  scale  has  been  injected.  In  his  derivation 
Losch  has  pointed  up  the  conflicting  pulls  of  the  scale  variable  and 
the  transport  outlay  variable;  in  essence,  the  basic  substitution  re- 
lation between  transport  outlays  and  production  outlays.  As  with  the 
Launhardt-Palander  construction,  the  Losch  derivation  is  implied  by 
the  principles  governing  substitution  among  transport  inputs  once 
Losch's  set  of  assumptions  is  admitted.  This  is  demonstrated  in  Sect. 
4  of  Chap.  10. 

We  proceed  with  the  summary  discussion  of  Chap.  8.  Section  2 
of  this  chapter  treats  localization  economies,  a  second  subset  of  ag- 
glomeration economies.  In  contrast  to  scale  economies  which  are  in- 
ternal to  a  firm,  localization  economies  are  external  to  a  firm.  They 
are  contingent  upon  the  spatial  juxtaposition  of  several  firms  of  like 
character.  They  are  reflected,  for  example,  in  lower  cost  service  inputs 
when  such  juxtaposition  permits  the  more  efficient  use  of  an  auxiliary 
repair  facility. 

The  realization  of  localization  economies  involves  a  physical  move 
and  additional  transport  outlays  by  at  least  one  firm.  At  least  one 
firm  must  and  will  find  it  profitable  to  substitute  transport  outlays 
for  production  outlays  in  general.  Exactly  which  firm  or  firms  will 
relocate  and  exactly  which  points  will  prove  to  be  the  points  of  ag- 
glomeration are  questions  which  revolve  around  a  complex  interplay 
of  historical  and  institutional  forces  relating  to  decision  making  and 

11  The  interested  reader  may  construct  these  boundary  lines  for  himself.  He  is 
reminded  that  the  market  areas  of  the  raw  material  sources  and  the  cheap  labor 
site  are  greater  than  the  corresponding  ones  of  Fig.  47.  Production  sites  which 
effectively  compete  with  the  raw  material  sources  and  L  are  farther  removed  from 
them  in  Fig.  48  than  in  Fig.  47. 

12  See  Fig.  51  below  for  an  illustration  of  several  nets  of  hexagonal  market  areas. 


268 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


rational  behavior  by  the  firm.  We  have  as  yet  been  unable  to  un- 
ravel the  concrete  manifestations  of  this  interplay.  The  clearest  picture 
of  the  degree  and  pattern  of  localization  and  of  specific  substitutions 
emerges  when  we  abstract  from  these  forces  and  approach  from  a  social 
welfare  standpoint  the  problem  of  industrial  planning  for  a  completely 
undeveloped  region. 


Fig.  49.    Spatial  production  patterns :  localization  and  scale  economies  introduced. 


For  illustrative  purposes,  we  posit  as  only  one  of  many  possible 
situations  that  depicted  by  Fig.  49.  (For  the  moment  ignore  the 
small  circles  which  are  not  filled  in.)  In  this  situation,  firms  Ii,  P2, 
and  Pi  have  relocated  around  M2'  to  realize  localization  economies; 
P3  and  I2  around  Mj ;  P4 ,  P5 ,  and  I^  around  M2 ;  and  none  around 
Ml'  and  L. 

Into  the  locational  pattern  of  Fig.  49,  we  can  introduce  the  forces 
associated  with  urbanization  economies,  the  third  subset  of  agglomera- 
tion economies.  To  do  so  compels  us  to  expand  into  a  multicommodity 
framework  since,  as  already  noted,  urbanization  economies  refer  to 
those  savings  in  production  outlays  which  are  realizable  when  firms 
producing  a  variety  of  commodities  agglomerate  around  a  point.  As 
we  have  discussed  in  Sect.  3  of  Chap.  8,  urbanization  economies,  like 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       269 

localization  economies,  reflect  a  complex  interplay  of  historical  and 
institutional  forces.  The  factors  governing  the  specific  localities  at 
which  different  degrees  of  urbanization  economies  become  obtainable 
are  beyond  the  pale  of  our  current  analytic  frameworks.  We  can  only 
make  the  simple  statement  that  for  many  firms  the  advantages  of 


•v^ 


■  00  + 


Fig.  50.    Spatial    production    patterns:     urbanization,     localization,    and    scale 
economies  introduced. 

locating  at  an  urban  center  outweigh  the  advantages  of  a  non-urban 
location.  The  decision  to  settle  in  an  urban  area  thereby  involves 
substitutions  among  various  outlays  and  revenues. 

We  portray  the  impact  of  urbanization  economies  with  the  use  of 
Fig.  50.  In  Fig.  49  we  have  already  noted  the  fairly  concentrated 
geographic  pattern  of  production  to  which  localization  economies 
lead  when  only  a  single  commodity  is  considered.  Suppose  in  Fig.  49 
we  also  depict,  for  the  given  region  or  nation,  the  geographic  pattern 
of  firms  producing  a  second  commodity.  These  firms  are  represented 
by  the  small  circles  which  are  not  filled  in.  Their  pattern  also 
reflects  localization  economies.  A  geographic  pattern  of  firms  pro- 
ducing a  third  commodity  could  be  marked  in  Fig.  49.  Likewise, 
for  a  fourth,  fifth  .  .  .  and  nth  commodity.  To  avoid  confusion  these 
have  not  been  presented  in  Fig.  49. 

In  Fig.  50  urbanization  economies  act  to  bring  together  the  firms 
represented  by  the  small  black  and  white  circles  which  would  other- 
wise be  separated  as  in  Fig.  49.  In  some  instances  the  firms  pro- 
ducing the  second  commodity  shift  to  a  center  of  production  of  the 
first  commodity ;  in  other  instances  the  firms  producing  the  first  com- 


270 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


modity  shift  to  a  center  of  the  second.  To  these  sets  of  locations 
on  Fig.  50  we  have  added  sets  of  locations  of  firms  producing  a  third, 
fourth,  and  fifth  commodity,  represented  respectively  by  small  black 
squares,  crosses,  and  white  triangles.    In  the  absence  of  urbanization 


Fig.  51.    A  simple  Losch  system  of  nets  of  market  areas.     (Source:   Adapted 

from  A.  Losch,  The  Economics  of  Location,  Yale  University  Press,  New  Haven, 

Conn.,  1954,  Fig.  28.) 


economies,  many  of  the  firms  producing  the  third  and  fourth  com- 
modities would  be  situated  differently.  Not  so,  however,  with  the 
firms  producing  the  fifth  commodity,  whose  locations  are  indicated 
by  white  triangles.  They  are  not  led  to  relocate  because  of  the 
pull  of  urbanization  economies.  Moreover,  they  are  not  very  sensitive 
to  localization  economies.    They  retain  a  fairly  dispersed  pattern. 

A  second,  less  satisfactory  way  of  graphically  depicting  the  impact 
of  urbanization  economies  is  to  follow  Losch.    In  Fig.  51,  we  repro- 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       271 

duce  one  of  Losch's  inconsistent  diagrams.  This  diagram  involves 
the  superimposition  of  several  nets  of  hexagonal  market  areas,  i^  As- 
sociated with  each  net  is  a  set  of  commodities  resembling  each  other 
only  in  that  they  have  market  areas  of  the  same  size  and  are  produced 
at  each  of  the  same  set  of  production  points.  The  several  nets  of 
market  areas  are  arranged  with  at  least  one  production  center  in 
common  and  so  that,  according  to  Losch:  (1)  the  greatest  number 
of  locations  coincide;  (2)  local  effective  demand  is  at  a  maximum; 
(3)  the  sum  of  the  shortest  distances  between  industrial  locations 
is  at  a  minimum;  and,  as  a  consequence,  (4)  shipments  and  total 
length  of  transport  lines  are  at  a  minimum.  To  this  diagram  we  have 
added  Losch's  twelve  major  radial  transport  routes;  and  we  have 
indicated  his  six  sectors  rich  in  number  of  production  sites  (shaded) 
and  his  six  sectors  poor  in  number  of  production  sites  (unshaded) . 

Perhaps  the  most  serious  deficiency  of  this  Loschian  construction  is 
that  it  yields  different  sizes  of  concentrations  of  industrial  activity  and 
thus  jobs  at  various  production  centers,  and  yet  it  postulates  uniform 
distribution  of  consuming  population.  It  is  beyond  the  scope  of  this 
volume  to  modify  the  Loschian  argument  in  order  to  eliminate  this 
inconsistency.  However,  it  is  clear  that  the  Loschian  diagram  would 
need  to  exhibit  for  each  commodity  greater  concentrations  of  market 
areas  and  producers  about  the  central  city  (the  common  production 
center)  in  order  to  square  with  the  central  city's  high  level  of  industrial 
activity  and  large  laboring  population.  We  construct  Fig.  52  merely 
to  suggest  such  greater  concentrations.  In  Fig.  52  at  the  lower  right 
we  have  indicated  a  second,  though  less  important  center,  at  which 
production  activity  is  concentrated.  Also,  below  and  to  the  right  of 
this  second  center  is  a  set  of  zones  which  is  to  be  ignored  for  the  present. 

Because  Losch's  construction  implies  a  relatively  high  density  of 
laborers  and  thus  population  at  the  core,  the  size  of  a  market  area  in 
square  kilometers  necessary  to  generate  sufficient  demand  for  a  com- 
modity to  justify  production  is  much  smaller  at  the  core  than  at  a  great 
distance  from  the  core.  Further,  at  a  great  distance  from  the  core, 
market  areas  must  be  much  larger  because  not  only  are  production 
sites  and  industrial  population  fewer  in  number  but  also,  as  a  logical 
consequence  of  differential  industrial  population,  agricultural  activity 
is  less  intensive  and  agricultural  population  more  sparse  than  in  the 
immediate  hinterland  of  the  central  city.  Thus,  we  obtain  a  pattern  of 
distorted  hexagons  (if  we  insist  on  maintaining  the  hexagonal  form) 
which  in  general  decrease  in  size  as  we  approach  the  central  city  from 

13  Specifically,  the  figure  covers  only  four  sizes  of  market  areas,  the  four  smallest 
of  the  th-^oretical  ones  derived  by  Losch. 


272 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


\  / 

y    A 


/ 


/    \- 

T^Mi 

R?       i 

^ 

<^ 

il 

rWCV    . 

1  i 

"\ 

---J., 


Fig.  52.    A  modified  Losch  system  consistent  with  resulting 
population  distribution. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       273 

any  direction.  In  fact  at  the  central  city  the  hexagonal  market  areas 
are  so  small  for  certain  commodities  that  they  reduce  to  points  when 
we  attempt  to  depict  them  on  a  small  scale  figure.  On  Fig.  52  we  por- 
tray this  reduction  to  points  for  two  sets  of  commodities,  where  each 
set  would  have  a  market  area  of  different  size  in  Losch's  scheme,  i^ 
(To  avoid  confusion  we  present  in  Fig.  52  hypothetical  market  areas 
for  only  three  sets  of  commodities.  The  reader  may  superimpose 
others.) 

In  Fig.  52  we  have  indicated  a  secondary  center  at  which  production 
sites  and  thus  industrial  population  are  concentrated.  Once  again,  the 
hexagonal  market  areas  decrease  in  size  as  we  approach  the  core. 
Moreover,  as  Losch  recognized,  economic  forces  lead  to  the  develop- 
ment around  each  core  of  sectors  alternately  rich  and  poor  in  number 
of  production  sites.  This  is  depicted  with  respect  to  both  centers. 
Further,  the  number  of  production  sites  tends  to  be  greater  in  any 
sector  as  the  concentrations  of  production  sites  (cities)  which  the 
transport  route  coursing  through  the  sector  interconnects  grow  larger 
in  magnitude.  15  This  relation  is  shown  in  Fig.  52  by  the  heavier  con- 
centrations of  production  sites,  and  generally  smaller  hexagonal  market 
areas,  along  the  transport  route  which  interconnects  the  two  centers 
indicated.  Actually,  we  should  have  presented  in  Fig.  52  secondary 
centers  (smaller  in  size  than  the  first)  along  each  transport  route  and 
a  hierarchical  array  of  satellite  centers,  as  is  a  logical  consequence 
of  the  Loschian  argument  and  as  occurs  in  reality.  In  order  to  avoid  a 
complicated  and  visually  meaningless  diagram,  we  have  not  done  so.^^ 

Thus  Fig.  52  suggests  the  impact  of  urbanization  economies  upon 
the  spatial  pattern  of  production  sites  when  the  Losch  uniformity 

^■^  With  reference  to  these  two  sets  of  commodities  we  attempted  to  adhere  to 
the  second  and  fourth  smallest  of  Losch's  theoretical  market  areas.  Because  of 
specifications  for  constructing  Fig.  52  which  are  cited  below,  we  were  not  able  to 
do  so  in  any  satisfactory  manner. 

1^  Unlike  Losch,  we  locate  major  transport  routes  through  the  heart  of  city-rich 
and  city-poor  sectors  rather  than  at  their  boundaries  in  order  to  catch  more  fully 
the  significant  scale  (urbanization)  economies  in  the  use  of  modern  transport 
media. 

16  For  examples  of  patterns  of  secondary  and  satellite  centers  which  we  have 
in  mind,  the  reader  is  referred  to  the  map :  United  States,  Population  Distribution, 
Urban  and  Rural,  1950,  U.S.  Bureau  of  Census,  Washington,  D.C.,  1953;  to  popu- 
lation dot  and  land  use  maps  for  the  area  around  such  cities  as  Indianapolis;  to 
Robert  E.  Dickinson,  City,  Region  and  Regionalism,  Kegan  Paul,  London,  1947, 
especially  Figs.  2,  5,  24,  32,  and  48;  and  an  expansion  of  a  figure  by  M.  J.  Proud- 
foot  in  Amos  H.  Hawley,  Human  Ecology,  Ronald  Press,  New  York,  1950,  p.  271. 
In  addition,  the  reader  may  gain  some  impression  of  hierarchical  arrangement 
from  Fig.  53  below. 


274  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOM\ 

assumptions  are  admitted,  except  for  modification  with  respect  to 
population  distribution.  The  resulting  'pattern  is  at  best  only  one  of 
many  which  can  be  evolved.^'^  Moreover,  because  of  the  underlying 
uniformity  assumptions,  this  pattern  incorporates  unrealities  in  many 
important  characteristics. 

A  second  basic  limitation  of  the  Loschian  argument  is  that  it  pertains 
to  situations  where  raw  materials  are  not  required  (as  in  service  activi- 
ties) or  are  ubiquitous  and  everywhere  available  at  the  same  costs. 
The  argument  therefore  excludes  that  production  (whether  market-  or 
material-oriented)  where  material  sources  exert  significant  locational 
pulls.  Yet  this  is  the  very  type  of  production  which  Weber  has  treated 
extensively  and  for  which  the  Launhardt-Palander  construction  was 
designed.  It  therefore  seems  generally  more  valid  to  envisage  an  urban 
economy  as  consisting  of  a  concentration  of  firms  using  localized  raw 
materials  18  (such  as  the  concentration  at  the  lower  left  of  Fig.  50) 
upon  which  concentration  is  superimposed  a  modified  Loschian  diagram 
similar  to  Fig.  52  to  account  for  industrial,  commercial,  and  service 
activities  utilizing  ubiquitous  raw  materials  or  none  at  all.  Hence- 
forth, we  have  in  mind  this  type  of  structure  when  we  speak  generally 
of  urban  economies,  i^    We  shall  outline  it  in  some  detail  in  connection 

1''  In  planning  the  construction  of  Fig.  52, 1  instructed  my  draftsman,  Mr.  Gerald 
A.  P.  Carrothers,  to  (1)  retain  the  Loschian  deduction  that  each  producer  of  any 
given  commodity  operates  at  approximately  the  same  cost  so  that  the  boundary 
separating  the  markets  of  any  pair  of  neighboring  producers  is  a  perpendicular 
bisector  of  the  line  connecting  the  two;  (2)  adhere  to  hexagonal  market  areas  in 
so  far  as  possible  in  order  to  deviate  as  little  as  possible  from  the  distinguishing 
characteristic  of  the  Loschian  derivation;  (3)  depict  hexagonal  market  areas  which 
increase  in  size  with  distance  from  the  core  in  any  direction;  and  (4)  construct  the 
hexagonal  market  areas  so  that,  along  any  circle  drawn  with  the  core  as  center,  the 
size  of  the  market  areas  in  general  tends  to  decrease  as  we  approach  the  transport 
axis  of  a  city-rich  sector  and  increase  as  we  approach  the  transport  axis  of  a  city- 
poor  sector.  In  the  time  made  available,  Mr.  Carrothers  was  not  able  to  adhere 
strictly  to  hexagonal  forms.  The  extreme  difficulty  met  in  working  with  hexag- 
onal forms  only  and,  as  a  consequence,  the  need  to  reshuffle  constantly  the  sites 
of  production  in  order  to  meet  this  specification  (for  this  reason  the  contrast 
between  the  size  of  market  areas  in  the  city-poor  and  city-rich  sectors  is  not  as 
sharp  as  we  initially  planned),  strongly  suggest  that  the  hexagon  is  a  pure  concept 
much  as  is  perfect  competition.  The  hexagon  loses  much  of  its  significance  as  a 
spatial  form  once  agglomeration  forces  are  admitted  and,  as  a  logical  outcome, 
inequaUties  in  population  distribution  recognized.  In  general,  non-hexagonal 
forms  are  more  consistent  with  the  full  interplay  of  location  forces. 

18  Raw  materials  are  conceived  broadly  so  as  to  include  semifabricated  and 
fabricated  products  which  are  subject  to  further  processing  as  well  as  minerals 
and  other  substances  in  their  crude  form. 

19  This  is  not  to  deny  that  urban  areas  may  have  as  their  basic  activities  func- 
tions and  services  and  even  industries  which  do  not  utilize  localized  raw  materials. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       275 

with  Fig.  54.  But  first  let  us  proceed  with  our  summary  discussion 
of  Chap.  8. 

Hitherto,  the  discussion  and  figures  of  this  chapter  have  referred  to 
location  factors  as  they  govern  interregional  and  intraregional  distri- 
bution of  basic  industry  and  service  activities  and  the  urbanization 
process.  We  must  now  introduce  those  location  forces  determining 
the  pattern  of  agricultural  land  use. 

In  Sect.  4  of  Chap.  8  the  interaction  of  these  latter  forces  was  dis- 
cussed. The  various  adjustments  of  the  agricultural  farm  enterprise 
were  examined  in  detail.  At  any  given  location,  the  farm  enterprise 
must  select  the  correct  proportion  of  factor  inputs  and  scale  of  opera- 
tions for  the  production  of  any  given  crop  or  commodity  mix;  this 
involves,  in  addition  to  others,  the  basic  substitution  point  between 
land  inputs  and  other  inputs,  between  rent  outlays  and  outlays  on 
inputs  other  than  land.  In  selecting  a  particular  site  for  farming,  the 
enterprise  again  substitutes  between  rent  outlays  and  all  other  outlays 
combined.  However,  this  latter  substitution  decomposes  into  a  subset 
of  substitutions:  one  between  rent  outlays  and  transport  outlays  as 
the  farm  enterprise  considers  locations  at  different  distances  from  the 
market ;  and  another  between  rent  outlays  and  the  sum  of  other  outlays 
(excluding  transport)  since  the  price  of  a  land  input  decreases  with 
distance  from  the  market  and  therefore  leads  to  different  factor  pro- 
portions at  sites  at  different  distances  from  the  market. 

With  respect  to  these  types  of  substitutions,  the  general  location 
analysis  for  the  individual  farm  enterprise  is  identical  with  the  general 
location  analysis  for  the  industrial  firm.  The  farm  enterprise  inten- 
sively uses  land  inputs;  therefore,  to  it,  cost  differentials  among  sites 
on  land  inputs  are  critical.  The  industrial  firm  which  is  labor-oriented 
or  power-oriented  uses  labor  or  power  inputs  intensively;  therefore, 
to  it,  cost  differentials  among  sites  on  labor  inputs  or  power  inputs  are 
critical.  This  firm  confronts  the  same  types  of  substitution  relations 
as  identified  for  the  farm  enterprise  in  the  previous  paragraph,  save 
that  labor  outlays  or  power  outlays  take  the  place  of  rent  outlays. 

In  this  regard  the  traditional  dualism  of  an  industrial  location  theory 
and  an  agricultural  location  theory,  separate  and  for  the  most  part 
unrelated,  loses  most  of  its  significance.  Both  the  location  of  the 
industrial  firm  and  that  of  the  farm  enterprise  can  be  treated  in  the 
same  general  analytic  framework. 

When  we  view  the  location  problem  of  the  farm  enterprise  still  more 


For  example,  medical,  educational,  and  governmental  activities  oriented  to  national 
markets  can  serve  as  basic  activities. 


276  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

comprehensively  within  a  setting  where  market  prices  are  given,  or 
income  and  demand  functions  specified,  and  when  we  confront  the 
enterprise  with  the  problem  of  choosing  a  crop  (commodity-mix)  to 
be  produced,  we  are  able  to  derive  a  set  of  rent  functions.  We  can  do 
this  by  noting  the  substitution  adjustments  of  the  enterprise  at  all 
locations  with  respect  to  each  crop.  These  rent  functions,  as  they  inter- 
sect, permit  the  identification  of  the  familiar  Thiinen  rings,  distorted 
of  course  by  any  restraints  we  may  wish  to  impose  which  relate  to 
resource  content  of  land,  physical  barriers,  legal,  political,  and  social 
institutions,  etc.  When  we  formulate  mathematically  the  substitution 
relations  governing  agricultural  land  use,  as  in  Sect.  5  of  Chap.  10, 
we  are  able  to  harbor  a  still  more  embracive  set  of  situations.  This 
set  can  involve  the  use  of  many  raw  materials,  each  furnished 
from  a  single  source  or  supply  area,  and  a  framework  of  many 
markets. 

A  general  graphic  representation  of  equilibrium  agricultural  land- 
use  patterns,  as  yielded  by  the  analysis,  is  attempted  in  Fig.  53.  Here 
we  consider  a  hierarchy  of  several  urban  areas  and  their  agricultural 
hinterlands.  A  considerable  distance  intervenes  between  each  pair  of 
cities.  Once  again  to  avoid  a  confusing  diagram,  we  ignore  satellite 
type  centers  which  may  exist  between  any  pair  and  which  the  reader 
should  bear  in  mind. 

About  each  city  we  have  drawn  Thiinen  rings.  These  rings  are  not 
concentric  circles.  Rather  they  are  distorted  bands.  In  part  they 
reflect  the  impact  of  lower  transport  rates  along  major  transport 
routes,  which  routes  comprise  the  net  suggested  by  Losch  and  indicated 
in  Fig.  51.2  0  This  net  embodies  those  urbanization  economies  which 
stem  from  scale  economies  in  transportation. 

Many  other  forces  distort  the  symmetry  of  the  Thiinen  pattern  about 
each  city  and  of  the  boundary  lines  which  separate  the  agricultural 
hinterlands  tributary  to  each  city.^i  To  the  right  in  Fig.  53  we  have 
indicated  an  area  of  marshland  which  precludes  any  agricultural  activ- 
ity. To  the  left  we  have  indicated  an  area  containing  soil  particularly 
suited,  and  therefore  devoted,  to  the  production  of  a  crop  which  ordi- 
narily would  not  be  cultivated  so  close  to  a  city. 

Because  we  have  depicted  the  impact  of  only  a  few  disturbing  forces, 
Fig.  53  greatly  exaggerates  the  symmetry  of  agricultural  land-use  pat- 

20  Again,  we  revolve  the  net  so  that  the  transport  routes  course  through  the 
middle  of  city-rich  and  city-poor  sectors. 

21  The  boundary  lines  are  yielded  by  supply  area  analysis  wherein  any  one  com- 
modity (or  combination)  of  many  possible  ones  may  be  yielded  by  a  given  unit 
of  land.    Note  that  one  city's  agricultural  hinterland  is  entirely  enclosed. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       277 


a\' 


II  1  1  1  1 
II  1  1  II 
II  1  1  II 
1  1  1  1  1  1 

u-^^ 

^ 

1  1  1  '  ii^ 

1                r 

*%!& 

Mi 
1  1  1  1  II 
1  1  1  1  II 

i|ii:ii|!|ii 
;ii!i|ii!{ii 

1 1 1 1  1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1  [  T  ;■■; 

I  1  1  1  1  1  1  1  1  iji 

II  1  1  1  1  1  1  II 
II  1  1  1  1  1  1  1  1 

1 

/C 

// 

%-     '  i' ' ' ' ' ' 

i; 
r 

/^ 

\ 

^:0'         \ 
\ 

/ 
-       / 

\ 

\ 
\ 

/ 
\/ 

\ 

Fig.  53.     An  agricultural  land-use  pattern. 


terns.  2  2  The  pattern  of  reality  is  much  more  complex.  Yet  whether 
we  consider  the  complex  pattern  of  reality  or  the  oversimplified  pat- 
tern of  Fig.  53,  the  relevant  substitution  framework  reflecting  the 
interplay  of  competitive  forces  is  the  same. 

It  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  grid  of  agricultural  bands  of 
Fig.  53  does  not  conflict  with  the  modified  Loschian  market  areas  of 

--  For  this  reason,  we  have  not  attempted  to  construct  Fig.  53  to  be  rigorouslj' 
consistent  with  our  theoretical  framework.  This  figure  was  designed  to  be  visually 
suggestive. 


278  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

Fig.  52.  Within  a  city  the  market  areas  cover  urban  residents.  As 
distance  from  the  city  increases,  the  market  areas  cover  increasingly 
farming  populations.  The  isolated  dots  at  considerable  distances  from 
the  city  indicate  small  centers  of  retail  and  service  activities  oriented 
to  farming  population.  To  portray  this  consonance  in  the  use  of  land 
we  have  superimposed  upon  the  market  areas  at  the  lower  right  of 
Fig.  52  a  set  of  bands  indicating  an  hypothetical  agricultural  land-use 
pattern. 

We  are  now  in  a  position  to  probe  somewhat  more  deeply  into  the 
impact  of  urbanization  economies  and  to  examine  the  pattern  of  urban 
land  use  which  results  from  superimposing  upon  a  concentration  of 
heavy,  localized  raw  material  using  industries  (such  as  depicted  at 
the  lower  left  of  Fig.  50)  a  modified  Loschian  system  of  nets  of  market 
areas  (such  as  depicted  in  Fig.  52) .  For  the  more  customary  situation, 
the  logic  of  this  procedure  has  been  stated. 

As  one  of  many  suggestive  patterns  of  urban  land  use,  we  present 
Fig.  54  from  which  boundary  lines  separating  market  areas  of  producers 
are  omitted.  Figure  54  is  constructed  on  a  larger  scale  than  is  Fig.  52. 
The  central  city  is  outlined  in  greater  detail.  Apart  from  the  apparent 
effect  upon  size  resulting  from  the  use  of  a  larger  scale,  the  dimensions 
of  the  central  city  (when  compared  with  those  of  Fig.  52)  are  signifi- 
cantly greater  because  of  the  city's  expanded  industrial  base.  The 
city's  total  economy  now  comprises  those  activities  using  localized  raw 
materials  as  well  as  those  using  ubiquitous  raw  materials  or  none 
at  all.  Because  of  the  addition  of  operations  utilizing  localized  raw 
materials,  the  population  and  the  income  stream  of  the  city  have 
mounted,  and  in  turn  these  have  stimulated  the  expansion  within  the 
city  of  those  activities  using  ubiquitous  raw  materials  or  none  at  all. 
These  latter  are  for  the  most  part  commercial  and  service  type  activi- 
ties. The  locations  of  firms  engaging  in  commercial  and  service  type 
activities  are  represented  by  small  dots. ^  3  The  density  of  these  firms 
is  so  great  at  and  around  the  core  of  the  city  that  the  core  and  its 
immediate  environs  appear  as  almost  a  solid  black  mass. 

Figure  54  portrays  four  industrial  districts  (light  grey  shading) 
greatly  differing  in  size.  Apart  from  those  firms  which  manufacture 
miscellaneous  items  or  use  ubiquitous  raw  materials  and  which  are 
indicated  by  a  double  dagger  sign  (|),  we  have  concentrated  in  one  of 

23  The  specific  spatial  pattern  as  well  as  the  magnitude  of  these  activities  is 
clearly  a  function  of,  among  other  variables,  the  amount  of  manufacture  which  is 
based  on  localized  raw  materials. 

It  should  also  be  noted  that  in  Fig.  54  dots  are  no  longer  used  to  represent  in 
addition  the  industrial  firms  utilizing  ubiquitous  raw  materials,  as  was  the  case 
in  Fig.  52. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       279 


Fig.  54.    An  urban  land-use  pattern. 


the  several  industrial  districts  all  producers  of  any  given  commodity. 
By  so  doing,  we  retain  a  pattern  consistent  with  the  localization  econo- 
mies hypothesized  in  connection  with  Figs.  49  and  50.  Thus  the  four 
firms  in  the  lower  left  agglomeration  of  Fig.  50,  which  produce  the  first 
commodity  associated  with  Fig.  50  and  which  are  represented  by  a 
black  circle  (•),  are  placed  together  in  the  industrial  district  at  the 
lower  center  of  Fig.  54.  The  five  firms  producing  the  fourth  commodity 
represented  by  cross  signs  (+)  are  located  in  the  same  industrial  dis- 
trict. The  four  firms  producing  the  third  commodity  represented  by 
black  squares    (■)    and  the  three  producing  the  second  commodity 


280  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

represented  by  white  circles  (O)  are  put  together  in  a  second  indus- 
trial district.  Lastly,  the  three  producing  the  fifth  commodity  and  rep- 
resented by  white  triangles  (^)  are  concentrated  in  a  third  industrial 
district.  Together  with  the  firms  which  manufacture  miscellaneous 
items  or  use  ubiquitous  raw  materials  and  which  are  present  in  all  four 
industrial  districts,  these  firms  compose  the  industrial  sector  of  the  city. 

In  addition  to  designating  areas  of  industrial  activity  and  of  com- 
mercial and  service  activity,  Fig.  54  identifies  a  third  set  of  areas 
allocated  to  residential  use  (shown  by  crosshatched  shading,  where 
varying  density  of  shading  indicates  varying  intensity  of  use),  and 
a  fourth  set  of  areas  devoted  to  parks  and  recreational  activities 
(shrub-like  shading). 2* 

The  land-use  design  of  Fig.  54  represents  one  of  many  possible  brews 
of  (1)  intuition,  (2)  logic  and  analytic  principles  relating  to  the  inter- 
action of  general  forces  governing  land  use,  and  (3)  facts.  It  is  not 
a  rigorous  theoretical  derivation.  The  development  of  a  body  of  ab- 
stract thought  on  urban  land  use  has  not  proceeded  sufficiently  far  to 
allow  a  firmer  statement  on  optimum  urban  land-use  patterns.  One 
important  avenue  along  which  such  development  might  proceed  would 
involve  a  comprehensive  investigation  of  the  interconnections  of  urban 
land-use  theory  and  agricultural  location  theory.  As  indicated  in  the 
Appendix  of  Chap.  8,  there  are  basic  similarities  between  these  two. 
As  in  agricultural  location  theory,  urban  land-use  analysis  must  place 
central  emphasis  upon  rent  outlays  (land  values) .  Further,  along  the 
methodological  lines  of  agricultural  location  theory,  rent  functions  can 
be  derived  and  used  as  allocators  of  urban  land.  To  both  the  urban 
land  user  and  the  farmer,  transport  relations  are  critical.  To  the  former 
these  relations  are  in  terms  of  effective  distance  from  the  core  and 
accessibility  to  potential  customers,  although  the  user  of  any  particular 
urban  site  does  not  customarily  incur  the  major  part  of  the  transport 
outlays  (both  real  and  implicit)  connected  with  the  sale  of  product  or 
service.  As  in  the  rural  setting,  we  observe  that  in  an  urban  economy 
complementary  and  competitive  relations  in  terms  of  configuration  of 
uses  spatially  juxtaposed  critically  affect  unit  production  costs  and 
accessibility.  Moreover,  technology,  physical  and  cultural  environ- 
ment, legal  institutions,  and  other  factors  serve  to  impose  restraints 
as  well  as  distortions  upon  otherwise  rational  land-use  patterns. 

2-1  In  Fig.  54  we  do  not  purport  to  indicate  all  types  of  land  use.  Only  four  major 
categories  are  presented.  As  a  consequence,  we  must  define  these  categories  very 
broadly  so  that  they  embrace  other  types  of  uses.  For  example,  we  include  within 
the  land  area  assigned  to  commercial  and  service  activities  that  land  required  for 
governmental  and  institutional  functions  of  a  similar  character;  and  within  the 
land  for  residential  purposes  that  land  set  aside  for  elementary  school  functions. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       281 

Despite  these  basic  similarities,  there  are  important  forces  influenc- 
ing the  array  of  urban  land  uses  which  do  not  have  a  correspondingly 
strong  counterpart  in  the  rural  setting.  As  examples,  we  refer  to  those 
shaping  journey -to-work  phenomena,  the  pattern  of  shopping  trips 
and  social  contact,  advertising  outlays,  and  quality  competition.  None- 
theless, we  find  a  general  substitution  framework  of  relevance  in  ap- 
proaching urban  land-use  problems,  let  alone  in  attacking  the  entire 
range  of  land-use  problems  wherein  the  competition  between  agricul- 
tural uses  and  industrial,  commercial,  and  residential  uses  is  encom- 
passed as  well. 

To  complete  the  graphic  presentation  of  this  chapter  we  should 
depict  the  flows  of  commodities  and  people  connected  with  the  various 
locations,  land  uses,  and  cities  which  have  been  examined.  For  the 
most  part  our  graphic  conceptions  have  referred  to  static  structural 
situations.  They  have  not  underscored  the  kinetic  characteristics:  the 
constant  stream  of  raw  material  and  commodity  shipments,  inter- 
regional and  intraregional ;  the  journey -to-work  patterns;  trips  to 
shopping  centers  and  points  of  social  contact;  intercity  movement  of 
people;  various  interconnections  via  communications  media;  etc.  To 
illustrate  all  these  diverse  flow  phenomena  is  beyond  the  scope  of  this 
summary  chapter.  We  shall  have  reference  to  only  one  type,  namely, 
that  associated  with  the  movement  of  selected  raw  materials  and 
finished  product.  We  leave  to  the  reader  the  task  of  superimposing 
upon  the  patterns  already  depicted  the  kaleidoscopic  variety  of  realistic 
flows.  2  5 

,  In  Chap.  9,  we  partially  analyze  the  interrelations  of  trade  (com- 
modity flows)  and  industrial  location.  Our  particular  concern  is  with 
the  possibility  of  improving  by  reformulation  both  international  trade 
doctrine  and  location  theory,  and  thereby  to  obtain  a  superior  set  of 
analytical  tools. 

With  examples  of  simple  sets  of  conditions,  we  demonstrate  how 
the  distance  variable,  and  thus  industries  locationally  sensitive  to 
transport  cost  differentials,  can  be  incorporated  into  trade  doctrine. 
This  step  involves  the  explicit  consideration  of  transport  inputs  and 
consequently  meets  certain  harsh  criticisms  levelled  at  traditional  trade 
theory.     Concomitantly,  we  achieve  an  extension  of  location  theory, 

25  For  illustrative  materials  on  flows,  the  reader  is  referred  to:  E.  L.  Ullman, 
"Die  wirtschaftliche  Verflechtung  verschiedener  Regionen.  der  USA  betrachtet  am 
Giiteraustausch  Connecticuts,  lowas  und  Washington^  mit  den  anderen  Staaten," 
Die  Erde,  1955,  Heft  2;  "Interregional  Highways,"  House  Document  379,  78th 
Congress,  2nd  Session,  Washington,  1944;  and  Gerald  W.  Breese,  The  Daytime 
Population  oj  the  Central  Business  District  of  Chicago,  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  Chicago,  1949. 


282 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


namely,  the  restatement  of  transport  orientation  doctrine  in  terms  of 
opportunity  cost.  We  find,  for  example,  that  traditional  Weberian 
doctrine  might  suggest  in  an  international  trade  setting  complete 
transport-orientation  when  an  optimum  solution  would  involve  only 
partial  transport-orientation.    These  reformulations  of  both  long-run 


Region 
A 


Fig.  55.    A  commodity  flow  pattern:   intranational  trade. 


opportunity  cost  doctrine  and  transport-orientation  dogma  are  in 
essence  one  and  the  same.  They  lead  to  a  partial  fusion  of  trade  and 
location  theories  and  pave  the  way  for  a  more  comprehensive  inte- 
gration. 

Our  examples  clearly  demonstrate  how  a  change  in  the  distance 
variable  can  completely  revamp  the  geographic  flow  of  commodities 
and  the  composition  of  trade  and  influence  in  a  major  way  the  indus- 
trial structure  of  nations  and  international  location  patterns.  When 
graphically  presented,  these  examples  also  point  up  basic  interrelations 
with  urban  economic  structure  and  land-use  patterns. 

To  begin,  we  assume  within  a  nation  three  regions  A,  B,  and  C  with 
their  central  cities  as  terminating  and  originating  points  of  commodity 
flows.  We  take  the  central  city  and  surrounding  area  of  Fig.  54  to 
be  our  region  B.  Of  region  B  we  reproduce  in  Fig.  55  and  subsequent 
figures  only  its  lower  central  industrial  district.     Except  for  relative 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       283 

position  regions  A  and  C  are  not  indicated  in  Fig.  55.  As  with  nations 
A,  B,  and  C  of  Table  II  of  Chap.  9,  regions  A  and  C  together  with 
region  B  are  geographically  situated  as  the  corners  of  an  equilateral 
triangle.  We  also  postulate  initially  the  same  resource  endowments, 
demand  conditions,  and  production  functions  as  are  assumed  for  nations 
A,  5,  and  C  in  Chap.  9. 

Since  it  is  clear  from  Table  I  of  Chap.  9  that  region  C  has  an  abso- 
lute disadvantage  in  the  production  of  each  commodity  and  since 
among  regions  within  a  nation  long-run  mobility  of  productive  factors, 
especially  labor  and  capital,  may  be  posited,  long-run  equilibrium 
may  be  assumed  to  entail  the  shift  of  productive  factors  from  C  to  A.^^ 
Trade  between  A  and  C  would  be  non-existent.  Trade  between  A  and 
B  would  be  approximately  as  depicted  in  Fig.  55  with  B  producing  all 
steel  and  coal,  and  A  all  ore,  textiles,  and  shipping.  The  producers  of 
steel  may  be  taken  to  be  represented  by  the  black  circular  marks  {*)  .^'^ 
B's  imports  from  and  exports  to  A  are  indicated  by  arrows  whose 
widths  approximately  represent  values. 

We  now  introduce  national  boundaries,  in  essence  change  the  para- 
metric value  of  the  political  variable.  We  assume  regions  A,  B,  and  C 
are  three  nations  as  in  Chap.  9.  Since  long-run  immobility  of  factors 
is  characteristic  of  the  international  setting,  we  can  no  longer  postulate 
that  factors  will  shift  from  A  to  C.  Rather,  the  productive  units  remain 
at  C,  and  C  engages  in  those  activities  in  which  she  has  least  compara- 
tive disadvantage.  The  tables  and  discussion  of  Chap.  9  spell  out  the 
long-run  equilibrium  position. 

Figure  56  depicts  this  second  situation  as  it  bears  upon  region  B. 
The  change  from  an  intranational  to  an  international  setting  alters 
the  magnitudes  of  the  flows  between  B  and  A  and  introduces  new 
flows  between  B  and  C.  Also,  we  observe  that  the  industrial  structure 
of  B  changes  somewhat.  B  engages  in  a  new  activity,  namely,  textiles. 
The  firm  producing  textiles  is  indicated  by  a  star  sign  (*) . 

In  Chap.  9  a  change  in  another  basic  variable,  namely,  the  distance 

2*3  This  assumption  oversimplifies  any  real  situation.  C  may  possess  other 
resources  and  be  in  an  advantageous  position  to  produce  other  commodities  not 
considered  in  this  simple  example.  Furthermore,  short-run  immobihty  may  lead 
to  the  estabUshment  of  industry  at  C  which,  once  established,  becomes  economic 
to  operate  at  C  because  of  relocation  costs  and  other  socio-economic  factors. 
Nonetheless,  the  validity  of  the  general  points  we  wish  to  make  with  this  and 
the  two  succeeding  figures  is  not  impaired. 

27  To  be  consistent,  we  assume  that:  (1)  the  four  firms  in  region  B  indicated  by 
the  cross  sign  (  +  )  obtain  raw  materials  from  areas  not  indicated  and  produce 
products  wholly  consumed  within  the  region;  and  (2)  the  three  firms  indicated 
by  the  double  dagger  sign  (t)  use  ubiquitous  raw  materials  and  produce  for  the 
local  market  only. 


284 


LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 


variable  is  considered.  The  relative  position  of  the  three  nations 
(regions)  A,  B,  and  C  is  altered.  They  are  assumed  to  be  situated 
along  a  straight  line  with  C  in  the  middle.  Trade  flows  are  completely 
revamped  as  indicated  in  Table  IV  of  Chap.  9.  In  Fig.  57  we  portray 
these  new  flows  as  they  relate  to  region  B.  It  should  be  noted  that  the 
industrial  structure  of  B  undergoes  major  change.     Steel  production 


Nation 
A 


Fig.  56.    A  commodity  flow  pattern:  international  trade. 


falls  to  approximately  one-third  its  former  level.  Textile  output 
roughly  triples  in  size.  These  changes  are  roughly  indicated  by  the 
numbers  of  firms  producing  steel  (•)  and  textiles  (*)  in  the  indus- 
trial district.  If  we  were  to  probe  more  deeply,  we  should  unearth 
other  changes.  For  example,  steel  and  textiles  have  different  input 
requirements.  This  fact  implies  change  in  the  structure  of  subsidiary 
industries  in  region  B  which  feed  their  outputs  into  steel  and  textiles. 
Further,  steel  and  textiles  generate  different  levels  of  income  and,  in 
general,  have  different  internal  multiplier  effects,  whether  we  consider 
industry,  employment,  or  population.    As  a  consequence,  the  total  pat- 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       285 

tern  of  land  use,  as  well  as  the  pattern  of  each  type  of  land  use — com- 
mercial, industrial,  residential,  etc. — is  altered.  This  is  so  not  only 
because  steel  and  textiles  have  different  land  requirements  and  different 
competitive  potentials  in  bidding  for  land  but,  more  important,  because 
the  structures  of  industry  erected  upon  steel  and  textiles  are  signifi- 
cantly different  and  require  different  quantities  and  qualities  of  land 
inputs.  Thus  we  see  the  basic  interconnections  among  urban  land-use 
patterns  (and  hence  agricultural  land-use  patterns),  commodity  flows, 
and  interregional  (international)  position. 


Nation 


Fig.  57.    A   commodity  flow  pattern  with   modified  geographic  position   of 
trading  nations. 


With  Fig.  57  we  bring  to  a  close  the  graphic  presentation  of  this 
chapter.  This  presentation,  in  particular  Figs.  52-57,  reflects  the  im- 
pact upon  land-use  patterns  and  commodity  flows  of  the  interaction 
of  the  various  location  forces.  To  the  extent  that  a  limited  number 
of  diagrams  permits,  there  are  embodied  in  these  figures  the  several 
kinds  of  related  forces:  (1)  those  tending  to  transport-orientation  and 
to  labor  and  similar  forms  of  orientation;  (2)  those  stemming  from 
technological  change  and  from  economies  of  scale,  localization  econo- 
mies, and  urbanization  economies;  (3)  those  leading  to  the  formation 
of  the  standard  types  as  well  as  the  Losch  type  of  market  and  supply 
areas,  of  modified  Thiinen  patterns  of  agricultural  land  use,  and  of  the 
intricate  patterns  of  urban  land  use;  and  (4)  those,  such  as  are  gen- 
erated by  political  boundary  lines,  which  emerge  from  the  broad  social 
and  institutional  setting.  Together  with  other  similar  diagrams  which 
may  be  constructed,  these  figures  can  embrace  different  kinds  of  general 
situations — situations  which  may   involve  many  regions  and   cities, 


286  LOCATION  AND  SPACE-ECONOMY 

where  each  pair  is  interconnected  by  diverse  commodity  and  communi- 
cation flows  and  where  the  population  of  each  consumes  many  com- 
modities, in  the  production  of  each  of  which  many  firms  may  be  en- 
gaged, where  each  firm  may  utilize  many  raw  materials  of  which  each 
may  be  available  from  many  sources. 

As  already  intimated,  the  above  diagrams  may  be  taken  to  represent 
one  path  of  integration,  namely,  visual  integration.  In  Chap.  10  we 
attempt  a  second  contrasting  path  of  integration,  one  that  follows 
mathematical  lines.  There  we  develop  a  pervasive  and  basic  location 
principle.  The  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between  any  two  transport 
inputs  or  groups  of  transport  inputs,  however  the  transport  inputs  or 
groups  of  transport  inputs  may  be  defined,  must  equal  the  reciprocal 
of  the  ratio  of  their  transport  rates,  social  surplus  (however  defined) 
less  costs  on  all  other  transport  inputs  being  held  constant.  This  prin- 
ciple when  supported  by  appropriate  postulates  implies  various  location 
theories:  the  transport-orientation  dogma  of  Weber,  Fetter-Launhardt 
market  and  supply  area  analysis,  Loschian  market  area  schemata,  and 
Thiinen  agricultural  location  theory.  Thus,  this  principle  demonstrates 
a  basic  unity  in  much  of  location  theory  and  permits  considerable  syn- 
thesis of  location  doctrines.  Further,  with  this  principle  we  are  able 
to  extend  and  generalize  much  of  this  theory  to  encompass  a  much 
broader  range  and  a  more  realistic  set  of  situations.  Additionally,  this 
principle  and  the  mathematical  formulations  of  Chap.  10  coupled  with 
the  notion  of  a  spatial  transformation  function  facilitate  the  fusing  of 
location  theory  and  production  theory. 

The  above  set  of  summary  graphs  and  discussion  bring  to  a  close  the 
analysis  of  this  book.  Needless  to  say,  there  is  a  tremendous  amount  of 
ground  yet  to  be  ploughed.  The  ways  in  which  production  theory  and 
location  theory  may  be  interwoven  and  fused  must  be  spelled  out  in 
considerable  detail.  The  logical  relations  between  trade  theory  and 
location  theory  need  to  be  more  thoroughly  explored  and  a  more  explicit 
synthesis  achieved.  The  transport  system  and  rate  structure  must  be 
considered  as  variables  rather  than  as  fixed  data ;  to  do  so  would  facili- 
tate the  merging  of  the  transport  problem  as  conceived  by  Koopmans 
and  the  location  problem  as  developed  in  this  book.  The  concept  of 
rational  behavior  must  be  sharpened  via  game  theory  and  other  con- 
ceptual apparatuses;  once  this  concept  is  defined  in  concrete  and  pre- 
cise (desirably  quantitative)  terms,  its  application  to  the  decision 
making  process  of  the  firm  will  permit  a  more  valid  statement  on  the 
nature  and  conditions  of  locational  equilibrium  and  a  deeper  under- 
standing of  the  phenomenon  of  agglomeration,  particularly  where 
pricing  policy  is  a  variable  and  where  firms  possess  considerable 
geographic  mobility. 


PARTIAL  GRAPHIC  SYNTHESIS  AND  SUMMARY       287 

We  need  to  develop  new  and  superior  concepts  relating  to  the  spatial 
structure  of  society.  Spatial  interaction  phenomena,  as  manifested  for 
example  in  the  various  empirical  materials  on  commodity  and  com- 
munication flows  and  population  movement,  must  be  dissected  with 
tools  honed  to  a  much  finer  sharpness.  We  especially  need  to  probe 
deeply  into  space  preferences,  i.e.,  into  man's  propensity  for  intricate 
forms  and  patterns  of  herd  existence  and  into  the  socio-psychological 
and  biological  forces  which  together  with  economic  and  other  forces 
govern  the  spatial  patterns  of  population  settlement.  These  forces 
have  a  strong  bearing  upon  urban  land-use  patterns  and  the  mutual 
interdependence  of  the  industrial,  commercial,  and  residential  sectors. 

We  must  gain  further  insight  into  urbanization  economies,  into  the 
complex  interrelations  of  the  sets  of  net  economy  curves,  and  into  the 
structure  and  functioning  of  metropolitan  regions  as  socio-economic 
organisms.  How  the  structure  and  functioning  of  any  given  region  are 
shaped  and  limited  and  how  the  location  decisions  of  its  firms  are 
restrained  by  the  region's  total  resources,  income,  gross  product,  and 
labor  productivity,  and  by  the  tastes,  standards,  and  expenditure  pat- 
terns of  its  populace  require  thorough  investigation.  This  type  of 
inquiry  is  very  much  in  the  direction  of  regional  science. 

We  need  to  pry  into  the  space-economy  with  welfare  considerations 
in  mind,  to  relate  spatial  structures  to  social  well-being  and  to  intro- 
duce political  variables  and  policy  decisions  as  they  reflect  attempts 
to  give  a  concrete  basis  to  values  and  ideals;  and  we  must  study  how 
they  in  turn  influence  location  decisions  and  spatial  patterns. 

Finally,  we  need  to  develop,  as  will  be  attempted  in  a  future  volume, 
operational  models  to  quantify  various  interrelations  and  to  provide 
cutting  tools  more  relevant  to  policy  decisions.  Whether  we  attempt 
improvement  of  regional  and  interregional  input-output  models,  or 
linear  programming  techniques,  or  industrial  complex  analysis,  or  pro- 
jections of  gross  regional  product  and  its  constituents,  or  gravity 
models,  or  other  structural  schemata  involving  ordered  arrangements 
of  groups  and  sub-groups  and  of  aggregated  and  disaggregated  sectors, 
or  whether  we  aim  at  synthesis  of  the  stronger  elements  of  these  models 
and  analytical  techniques,  we  must  be  able  to  present  and  handle  more 
effectively  the  space-economy  as  a  hierarchy  of  focal  points  and  trans- 
port and  communication  routes.  Substitution  in  the  large  must  be 
assigned  a  much  more  significant  role.  Once  again  such  developments 
would  take  us  along  the  channels  of  regional  science.  It  is  our  hope 
that  these  channels  will  be  diligently  explored. 


Author  Index 


Abbott,  Lawrence,  204n 

Ackley,  Gardner,  165,  165n 

Aeroboe,  Friedrich,  190n,  243,  243n 

Alderson,  Wroe,  65n,  67 

Allee,  Warder  C,  84n 

Allen,  G.  R.,  57n 

Allen,  Roy  G.  D,  118,  llSn 

Amoroso,  Luigi,  161n 

Anderson,  Theodore  R.,  65n 

Auerbach,  F.,  55,  55n 

Beckerman,  W.,  209n 

Beckmann,  Martin,  24n,  167n,  168n,  222n 

Benedict,  Elizabeth  T.,  190n,  243n 

Benedict,  Murray  R.,  243n 

Bergson,  Abram,  236n 

Bernard,  Luther  L.,  84n 

Bogue,  Donald  J.,  68,  68n,  70,  70n,  145n, 

251n 
Bohm-Bawerk,  Eugen,  83n,  85n 
Bortkiewicz,  Ladislaus,  31,  109,  109n 
Boulding,  Kenneth  E.,  81n,  204n,  221n 
Breese,  Gerald  W.,  281n 
Bright,  Margaret  L.,  65n 
Brinkmann,  Theodor,  190n,  194n,  199n, 

243,  243n,  244,  244n 

Capron,  William  M.,  37n 
Carrothers,  Gerald  A.  P.,  274n 
Carver,  Thomas  N.,  28n 
Cassel,  Gustav,  32,  33,  42 


Chamberlin,  Edward  H.,  25,  25n,  27n, 
38n,  46,  49n,  50,  50n,  92n,  144,  144n, 
162,  162n, 204n 

Chipman,  John  S.,  214n 

Christaller,  Walter,  58n,  60,  60n,  239n 

Clark,  Colin.  21,  70n 

Clark,  John  B,  82n 

Colson,  M.,  109n 

Cournot,  Augustin,  161n 

Cox,  Reavis,  65n,  67 

Cumberland,  John  H.,  119n 

Dantzig,  George  B.,  222n 

Dean,  William  H.,  Jr.,  15,  30n,  31n,  87n, 

93n,  107n, 120,  121,  125,  128n,  132,  225n 
Dickinson,  Robert  E.,  273n 
Dodd,  Stuart  C,  65n 
Dorfman,  Robert,  204n 
Dunn,    Edgar   S.,    190,    190n,    192,    193, 

193n,  194n,  195n,  198n,  199n,  243,  243n, 

244,  244n,  247,  247n 

Edgeworth,  Francis  Y.,  161n,  228 

Ellis,  Howard  S.,  236n 

Englander,  Oskar,  15,  24n,  29,  29n,  30n, 
31,  32,  32n,  34,  41n,  50,  85n,  93n,  94, 
143n,  160,  180,  208,  208n,  231n 

Enke,  Stephen,  24n,  25n,  167n,  168n 

Fetter,  Frank  A.,  25n,  144n,  153,  160, 
231n,  239,  286 


289 


290 


AUTHOR  INDEX 


Fisher,  Irving,  83n,  85n,  88n,  89n 
Fox,  Karl  A.,  24n,  167n,  169n 
Freutel,  Guy,  209n,  251n 
Friedrich,  Carl  J,  27n,  128n,  172n,  178n, 

222n 
Furlan,  L.  Vladimir,  3 In,  50,  208,  208n 

Gibrat,  R.,  55,  55n 

Graham,  Frank  D.,  209,  209n,  210,  212n, 

213,  214n,  215n 
Greenhut,  Melvin  L.,  144n,  170n,  171n 

Haberler,  Gottfried,  53,  86n,  215n,  220n 

Harrod,  Roy  F,  215n 

Hawley,  Amos  H.,  68,  68n,  145n,  251n, 

273n 
Hawtrey,  Ralph  G.,  30n 
Hayek,  Friederich  A.,  82,  82n,  83n,  85n 
Hicks,  John  R,  25,  25n,  26,  26n,  27,  95n, 

102,  118,  118n,  192 
Hitchcock,  Frank  L.,  168n 
Hoover,  Edgar  M.,  Jr.,  24n,  30n,  58n, 

84n,  86n,   87n,  94n,   105n,   108,   108n, 

122,  123.  124n,  125,  127n,  128n,  130n, 

139n,  143n,  144n,  148,  148n,  150,  153n. 

154n,  155n,  164n,  172,  173n,  174n. 

175n,  190n,  194n,  195n,  205n,  210n, 

231n,  235,  235n 
Hotelling,  Harold,  160,  161,  161n,  162, 

163n,  164,  164n,  169,  170,  181 
Hoyt,  Homer,  88n 
Hurwicz,  Leonid,  165n 
Hyson,  C.  D.,  144n,  147n,  157n,  231n, 

239 
Hyson,  W.  P.,  144n,  147n,  157n,  231n, 

239 

Isard,    Walter,   58n,    119n,   207n,    209n, 

211n,  220n,  251n 
Isabel!,  Eleanor  C.,  65n 

Jurgen,  H.,  37n,  208n 

Kaldor,  Nicholas,  82n 

Kaysen,  Carl,  165n 

Knight,  Frank  H.,  81,  81n,  82n,  83n,  86, 

89,  89n 
Koopmans,  Tjalling,  22,  24n,  77n,  168n, 

213n,  222n,  286 

Lange,  Oscar,  25,  25n,  82n 

Launhardt,  Wilhelm,  24n,  28,  43,  122, 
125,  143n,  144n,  153,  160,  161,  210n, 
231n,  239,  256,  258,  259,  261,  267,  274, 
286 

Leontief,  Wassily  W.,  21,  49,  49n,  58n 


Lerner,  Abba  P.,  163,  163n,  164n 

Losch,  August,  15-19,  19n,  42-44,  44n, 
45,  48,  48n,  49,  49n,  50,  53n,  54,  58, 
58n,  59,  60,  60n,  75n,  78n,  86n,  125, 
143,  143n,  150,  150n,  151-153,  153n, 
154,  157-159,  159n,  162n,  174,  174n, 
190n,  195n,  199n,  208,  231n,  236,  239, 
239n,  240-242,  242n,  243n,  244,  247, 
247n,  252,  267,  270,  271,  271n,  272, 
273,  273n,  274,  274n,  276-278,  285, 
286 

Lotka,  Alfred  J.,  55,  55n 

Luce,  R.  Duncan,  165n 

Machlup,  Fritz,  83n 
Marschak,  Jacob,  165n,  167n 
Marshall,  Alfred,  24,  24n,  25,  85n,  90, 

254 
Mayberry,  J.  P.,  165n 
McDougall,  Wilham,  84n 
McKenzie,  Roderick  D.,  68,  68n,  145n 
Metzler,  Lloyd  A.,  212n 
Moller,  H.,  164n,  165n 
Morgenstern,    Oskar,    165,     165n,    166, 

166n,  167 
Mosak,  Jacob  L.,  25,  25n,  26,  26n 

Nash,  John  F.,  165n 

Neumann,    John    von,    165,    165n,    166, 

166n,  167 
Niederhauser,  Elisabeth,  37n,  92n,  109n 
Nimkoff,  Meyer  F.,  84n 
Nurkse,  Ragnar,  82n 

Ogburn,  Wilham  F.,  84n 

Ohlin,  Bertil  G.,  17,  28n,  50,  51,  52,  52n, 

53,  53n,  108n,  127n,  128n,  172,  208, 

208n,  215n,  217 

Palander,  Tord,  24n,  42,  43,  43n,  48,  50, 
52n,  86n,  94n,  95n,  108,  108n,  112n, 
122,  123,  124n,  125,  130n,  143n.  144n, 
161,  162,  163,  163n,  164n,  179n,  180, 
210n,  231n,  235,  235n,  239,  256,  256n, 
258,  258n,  259,  259n,  261,  262,  263, 
263n,  264n,  267,  274 

Pareto,  Vilfredo,  25,  32,  42,  55n,  56 

Peck,  Merton  J.,  71n,  207n 

Pick,  Georg,  121,  123 

Predohl,  Andreas,  31,  32,  32n,  33,  33n, 
34,  35,  35n,  36  36n,  41n,  42n,  50,  54, 
94,  95n,  131,  208,  208n,  254 

Proudfoot,  Malcolm  J.,  273n 

Raiffa,  Howard,  165n 
Ravenstein,  Ernest  G.,  64,  64n 


AUTHOR  INDEX 


291 


Reilly,  William  J,  65n 

Reiter,  Stanley,  16Sn,  213n,  222n 

Ricardo,  David,  28n,  51n,  89n 

Robinson,  Austin,  163n 

Ritschl,  Hans,  15,  30n,  31,  49n,  50,  87n 

Roscher,  Wilhelm,  15,  28,  28n 

Samuelson,  Paul  A.,  24n,  25,  25n,  43n, 
103n,  118,  118n,  167n,  168n,  228n,  230n 

Schaffle,  Albert  E.  F.,  15,  28,  28n 

Schmoller,  Gustav,  44n,  87n 

Schneider,  Erich,  160n,  164n,  231n 

Schumpeter,  Joseph  A.,  26n,  31 

Seedorf,  Wilhelm,  37n,  208n 

Shubik,  Martin,  165n 

Singer,  H.  W.,  55,  55n,  163,  163n,  164n 

Smithies,  Arthur,  82n,  164,  164n,  165n 

Stackelberg,  Heinrich,  165n 

Steiner,  Peter  0,  204n 

Stewart,  John  Q.,  65,  65n,  66,  66n,  68, 
68n,  77,  78 

Stippler,  H.,  243n 

Stopler,  Wolfgang  F.,  43n,  49n,  228n 

Stouffer,  Samuel  A,  63,  63n,  64n,  65n 

Thomas,  Dorothy  S.,  65n 

Thiinen.  Johann  Heinrich,  3.  15,  16,  17, 
18,  19,  19n,  24n,  27,  28,  28n,  29,  33, 
33n,  34,  37n,  41n,  51n,  52,  92,  93,  158, 
188,  190n,  198,  199,  208n,  210n,  243, 
243n,  244n,  249,  249n,  250,  252,  276, 
285,  286 

Triffin,  Robert  A..  50,  50n 


Trotter,  Wilfred,  84n 

Ullman,  Edward  L.,  58n,  60n,  71n,  239n, 

281n 
Usher,  Abbott  P,  15,  30n,  31n 

Viner,  Jacob,  53,  53n,  215n 
Vining,  D.  Rutledge,  22,  57n,  58n,  71n, 
77n 

Walras,  Leon,  25,  32,  33,  42,  43,  48n, 
89,  89n 

Weber,  Alfred,  15,  16,  19,  19n,  23,  27, 
27n,  28,  28n,  29,  30n,  31,  36n,  37n,  40, 
40n,  43,  50,  52,  53,  54,  91,  92,  92n,  93, 
94,  94n,  96,  104n,  108,  108n,  109,  109n, 
118,  120,  121,  123,  125,  127,  128n,  130, 
130n,  131n,  132,  135,  137n,  141,  143n, 
158,  170,  172,  172n,  176,  176n,  177, 
178,  179,  179n,  180,  181,  181n,  182, 
182n,  183,  188,  189,  196,  208,  210n,  217, 
222,  222n,  224,  225n,  228,  252,  252n, 
260,  274,  282,  286 

Weigmann,  Hans,  37,  37n,  38,  39,  40,  41, 
41n,  42,  42n,  49,  50,  54,  208,  208n 

Wicksell,  Knut,  25,  81n 

Williams,  John  H.,  208,  208n 

Young,  Kimball,  84n 

Zeuthen,  Frederik,  161,  161n,  162,  164n 
Zipf,  George  K.,  56,  57,  57n,  60,  61,  61n, 
62,  62n,  63,  63n,  64,  65n,  78n,  79n 


Subject  Index 


Abnormal  profit,  see  Profits,  surplus 
Accessibility,   as   related   to  transport  outlays 
(time-cost)    by  consumers,  205,  280 
effect  of  competitive  land  uses  on,   280 
effect  of  complementary  land  uses  on,  280 
effect  on  price  of  urban  land,  200-205 
effect  on  urban  land  use,  200-205,  280 
Ackley,   cases  of  discontinuous  consumer  dis- 
tribution, 165 
competitive  behavior  as  affected  by  type  of 

market  discontinuity,  165 
determinacy    of    solution    with    market   dis- 
continuity,   165 
lack  of  generalized  solutions  because  of  spa- 
tially discrete  demand,  165 
stability   of   solution   with   market  disconti- 
nuity, 165 
Activity   analysis,    as   an   element   of   regional 
science,  287 
as  appropriate  for  short-run  trade  doctrine, 

209 
need    to   synthesize   with    other    techniques, 

287 
use  of,   in   simple  trade-location   case,   214n 
to    determine    transport    rates    and    com- 
modity flows,  213n 
to  study  structure  of  space-economy,   287 
to  treat  substitution  in  the  large,  287 
Advertising   outlays,   as   affecting   urban   land 
use,  200-201,  281 
differences     in,     and     overlapping     market 

areas,  264 
effect  on  cost  curves,  203-204 
effect  on   rent  function,    203-204 
neglect  of,  in  Launhardt-Palander  construc- 
tion, 265 
Agglomeration,    a    pattern    of,    in    an    urban- 
metropolitan   region,    278-280 
analysis    of,    as    requiring    a    complex    ap- 
proach, 205n 
as  an  historical  process,  180 


Agglomeration — continued 

as  involving   increase  in   transport  outlays, 

179,  267 
as  not  affecting  industrial  distributions  by 

regions,   172 
as  similar  to  complementarity  in  land  use, 

205n 
caused    by    iron    and    steel    development,    8, 

19n 
centers,    advantage    of   existing   production 

points  as,   180 
decrease    in    validity    of    Weber's    assump- 
tions   with   increase   in,    179n 
effect    of    differential    bargaining    abilities 

upon,  180-181,  181n 
exceptions  to  Weber's   conditions   for,   178- 

179,   179n 
forces  of,  as  basic  to  location  analysis,  139- 

140 
from  economies  of  scale,   173-176,  265-267 
from   localization   economies,    176-182,   267- 

268 
from  urbanization  economies,  182-188,  268- 

270 
function  of  economy  of,  in  Weber,  178 
in  competitive  locational  equilibrium  along 

a  line,  162,  163n 
industrial,    differentials    in    land    outlays    as 

major  to,  189 
importance  of  internal  spatial  dimensions 

of,   189 
in   early   stages   of  settlement,   2 
labor  locations  as  centers  of,  179 
need    for    critical    isodapanes    to    intersect, 

176-178 
of   steel  fabricating   activities,   8 
of   urban   activities,   as   determined   by   rent 

functions,  204-205 
point   of,    and    substitution    between    trans- 
port outlays  and  production  outlays, 
174-175,   179,  179n,  188,  265,  267,  269 


293 


294 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Agglomeration — continued 

as  affected  by  replacement  deposits,  178 
as  influenced  by  side  payments,  180-181 
as  over-all  transport  cost  minimum  point, 

177-178 
as  pulled  to  superior  bargainers,  180-181 
use  of  transport-orientation  techniques  to 

identify,   178 
Weber's    determination    of,    177-178 

problem  of,   in  multiplant  firm,   179,   179n 

requisite    total    output   for,    176-178 

significance  of  inherited  physical  structures 
for,   180 

significance  of  relocation  costs  for,  180-181, 
181n 

unit,  size  of  and  distance  from  critical  iso- 
dapane,   178 
size  of  to  which  producer  attracted,  178 

use  of  side  payment  to  induce,   179n 

Weber's  conditions  for,  176-178 

see   also   Localization  ;   Urbanization 
Agglomeration    diseconomies,   see  Deglomera- 

tion  economies 
Agglomeration    economies,    and    decentraliza- 
tion policy,  14 

and  interdependence  of  sets  of  net  economy 
curves,  187-188 

and    meaningful   metropolitan    sectors,    14 

and   need   for   research   on   interdependence 
of   net   economy   curves,    188,   287 

and  need  for  weighting  net  economy  curves, 
186-187 

and  step-by-step  migration,  41n 

and  the  definition  of  industry,  92n 

as  classified  by  Hoover,  172 

as  classified  by  Ohlin,  172 

as    excluded    in    Launhardt-Palander    con- 
struction, 256 

as    including   economies    (diseconomies)    of 
scale,  139,  172,  265 

as    including    localization    economies     (dis- 
economies),   139,    172,    265,    267 

as    including   urbanization    economies    (dis- 
economies),   139,    172,    265,    268 

as   ignored   by   competitive  locational   equi- 
librium   models,    169-170 

as  independent  of  geographic  position,  139- 
140 

as  measured  by  the  critical  isodapane,  176n, 
178 

as  misrepresented  by  a  sum  of  representa- 
tive  net   economy   curves,    186-188 

as  primarily  dependent  on  magnitudes,  139- 
140 

as  they  counteract  Force  of  Diversification, 
79n 

effect   of   physical   environment   on,    140 

effect  on  aggregate  industrial  location  pat- 
terns, 21,  79n 

effect  on  transport  cost  surface,  251 

failure   of   Weber   to   distinguish   by   types, 
176 

from   interindustry   linkage,   21 

neglect  of,   in   Losch  scheme,   153-154 

nonadditive   character   of,    21,    188 

regularity    in    geographic    cost   pattern,    as 
related   to  transport  cost,    139n 

spatial   pattern   of,   as   derived   from   inter- 
action   of    other   forces,    140 

types  of,   139,  170 

see  also  Localization  economies  ;  Urbaniza- 
tion economies 


Agglomeration  theory,  and  need  for  a  sharply 
defined  concept  of  rational  behavior, 
286 

as  included  in  an  extended  trade  doctrine, 
219 

as  yielded  by  the  substitution  principle, 
173-188,  265-269 

coalition  problem  of,  as  complicated  by  re- 
location costs,  181n 

complications,  because  of  different  sizes  of 
agglomeration,   180-181 
because   of   the   coalition   problem,    181n 

difficulties  from  non-symmetric  location 
factors,   181n 

difficulties  of  converting  to  a  constant  sum 
game,  181n 

integration  with  production  theory,  173-188 

limited  application  of  Weber's,  179,  268- 
269 

need  to  develop  game  theory  for,  180, 
286 

sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  lo- 
eation-market-trade  doctrines,  256- 
285 

use  of  game  theory  in,  180-181,  181n 

Weber's,  applicability  to  entirely  new  situ- 
ations,  179,  268 
validity  for  new  area  development,    181- 

182,  268 
validity    for   regional   planning,    181-182, 
268 

see  also   Localization   theory  ;   Urbanization 
theory 
Aggregate  demand,  see  Demand,  aggregate 
Aggregate  demand  curve,  see  Demand  curve, 

aggregate 
Aggregate   supply    curve,    see   Supply   curve, 

aggregate 
Aggregation,   in   location   analysis,   21,   92-93, 
188-189 

industrial,   Colin   Clark   type,   21 
Leontief  type,  21 
useful  types  of,  21 
Aggregative  analysis,  interrelation  with  firm 
location    analysis,    93,    189,    198,    199, 
248 

use  of,  to  study  structure  of  space-economy, 
287 
Agricultural    enterprise,    see    Firm,    agricul- 
tural 
Agricultural     hinterlands,     see     Hinterlands, 

agricultural 
Agricultural  land  use,  and  industrial  and  res- 
idential   land     use,     competition     be- 
tween, 281 

and  structure  of  the  land  market,   40 

as  affected  by  raw  materials  supply,  248- 
249,  276 

as  constrained  by  regional  income  and 
other   total  conditions,    199 

as  interrelated  with  urban  land  use,  281, 
285 

as  related  to  factor  mobility,  285 

as  related  to  political  variable,   285 

as  related  to  regional  analysis,   199 

as  related  to  trade  and  geographic  speciali- 
zation, 285 

as  restricted  by  cultural  values  and  institu- 
tions,   205,    276,    280 

as   restricted   by   technology,   205,   280 

as  yielded  by  substitution  principle,  189- 
199,   205-206.   243-253,   275-278,  281 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


295 


Agricultural    land    use — continued 

basic     factors     determining,     2-3,     188-199, 

275-276 
changes  in   intensity  of,  along  substitution 

paths.  246-247 
competition    in,    as    leading   to   agricultural 
location   theory,    158 
as  leading  to  rent  theory,   158 
conditions  for  equilibrium  patterns  of,  245- 

251 
definition  of  type  of,  by  city-region,   249 
dependence    on    industrial   location,    8,    19, 

19n 
diminishing    returns    from    increasing    in- 
tensity  of,   4,   78 
effect  of  differentials  in  input  prices  upon, 

199n,  275 
effect     of     geographic     inequalities     of     re- 
sources upon,   18 
effect    on    industrial    location,    7 
elements  of,  in  a  Thiinen-Losch  model,  17- 

18 
forces    causing    irregularities    in,    276-277 
in   Ohlin's  model,   52 

intensity  of,  as  a  basic  variable  in  agricul- 
tural  location   theory,    244-247,    245n 
as  affected  by  net  farm   price,    194-195, 

244 
as  affecting  market  area  size,   271 
as   affecting   population   density,    271 
as  falling  with  distance  from  core    (mar- 
ket),    68-70,     155,     155n-157n,     194- 
195,  244,  247-248,  271 
as    related    to    factor    proportions,    194- 

195 
as  related  to  the  distance  variable,   194- 

195,  244,  285 
as  related  to  use  of  transport  inputs,   81 
changes  in  with  development,  3,  5,  8,   11 
effect   of   invariance   of   upon    rent   func- 
tion, 195n 
invalidity  of  constancy  assumption,  195n, 
244,  247 
limits  to,  as  precluding  analysis  of  systems 

of  supply  areas,   158 
need   to   consider    changes    in    intensity    of, 
to   unify   firm   and   industry   analysis 
in    agriculture,    247-248 
non-symmetric  character  of,  along  sides  of 

city-region    boundary,    249n 
optimum    pattern,    as    insured   by    competi- 
tion,   197-199,    281 
as  involving  equation   of   aggregate  sup- 
ply  and    demand,    198-199 
as  involving  problem  of  firm  equilibrium, 
198-199,   275-276 
patterns    of,    as    affected   by   multiple   mar- 
kets,  198-199,  249-251,   276 
as    determined    by    rent    functions,    195, 

197-199,    246,    276 
when    firm    produces    a    combination    of 
crops,  199,  276 
simple  pattern  of,  3 

sketch  of,  as  fused  with  sketch  of  modified 

Losch   market  system,    272,   277-278 

for  several  metropolitan  regions,  276-278 

zonal  intensity  of,  as  rising  or  falHng  with 

distance    from    market,    247n-248n 
see  also  Zones 
Agricultural  location  theory,  advantage  in  use 
of  inputs  of  agricultural  goods  with 
distance   from   city,   245n 


Agricultural     location      theory — continued 
and  central  position  of  rent  differentials  in, 

189,   196,  275,  276 
and    conditions    for    land    use    equilibrium, 

245-251 
and    crops    as    a    basic    variable,    190,    197- 

199,  276 
and    determination    of    equations    of    zonal 

boundaries,  246-247 
and    firm    indifference    to    location    within 

rent    yielding    hinterland,     197-198 
and  industrial  location  theory,  common  core 

of  cost  differential  analysis,   189-190, 

275 
and    production    functions    invariant    with 

distance   from   city,    244 
and   accepted   dualism   with   Weberian   doc- 
trine, 92-93,  188-189,  275 
and  continuity  of  the  location  problem,  196 
and  forcing  of  firms  into  efficient  substitu- 
tion paths,   196-197 
and  historical  approach,   15 
and   urban  land-use  theory,   competition  as 

basic   to  both,   205 
complementarity  as   basic  to  both,   205 
rent  functions  as  basic  to  both,  205,  280 
some  dissimilar  forces   in,   287 
and  use  of  rent  functions  to  determine  land 

use  patterns,   195,   197-199,  246,  276 
and    view    of    commodity    combinations    as 

single  commodities,  244,  276 
as  a  supplement  to  Losch  theory,   16 
as  a  transition  from  Weberian  firm  analy- 
sis,   189-190,    196-197,   275 
as  advanced  by  consideration  of  firm  equi- 
librium  problem,    198,   275-276 
as  explicitly  considering  transport  outlays, 

205,  280 
as    involving    firm    behavior   with   complete 

information,   196-197 
as  obtainable  from  analysis  along  a  straight 

line  from  city,  245n,  248n 
as   reflecting  competition   in   land  use,   158, 

188-199,    243-251,    277 
as  related  to  regional  analysis,   199 
as    substitution    between    land-use    outlays 

and    other   outlays,    33-34,    189-199 
as    yielded    by    general    location    principle, 

243-251,  252,  286 
as    yielded    by    substitution    principle,    189- 

199,    205-206,    243-251,    275-276 
assumption  of  given   prices   in,   210n,   243- 

244,  276 
assumption  of  invariance  of  transport  rate 

with   direction   from   city,    245 
basic    elements    of,    33n,    188-199,    243-251, 

275-278 
basic   role   of   space  factor   in,    188-199 
deeper  analysis  possible  than  in  industrial, 

190 
disadvantage  in  use  of  inputs  of  industrial 

goods  with  distance  from  city,  244n- 

245n 
emphasis  of,  on  cost  conditions,   210n 
extension  of,  to  cover  raw  material  supply 

areas,  248-249 
to  include  multiple  markets,  198-199,  249- 

251,  276 
to  incorporate  varying  unit  cost  on  farm, 

244-247 
generalized,    as    assuming   prices    as    given, 

249,  276 


296 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Agricultural      location      theory — continued 
as    avoiding-   definition   of   social   surplus, 

249 
as  avoiding  subjective  evaluations,  249n 
as  more  desirable  than   generalized  mar- 
ket area  analysis,   249 
to    include    other    location-market-supply 
analysis,  250-251 

incorporation  with  Weberian  doctrine  in 
one   framework,    92-93,    188-189,    275 

intensity  of  land  use  as  a  basic  variable  in, 
244-247,  245n 

interconnections  with  urban  land  use 
theory,  200-206,   280 

linkage  of  individual  farm  and  aggregate 
analysis,   189 

location  of  individual  producer  within,  92- 
93,   189-199,  275-276 

Losch's   approach   to,    48 

need  of  general  location  theory  for  multi- 
commodity  framework  to  encompass, 
243 

need  to  consider  changing  prices  in  a  truly 
general  system,  243 

need  to  define  industry  by  city-region  in, 
249 

need  to  study  bonds  with  urban  land  use 
theory,  280 

plus  elements  of  Losch  and  Weber,   16-19 

procedure  for  determining  rent,  190-199, 
244-251 

relative  neglect  in,  of  demand,  210n,  243- 
244,   275 

sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  lo- 
cation-market-trade doctrines,  256- 
285 

statement  of  problem  of,   244 

Thiinen  and  basic  location  methodology, 
27-28 

traditional  emphasis  on  aggregative  analy- 
sis, 92-93,   188-189 

transport  cost  on  material  inputs  in,  244n- 
245n,  248 

use  in,  of  multicommodity  framework,  197- 
199,  243-246,  276 

value   for    industrial   location    analysis,    189 

weakness   of   price   assumptions   of,    243 

see  also  Zone   formation 
Agricultural  production,  see  Agricultural  land 

use 
Agricultural    stratum,    as    a    foundation    for 
other  strata,  29 

effect  on   early   industrialization,    7,   29 

formation  of,  29 

locational  pull  of,   7,  29 

relation    to    industrial    stratum,    29 
Agriculture,  firm  analysis  in,  see  Firm,  agri- 
cultural 

industry  analysis  in,  and  firm  analysis,  case 
of    meaningless    distinction    between, 
247n 
need  to  consider  changes  in  average  unit 

cost  to  unify,   247-248 
need  to  consider  changes  in  land-use  in- 
tensity to  unify,   247-248 

in  extreme  case  as  firm  analysis,  248 

interrelation    with    firm    location    analysis, 
189,   198 
Aircraft,   and   population   mobility,    12 

and   site   selection,    12 

and    topographical    barriers,    12 

and    urban    decentralization,    12,    87-88 


Aircraft — continued 

effect  of,  on  industrial  location,  12 
on   metropolitan  structure,   12,   87-88 
on  space  preferences,   13 
on  trade  and   trade  routes,   12 
role  in   transport  network,   12 
Airway  passenger  movements,  variation  with 

population    and    distance,    62n 
Aluminum,   as   a   basic   industry,   18-19 

location  of,  and  substitution  between  power 
and    transport    outlays,    189-190 
Angle  conditions,  see  Equilibrium  point,  angle 

conditions 
Anglo-Saxon    bias,    against    spatial    analysis, 
24-27,    113 
partial   correction   of,   24n 
Atomic     energy,     and     government     subsidy, 
13 
and  new  industries,   13 
and   urban   decentralization,    13 
competitiveness   of   nuclear  power,   12-13 
effect  of,  on  existing  industries,  13 
on   interregional  trade,   13 
on    regional   development,    13 
on  space  preferences,   13 
locational  effect  of,  13,  79n 
Austi'o-Hungary,   cities  in,   rank-size  findings 

for,  57n 
Automobile  and  bus,  dispersion  of  urban  pop- 
ulation, 87-88 
effect  on  metropolitan  structure,  87-88 
Average  cost,  and  marginal  cost,  same  differ- 
ence   between    for    all    producers    in 
Losch,   240 
as   affecting   farm  output,   190-194 
as  base  for  delivered  price  in  Losch  scheme, 

240 
as  equated  to  price  in   Losch  scheme,  240 
as  varying  in  the  more  general  case  of  lo- 
cation, 236 
changes  in,   along  substitution   paths,   246- 

247 
disadvantages  relative  to  marginal  cost  in 

boundary   definition,   236n 
equality  with  net  farm  price  in  farm  equi- 
librium,  197 
incorporation  of  changes  in,  in  agricultural 

location    theory,    244-247 
invalidity    of    constancy    assumption,    195n, 

244,  247 
need  to  consider  changes  in,  to  unify  firm 
and  industry  analysis  in  agriculture, 
247-248 
on  farm,  constancy  of,  in  traditional  loca- 
tion theory,  244 
use    of,    to   determine    market   boundary    in 

single    firm    case,    231-232 
see   also    Cost   curves 
Average  cost  curves,   see  Cost  curves 
Average    cost   pricing,    see    Pricing    system 

Back  hauls,  effect  on  firm's  equilibrium  loca- 
tion,  113n 
effect  on  transport  cost  surface,  251 
Basic    form    of    space-economy,    and    market 
structure,  39-42 
and   the  spatial  array  of  markets,   38-41 
Weigmann's    concept   of,    38-42 
Basic   industry,   and  size  of  urban-metropoli- 
tan  region,   11,  278 
and    support    of    non-basic    activities,     11, 
128n,  278 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


297 


Basic    industry — continued 

as  aflEecting  spatial  pattern  of  service  activ- 
ities, 278n 
as   generating  secondary  labor,   128n 
by    types,    different    direct    land    input    re- 
quirements of,   285 
different   income   effects   of,    284 
different  indirect  land  input  requirements 

of,  285 
different   multiplier    effects    of,    284 
different   secondary   effects    of,   284-285 
non-raw  material  using  activities  as,  274n- 

275n 
pull   on   parasitic   industry,   8-9,    128n 
service  activities  as,   274n-275n 
using    localized    raw    materials,    and    asso- 
ciated   population    cluster,    19-20 
and  change  in  agricultural  land  use,   19, 

19n 
and  change  in  hierarchy  of  cities,  19,  19n 
and    change    in    structure   of    market-ori- 
ented   activities,    19,    278 
and   local  multiplier   effects,    19 
and  the  Thunen-Losch  model,    18-19 
as    swelling    urban    population,    278 
effect  on  urban  income  stream,  278 
non-applicability  of  Losch  theory  to,  154, 

274 
plus  market-oriented  activities  as  yielding 
urban-metropolitan     structure,     274- 
275,  278-280 
pull   on    ubiquities    using   activities,    278 
Basic-non-basic    ratio,    11 

variation   with  type  of  city,   11 
Basic      service      ratio,      see      Basic-non-basic 

ratio 
Beckmann,    and    continuous    geographical   in- 
tensity   distributions    of    production, 
168n 
and  neglect  of  certain  location  forces,  168n- 

169n 
as  generalizing  the  Enke  market  problem, 

168n 
needed   extension   of,    to   solve  the   location 
problem,   168n 
Behavior  patterns,  and  pattern  of  settlement, 
2,  6,  78 
as    reflected    in   space   preference,    84-85 
as   reflected   in   time   preference,    84-85 
see    also    Rationality ;    Game    theory 
Bogue    and    the    impact    of    distance,    on    in- 
tensity of  land  use,   68-70 
on   population   density,    68-70 
on  receipts  from  services,   68-70 
on  retail  sales,   68-70 
on  structure  of  metropolitan  region,   68- 

70 
on   value  added  by  manufacture,   68-70 
on   wholesale  sales,   68-70 
Bortkiewicz'  criticism  of  Weber's  use  of  ficti- 
tious distances,  109 
Boundaries,  see  City-region  boundaries  ;  Mar- 
ket boundaries  ;   Supply  area  bound- 
aries ;  Zonal  boundaries 
Breaks    in    transport    system,    see    Transport 

network,  breaks  in 
Brinkmann,   and  advantage   in  use  of  inputs 
of    agricultural    goods    with    distance 
from  city,  245n 
and  constant  unit  cost  on  farm,  244 
and    the    effect    of    differentials    in     input 
prices  on  agricultural  location,   199n 


Brinkmann — continued 

and  yield  per  acre  as  invariant  with  dis- 
tance   from    city,    244 

disadvantage  in  use  of  inputs  of  industrial 
goods  with  distance  from  city,  244n- 
245n 

transport    costs    on    inputs    in    theory    of, 
244n-245n 
Bus    passenger    movements,    and   the   PvPijD 
factor,  61-63 

variation  with  population  and  distance, 
61-63 

Canadian  cities,  rank-size  findings  for,  57n 
Capital,    as   a   location    factor,    133 

as    distinguished    from    services,    89-90 
relation  of  spatial  to  other  elasticity  forms 

of,  41 
some  elements  of  theory  of,  81-90 
Capital  goods,  adaptability  of  and  location,  41 
bound,  41 

combination-free,   41 
market,   immobility   in,   41 
spatial  inelasticity  in,  41 
structure  of,  40-41 
Capital  inputs,  and  the  investment  period  of 
factors,  82-83 
and  the  roundaboutness  of  production,   82- 

83,  255 
and  the  time  extent  of  production,  82 
and  transport  inputs,  substitution  between, 

253 
as  embodied  in  transport  inputs,  89-90 
as    ultimately    stemming    from    labor    and 

land  inputs,  81,  255 
definition   of,    81,    81n 
increase  in  output  with  increase  in  use  of, 

81-82 
profit  motive  and  the  use  of,  81-82 
transport    inputs    contrasted    with,     81-85, 

255 
use  of,  and  the  increase  in  the  time  period 
of  investment,   82 
Capital   outlays,    and    transport   outlays,   sub- 
stitution   between,    33 
in   Predohl's    framework,   33 
in  terms  of  use  units,  35 
Capital  structure,  as  related  to  spatial  extent 
of   production   via   substitution   prin- 
ciple,  253 
changes  in,  with  orientation  to  cheap  cap- 
ital sites,   133 
Capitalism,   bound,   and   immobile  labor,   40n- 
41n 
free,  and  mobile  labor,  40n-41n 
Central  dependent  stratum,  as  tied  to  central 

organizing  stratum,  29 
Central   organizing   stratum,    composition    of, 
29 
effect  on  central  dependent  stratum,  29 
independence  of,  29 
Central  place  theories,   and  frequency   distri- 
bution of  cities,   59-60,  60n 
and  spatial  regularity  of  cities,   60,   60n 
of  Christaller  and  Losch,  60,  60n 
Centrifugal  effect,  and  decentralization  policy, 
13 
and  space  preference,  84-85 
from   diminishing   returns,   4,   78n,   84 
Centripetal    effect,    and    lines    of    force    in    a 
potential  field,  78« 
from  increasing  returns,  4 


298 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Chamberlin,  solution  of,  to  Hotelling  problem 
when  three  or  more  competitors,  162 
tendency  for  competitors  to  disperse,  162 
see  also  Monopolistic  competition 
Cheap  labor,  see  Labor,  cheap 
Chemicals,  as  a  basic  industry,   18-19 
Child   labor,   see  Labor,   cheap 
Chipman,  and  linear  programming  in  simple 

trade-location   case,    214n 
Christaller,     and     frequency     distribution     of 
cities,  59-60 
and  hierarchy  of  cities,   60n 
and  spatial  regularity  of  cities,   60n 
central  place  theories  of,  60,  60n 
resource  inequalities  and  spatial  pattern  of 
cities,  60 
Circles,   as   market   boundaries,    145-147,   231, 
239 
as   supply   area   boundaries,    155 
distorted,  as  superior  to  regular  hexagonal 
markets    in    a    general    case,    242n- 
243n 
Cities,  advantages  and  disadvantages  of,  for 
plant   location,    183 
and  size  of  basic-non-basic  ratio,  11 
as  centers  of  market-oriented  activities,  57 
as  local  peaks  of  population  potential,   66- 

67,  78 
decline  of,  8-9,  17-18,  19 
emergence  of  different  sizes  of,  and  econo- 
mies  of   scale,    57-58 
frequency   distribution    of,    at   shortest   dis- 
tance intervals,  by  size  classes,  59 
growth  of,  4-9,   19,   19n,  29 

and   deglomeration   economies,   139 
and  increase  in  cost  of  food  supply,  139 
and  increase  of  rents,   139 
hierarchy  of,   and   regularity  of  flows   over 
distance,  58-60 
Christaller's,  60n 
hierarchy    of    sites    within,    in    a    modified 
Losch    diagram,    272-273 
>     network  of,  as  reflecting  the  joint  distribu- 
tion of  economic  activities,   184 
desirable  changes  in,   183 
operating   economies    of,    186-187 
optimum   hierarchy   of,    183 
optimum  hierarchy  of  sites   within,   183 
optimum  size  of,    12 
optimum  spatial  distribution  of,   183 
patterns  of,   as  associated  with  commodity 
flows,  281 
as   associated  with  population  flows,   281 
proximity  of,  as  affecting  power  generation 

economies,   185 
rank  of,  11,  12 

rank-size   findings   on,   in   Austro-Hungary, 
57n 
in  Canada,  57n 
in  France,  57n 
in  Germany,  57n 
in  India,  57n 

in  United  States,  56-57,  57n 
rank-size   rule    for,    mathematical   formula- 
tion of,  55-56 
universality  of,  57 
validity  of,  57 

Zipf's  interpretation  of  deviations  from, 
57n 
rise  of  new,   and  new  basic  industry,   19 
and  new  iron  and  steel  location,  19n 
and  new  plant  locations,  17,  18 


Cities — continued 

satellite,  and  secondary  peaks  in  rent  func- 
tion, 203 
structure  of,  12 
selection  among,  8-9,  19 
service  activities  as  basic  industry  in,  274n- 

275n 
size  of,   and  deglomeration  forces,   78,   139, 
186 
and   dominance   in  national  commodities, 

58 
and   economies  of  scale   in  power  gener- 
ation, 184-185 
and  geographic  inequalities  of  resources, 

78 
and  hypothetical  economies  of  scale,  186- 

187 
and   size   and   character   of   urban   trans- 
port network,   185-186 
and  volume  and  length  of  population  and 

commodity  flows,   58,   281 
as   related  to  basic  activities,   278 
associated  with   number  of   activities   in, 
57 
spatial  pattern  of,  and  central  place  theory, 
60,  60n 
and  hierarchy  of  cities,  58-60 
and  resource  inequalities,  60 
and  spatial  regularity,  58-60,  60n 
and  the  Forces  of  Unification  and  Diver- 
sification, 78n-79n 
empirical  data  on,  in  Iowa,  59 
in  South  Germany,  60n 
standardization   of,    by   basic   service   ratio, 
186n 
by  flow  configurations,   186n 
by  industrial  mix,  186n 
by  land  use  patterns,  186n 
invalidity  of,  186-187 
variation    in    power    consumption    by    type 
of,  184 
City-regions,   and  need   to  define  industry   in 
terms  of,  249 
as     focal    point    for    agricultural     location 

theory,   198-199,  244 
boundaries    of,    as    cutting    off    concentric 

zones,  249n 
boundaries   of,   non-symmetric  character  of 

land  use  along  sides  of,  249n 
commodity   trade   between,    17-18 
effect  of  multi-,  upon  agricultural  land-use 

patterns,    198-199,    249-251 
geographic   specialization   among,    17-18 
hinterland    boundaries    of,    as    implied    by 

general    location    principle,    249n 
hinterlands  of,  16-17,  249n 
see     also     Cities ;     Urban-metropolitan     re- 
gions ;   Urban-metropolitan  structure 
Classical  school,  neglect  of  space,   27,   50,   89, 
116 
neglect    of    transport-orientation    in    trade 
theory,  50,   53,  208 
Classification    of   commodities,    see   Commodi- 
ties,  classification   of 
Classification  of  industry,  see  Industry,  classi- 
fication of 
Classification  of  location  factors,  see  Location 

factors,   classification   of 
Classification    of   markets,    see   Market   areas, 

classification  of 
Climate,  as  a  location  factor,  2,  3,   133,  138 
_  Coal,  as  a  localized  raw  material.  19 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


299 


Coal   deposits,   relation   of,   to   iron   and   steel 

location,    7-9,    19n,    118n 
Commercial    activities,    importance    in    urban 
structure,   200n-201n 
see  also  Market-oriented  activities  ;  Service 
activities 
Commercial  land  use,  see  Urban  land  use 
Commodities,  categories  of,  in  terms  of  num- 
ber of  substitution  relations,  94 
classification  of,   by  dispensability,   93-94 
by  number  of  sources,  93-94 
by  mobility,  93-94 
by  weight-loss,  93-94 
in  terms  of  possible  types  of  substitution, 

94 
by  size  market  area,   17,   153,  271 
conditionally  place-bound,   32n 
differences  in  transport  rate  by  type  of,  88 
Englander's  classification,   31n-32n 
fixed     proportion     of,     and     restraints     on 
transformation   function,    137 
and  substitution  limitations,  131,  136-137 
immobility  of,  and  limited  competition,  37- 

38 
markets  for,  in  terms  of  factor  markets,  40 
national,  17,  18,  58 

and  economies  of  scale,  58 
dominance  in  and  size  of  city,   58 
perfect  mobility  of,  33 
place-free,  31n-32n 
regional,  17 
subnational,  18 
subregional,  17 
substitution  between  groups  and  subgroups 

of,  95n,  227-228 
supraregional,  17,  18 
transport    rates    by    characteristics    of,    88, 

112,    118n.   227n 
unconditionally    place-bound,    32n 
unique  combinations   of,   and   firm   analysis 

as    industry   analysis,    248 
use   of  multicommodity   framework,   in   ag- 
ricultural   location    theory,    197-199, 
243-246 
in    Losch    analysis,    44-49,    153-154,    270- 

271 
in  urban  land  use  theory,  204-206 
in   urbanization   theory,    185-188,   268-270 
view    of    combinations    of,    as    single    com- 
modities,  244,   275 
Commodity  flows,  a  case  of  intranational,  282 
and  composition  of  trade,  9 
as   associated  with   city   patterns,   281 
as   associated  with  land-use   patterns,   281, 

282-285 
as  associated  with  location  patterns,  281 
as  basic  to  analysis  of  space-economy,  22, 

281 
as   determined    in   a   general   market-trans- 
portation-location model,   168n-169n 
as   determined   in    Enke's    market   problem, 

167n-168n 
as  related  to  urban-metropolitan  structure, 

282-2S5 
as  simultaneously  determined  with  location, 

207 
distributional  stability  of,  22 
effect  of   friction   of  distance,   by  type,    70, 

72n 
effect  on,  of  changes  in  demand,  156n-157n 
of  changes  in  distance  variable,  215-219, 
282-285 


Commodity     flows — continued 

of  changes  in  supply,   156n-157n 
of  changes   in   transport  rate,   156n-157n 
hierarchy  of,  by  volume  and   length,   58 
international,   and   need   to   consider   trans- 
port-orientation,  210 
in  a  simple  trade-location  example,  210- 
219,  283-285 
length  of,  and  economies  of  scale,  58 
and  market  types,   58 
and  size  of  city,   58 
need   for   finer   analysis  of,   287 
need  to  specify   demand   to  determine  pat- 
tern of,  212 
of  selected  raw  materials  and  finished  prod- 
uct, 281-285 
over  distance,  70-75 
sketches  of,  282,  284-285 
variety  of  in  reality,  281 
volume  of,  and  size  of  city,   58 

as    significant    in    determining    transport 
rates,  213n 
see  also  Trade 
Comparative    advantage,    situations    of,    in    a 
simple    three-country    case,    213-219, 
282-285 
Competition,    absence    of,    and    circularity   of 
market  areas,   145 
as  basic  to  both  agricultural  location  theory 

and  land  use  theory,  205,  280 
as    eliminating   surplus    profits,    196,    196n- 

197n,  202 
as     equating     price    and    average    cost    in 

Losch,  240 
as   forcing   farmers    into   efficient   substitu- 
tion  paths,    196-197 
as   insuring  best  farm  practices,   197-199 
as    insuring    maximum   rent   for   each   site, 

196,   197-199 
as    insuring    optimum    pattern    of    agricul- 
tural land  use,   197-199 
as  linking  individual  farm  and  aggregative 

agricultural    analysis,    199 
degree  of,  and  variation  in  transport  rate, 

88 
effect  on  urban  land  use,  200-205,  280 
for   sites,    effect   on    price    of   urban    land, 

200-205 
imperfect,   as   leading  to  overlapping  mar- 
ket boundaries,  264 
in   agriculture,   as   involving   firm  behavior 

with  complete  information,   196-197 
land   use,    as   embraced    in   general   equilib- 
rium  approach,    201n 
as     problem     of     firm     equilibrium,     198, 

280 
effect  on   rent  function.   204-205 
quality,  effect  on  urban  land  use,  281 
role  of,   in   Losch,   44-45,   240 
see  also  Competitive  locational  equilibrium  ; 
Monopolistic  competition  ;  Pure  com- 
petition 
Competitive     equilibrium,     see     Agricultural 
land  use  ;  Competitive  locational  equi- 
brium ;    Market    areas ;    Urban    land 
use 
Competitive  field,  as  a  spatial  array  of  mar- 
kets, 38-39 
Competitive    locational    equihbrium,    Ackley's 
solutions,  165 
and  hinterlands  of  firms,  161-165 
and  spatial  price   discrimination,   163n 


300 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Competitive  locational  equilibrium — continued 
and   the    Cournot   problem   when    firms    in- 

finitesimally   close,    161n 
as  allied  to  Koopman's  transportation  prob- 
lem,  167n-169n 
as  allied  to  spatial  price  equilibrium,  167n- 

169n 
as    related    to    the    general    transportation 

problem,  167n-169n 
as  yielding  less  precise  results  than  market 

area  analysis,    169,   264-265 
cases    of    discontinuous    consumer    distribu- 
tion,  165 
Chamberlin's   solution  when  three  or   more 

competitors,   162 
competitive    behavior    as    affected    by    type 

of  market  discontinuity,  165 
competitive   behavior   as   unrestricted    vari- 
able,  166 
determinacy   of,    as   related   to  market   dis- 
continuity,  165 
difficulties   in   application   of   present   game 

theory     to,     167,     265 
dispersion    of    competitors    in    Chamberlin's 

analysis,   162 
effect  on,  of  economies  of  scale,   173-176 
of  size  of  market,   164 
of  transport   cost,    164 
Enke's    market   problem    as    a    simple    case 

of,   167n-168n 
Hotelling,    and    simultaneous    variation    of 
price   and   location,    160-162 
agglomeration    tendency,    162,     163n 
solution  (s),   assumptions    in,    161 
borne   out  by   Zeuthen,    161 
invalidity    of,    for    autonomous    trading 

firms,   162-163,   163n 
stability  of,   161-162 
when   both   firms  mobile,    162 
when    no    undercutting,    161 
when   one  producer  immobilized,   161 
when     one     producer     trades     autono- 
mously,  161 
when   producers   undercut,   161-162 
when   production   costs   are  zero,    161 
lack    of    generalized    solutions    because    of 

spatially  discrete  demand,   165 
Lerner  and  Singer,   and  demand  elasticity, 
163-164 
and    more    realistic    undercutting    policy, 

163-164 
and  upper  price  limit,   163-164 
many   solutions    in,    depending   on   assump- 
tions,  160-165,   264-265 
models  of,  as  being  more  sophisticated  than 
market  area  analysis,   169,  265 
as    ignoring    various    inequalities    in    re- 
source distribution,  169-170 
need    to    allow    areal    distribution    of    de- 
mand,  169 
need  to  allow  areal  mobility  of  the  firm, 

169 
need     to     allow     more     realistic     pricing 

policy,   169 
need  to  consider  more  realistic  cost  con- 
ditions,  169 
need  for  sharply  defined  concept  of  rational 

behavior,  286 
need  to   integrate  with  market  and  supply 

area   analysis,    170,    265 
need  to   integrate  with  Weberian   doctrine, 
170 


Competitive  locational  equilibrium- — continued 
neglect  of,  in  Launhardt-Palander  construc- 
tion, 264-265 
Palander's  criticism  of  Hotelling's  agglom- 
eration,  162-163,   163n 
Palander's     solution  (s),     autonomous     and 
"superpolitisch"   trade   in,    163 
for   autonomously   trading  firms,   162-163 
hintei-land    defense,    conditions    for,    163, 

163n 
market    sharing    policy,    conditions    for, 

163,   163n 
price  fluctuations  when  firms  close,   162- 

163 
undercutting   policy,    conditions   for,   133, 
163n 
relevance  of  game  theory  for,  165-167,  170, 

265 
results  of,   as   yielded  by  substitution  prin- 
ciple,  170 
separation   of  rivals  as  insulation  from  re- 
actions,  167 
Smithies,  and  effect  of  changes  in  marginal 
cost,   165n 
and    hinterland    demand    as    function    of 

price  and  location,   164 
and  types  of  competitive  behavior,  164n- 

165n 
solution   with  linear  demand,    164 
stability  of,   as   related  to  market  disconti- 
nuity,  165 
undercutting    as    related    to    proximity    of 

producers,   161 
unrealities   of   game   theory   postulates   for, 

167 
see    also    Agricultural    land    use ;    Equilib- 
rium     points ;      Firm      agricultural ; 
Firm,       industrial ;      Firm,       urban ; 
Urban  land  use 
Complementarity    of    land    uses,    analysis    of,- 
as    requiring    a    complex    approach, 
205n 
as   basic   to  both   agricultural   location   and 

land  use  theory,  205n 
as   embraced   in   a   general  equilibrium   ap- 
proach, 201n 
as   similar   to  agglomeration,   205n 
effect    of,    on    price    of    urban    land,    200- 
205 
on  production  costs,   200-205,  280 
on  rent  functions,  204-205 
on   sales   volume,   200-205 
on  secondary  peaks  of  sales  volume,  201n 
on  urban  land  use,  200-205,  280 
types  of,  200,  205 
Complex  analysis,   as  an   element  of  regional 
science,  287 
need    for,     in    agglomeration    theory,     188, 
205n 
in  urban  land  use  theory,  205n 
to  synthesize  with  other  techniques,  287 
use    of,    to    study   structure   of    space-econ- 
omy, 287 
to  treat  substitution  in  the  large,  287 
Concentration    of    urban    activities    as    deter- 
mined by  rent  functions,   204-205 
Conditions    of    equilibrium,    see    Equilibrium 

conditions 
Congestion,    and    spatial    extent    of    agricul- 
ture, 4 
from  population  growth,   4 
increase   of,   and   deglomeration,    139 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


301 


Congestion — continued 

and  urbanization  diseconomies,   183,   185- 
186 
see  also  Deglomeration  economies 
Constant  cost  conditions,  market  area  analy- 
sis under,  148,  235-236 
supply  area  analysis  under,   155,  235-236 
Consumer  behavior,  and  increasing  consump- 
tion  of  transport  inputs,   87-88 
as  affected  by  a  fall  in  time  and  money  cost 

of  population  movement,  87-88 
changes  in,  and  the  scale  effect,  87-88 
changes     in,     and    the    substitution    effect, 

87-88 
see  also  Consumption 
Consumer    distribution,    see    Population    dis- 
tribution 
Consumer  expenditure  pattern,  see  Consump- 
tion pattern 
Consumer     indifference     as     defining     market 

boundaries,  231-232,  236,  236n 
Consumer  surplus,  see  Surplus,  social 
Consumer  tastes,  see  Tastes,  consumer 
Consumption,   area  of,   ability  of  Launhardt- 
Palander  construction  to  treat,   257- 
258,  262-264 
as   a  finite  number  of   variables,   237-238 
as  a  set  of  market  areas,  237-242 
as  an  infinity  of  market  points,  237 
as  related  to  material  sources  via  indus- 
trial  producers,    263-264 
breakdown    by    production    location,    257- 
269 
effect  of  density  of,  on  conditions  for  max- 
imizing social  surplus,   233n 
level  of,  as  affected  by  changes  in  distance 
variable,  214-219 
in  a  simple  three  country  trade-location 
example,    214-219  ;    of   new   commod- 
ity,  locational  effect  of,   4 
pattern  of,  effect  of  changes  in  supply  on, 
156n-157n 
effect   of    changes    in   transport   rate   on, 

156n-157n 
need  to  study  relation  with  metropolitan 
structure,  287 
urban,  and  effect  on  weighting  of  net  econ- 
omy curves,   186-187 
variation   in   density   of,    and   multiple   sta- 
tionary points  in  market  area  analy- 
sis, 234 
see  also  Market  areas 
Corner   location,   see  Equilibrium  point,   as   a 
corner  ;  Equilibrium  point,  as  an  end 
point 
Cost    curves,    as    affected,    by    distance    from 
urban  core,  202,  202n 
by    resource   content   of   land,    194,    194n, 

202n 
by  taxes,  194,   194n 
change    of,    with    pricing    system    change, 

150n 
effect  on,  of  advertising  outlays,  203-204 
of  irregularities  in  labor  cost,  202n 
of  product  quality,  203-204 
of  service  quality,  203-204 
of  topography,  202n 
use  of,  in  agricultural  location  theory,  190- 
194 
in   determining   rent   functions,    201-205 
in  determining  urban  land  use,  201-202 
with  rent  as  explicit  cost,  191,  193-194 


Cost  curves — continued 

see  also  Average  cost ;  Marginal  cost 
Cost  of  living,  and  urban  diseconomies,  186 

increases   in,   with  city  size,    186 
Costs,    conditions   of,    as   emphasized    in    Gra- 
ham's   trade   theory,    210 
emphasis     upon,      in     traditional     location 

theory,  21 On 
inadequate  treatment  of,  in  location  theory 

for  international  analysis,  210 
inequalities    in    the    geographic    pattern    of, 
as  ignored  by  competitive  equilibrium 
models,   169-170 
by  type  of,  169 
validity    of    principle    of    minimization    of, 

221n 
see  also  Average  cost ;  Cost  curves  ;  Factor 
costs  ;    Marginal    cost ;     Opportunity 
costs  ;  Prices 
Cournot     problem,     reduction     of     Hotelling 
problem    to,     when    firms    infinitesi- 
mally  close,   161n 
Critical  isodapane,   see  Isodapane,  critical 
Crops,  as  a  basic  variable  in  agricultural  loca- 
tion theory,   190,   197-199 
changes   in,   as  involving  substitution,   197- 

199,  275 
combinations   of,    as   characteristic   of   real- 
ity,  199 
as   contained  in   farm  equilibrium  analy- 
sis,  199,  275 
different  types  of,  associated  with  different 

rent  functions,   195,  197-199,  276 
zones   of    cultivation    of,    as    determined   by 
rent   functions,    195,    197-199,   275 
with   multiple   markets,    198-199,   275 
see    also    Agricultural    land    use 
Cross  hauling,  see  Market  areas,  overlapping 
Cultivation    of    crops,    see    Agricultural    land 

use 
Cultural   complexes,    patterns   and   traits,   see 

Cultural   values    and    institutions 
Cultural    values    and    institutions,    and    cheap 
labor,   8-9,   10,   128n 
and  decentralization  policy,  13 
and  variations  in  local  input  costs,  130-131, 

138 
as    a    distorting    factor    in    space-economy, 

138,  276 
as  limiting  land  use,  205-206,  276,  280 
as   reflected  in  policy  decisions,  287 
changes  in,  from  technological  advance,   13 
effect  of,  on  agricultural  zones,  16,  276 
on   international  trade,   75,   283n 
on  population  pattern,  144n-145n,  287 
on  space-economy,  need  for  deeper  study 

of,  287 
on   urban-metropolitan   structure,    10,    11, 

12,   283n,   287 
on   urban   transit   network,   185 
locational  effect  of,  2,  4,  6,  8-9,  10,   12,   13, 

21,   138-140,  283n 
see  also  Political  variable 

Dean,  and  emphasis  on  relative  gross  weights 
and  relative  distances,   121,  225n 
and  the  generalized   index  test,   121 
and  the  historical  approach,   15,  31n 
criticism  of  Weber  for  overestimating  pull 

of   weight-losing   materials,   225n 
criticism  of  Weber  for  underestimating  pull 
of  pure  materials,   225n 


302 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Dean — continued 

deviational    economies    and    power    orienta- 
tion,  132 
use  of  weight  triangle  in  transport-orienta- 
tion problem,   120-122 
Decentralization    (industrial  and  urban),  and 
aircraft,   12 
and  atomic  energy,  13 

and  future   metropolitan   organization,    13 
and   technological   advance,    10,    12,    79n 
of    activities,    relation    to    rent    functions, 

204-205 
policy,   and   agglomeration   economies,    14 
and  demand  for  transportation  and  util- 
ity  services,    14-15 
and  guiding  new  industrial  growth,  14-15 
and    historical    inertia,    14-15 
and    input-output    and    by-product    rela- 
tions,  14-15 
and  locational  shifts,   14-15 
and  meaningful  metropolitan  sectors,  13- 

14 
and   resource   conservation,    14-15 
and  size  of  consumer  market,  14-15 
and  structure  of  labor  force,  14-15 
and  structure  of  labor  requirements,   14 
as   deviational  policy,    13 
restraints  upon,  13-14 
Decisions,  of  urban  units,  as  reflecting  prin- 
ciples of  urban  land  use  theory,  205- 
206 
policy,    see   Political   variable 
rational,  see  Game  theory  ;  Rationality 
Deglomeration,   see  Agglomeration 
Deglomeration    diseconomies,   see   Agglomera- 
tion economies 
Deglomeration    economies,    and    spread    into 
space,  78,  255 
as  associated  with  the  use  of  transport  in- 
puts, 255 
as  independent  of  geographic  position,  139- 

140 
as  primarily  dependent  on  magnitudes,  139- 

140 
as    they    counteract    Force    of    Unification, 

79n 
effect   on   location   patterns,    79n,    84 
from  congestion,   139 
from    increase    in    intensity    of    land    use, 

139 
from  increase  in  urban  population,   139 
from  rise  in  cost  of  food  supply,  139 
from   rise  in   cost  of  urban  services,   139 
from  rise  in  rents,  139 
implications  for  non-herd  existence,  84 
spatial  pattern   of,   as   derived   from   inter- 
action of  other  forces,   140 
see  also  Agglomeration  economies  ;  Decen- 
tralization 
Delivered  price  line,  as  a  transport  gradient 
line,   148-149 
construction  of,   148 
Delivered   prices,   equal,   loci   of   points   of   as 
boundaries,    146-147,    237,   240 
equality    of,    from    several    supply    sources, 

155,  155n-157n 
rise  of,  with  increase  in  supply  area,  155 
Demand,   aggregate,   as   related  to  the  labor 
market,  40 
as  related  to  the  land  market,  40 
equation   to   aggregate   supply   for   agricul- 
tural  equilibrium,    198-199 


Demand — continued 

assumption  of  fixed  pattern  of,  in  long-run 

trade  theory,  212n 
effective,  as  setting  limits  to  market  areas, 

145-147 
elasticities   of,   and  differentials   in  revenue 

potentials,  126n 
need  to  introduce  areal  distribution  of,  into 
competitive      locational      equilibrium 
theory,   169 
need    to    specify,    to    determine    exchange 
ratios,  212 
to  determine  location   pattern,  212 
to   determine   trade  pattern,   212 
regional,  need  to  consider  in  general  loca- 
tion theory,  207 
need  to  consider  in  trade  theory,  207 
relative   neglect   of,    in   traditional   location 

theory,  210n 
total,    as    restraining    urban    land    use    pat- 
tern, 206,   287 
see  also  Demand  curve 
Demand    curve,    aggregate,    construction    of, 
156n-157n,   159n 
use  of  with  aggregate  supply  curve,  157n 
effect    of    shift    of,    on    commodity    flows, 
156n-157n 
on  output  of  supply  sources,   156n-157n 
for  the  firm,  sloping,  construction  of,  159n 

sloping,  because  of  space,  158-159 
invalidity  of  horizontal,   158-159 
Demographic  energy,   concept  of,   65 
linear  relation  with  state  incomes,   68 
population   and  distance  as   basic  variables 
of,  65-66 
Demographic   force,   concept  of,   65 

population   and  distance  as  basic  variables 

of,  65-66 
relation  to  Reilly's  law  of  retail  gravitation, 
65n 
Development  processes,   Palander's   insistence 
upon  study  of,  43 
sketch  of  some  basic  elements  of,  1-15 
Deviational  economies,  see  Dean 
Differentials,  analysis  of,  as  common  to  both 
industrial   firm   and   farm   enterprise 
location,   189-190,   199,  275 
limits  to  substitution  in  considering  many, 

137 
outlay  and  revenue,   and  substitution,   135- 
137,   137n 
location  effect  of,  126-137 
need  to  consider  all  types  of,   135 
procedures    in    considering    several,    135- 
137,   137n 
see  also  Labor  outlays  ;  Power  outlays  ;  Pro- 
duction outlays  ;  Revenue  potentials  ; 
Transport  outlays 
Diffusion,  see  Decentralization 
Diminishing  returns,  and  the  need  for  spread 
into  space,  78,  255 
centrifugal  effect  of,  4,  78n,  84,  255 
postponement  of,  and  the  use  of  transport 
inputs,  255 
Disaggregation,  in  location  analysis,  21,  92-93 
industrial,   Colin  Clark  type,  21 
Leontief  type,  21 
useful  types  of,   21 
Disaggregative   analysis,   see  Disaggregation 
Discontinuity,  see  Location,  problem  of  ;  Sub- 
stitution, in  the  large ;  Transforma- 
tion line,  discontinuous 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


303 


Discounting  over  space,  see  Space  Discount 
Discounting  over  time,  discounting  over  space 

contrasted  with,   85-86 
Diseconomies     of     scale,     see     Deglomeration 

economies  ;  Economies  of  scale 
Dispersion,   see  Decentralization 
Distance,  as  fostering  spatial  price  discrimi- 
nation,  164n 
between    rivals    as    insulation    from    game 

theory  reaction,   167 
effective,    as    physical   distance   adjusted    in 
time-cost  dimensions,  200-201,  205n 
as  related   to   transport  technology,    16 
transport   network    as    critical    in    defini- 
tion of,  205 
fictitious,    invalid    use    of    by    Weber,    109, 

109n 
friction   of,   and  sloping  demand  curve  for 
the  firm,   158-159 
and    the    need    for    transport   inputs,    79, 

80n,   140 
effect  of  by  type  commodity  flows,  70 
presence  in  social  system,  75-76 
from  transport  route  and  increase  in  mar- 
ket area  size,  274n 
physical,    and    Weigmann's    theory    of    lim- 
ited  competition,   38-39 
as  different  from  effective  distance,  200- 
201,  205n 
time-cost,  3,  201 

unnecessary,  and  minimization  of  transport 
cost,  96-97 
as  precluded  in  the  transformation  func- 
tion, 96-97,   lOln,   107 
possibility   of   with  discriminatory  trans- 
port rates,  97n,   lOln,   113n,   130n 
see  also  Distance  variable  ;  Space 
Distance  inputs,  replacement  of,  by  the  term 
transport   inputs,   80 
use    of,    instead    of   transport    inputs,    pros 

and  cons,   116 
see   also   Distance    variable ;    Transport   in- 
puts 
Distance    variable  (s),    and    basic    regularities 
in  space-economy,  75-76,   140,  254 
and  bus   passenger   movements,   61-63 
and  Class   1  Railroad  shipments,   70-73 
and  empirical  findings  by  Losch,   60n 
and  family  migration  in  Cleveland,  63-64 
and   international   commodity   flows,    73-75, 

208-209,  282-285 
and  intranational   commodity   flows,   70-73, 

208-209,  282-283 
and  population  density,   68-70,  271-273 
and  railway  express  shipments,  60-61 
and  Ravenstein's  finding  on  migration,  64n 
and  retail  sales,  68-70 
and  secondary  peaks,  in  rent  function,  203 

in   sales  volume  curve,   201 
and  service  receipts,  68-70 
and   shipments,    by   type    I.C.C.    commodity 

group,  72n 
and    telephone    messages,    61-62 
and  value  added  by  manufacture,   68-70 
and  wholesale  sales,  68-70 
and  world  ocean-going  freight,  73-75 
as    affecting   cost  curves,    194,   202 
as  affecting  exchange  ratios,  215n,  217 
as   affecting   factor   proportions,   275 
as   affecting  farm   output,    190-194 
as   affecting   population   content   of  market 
areas,  278 


D  istance    variable  ( s )  — continued 

as  affecting  price  of  land  input,  275 

as  affecting  structure  of  industrial  districts, 
282-285 

as  affecting  substitution  points  of  farm  en- 
terprise,  197,  275 

as  basic,  in  Stewart's  social  physics,  65-68 

as  basic  to  location  theory,  35-36 

as  contained  in  concept  of  transport  in- 
puts, 35,  79,  113-114,  222-223 

as  related  to  intensity  of  land  use,  194-195, 
244,  247-248,  271-273 

as  related  to  the  rent  function,  194-195, 
195n,    197,   201-205,   244 

basic  role  in  agricultural  location  theory, 
189-199 

effect    of,     on     commodity    flows,     215-219, 
283-285 
on  equipotential  contours,   66-67 
on     geographic     specialization,     215-219, 

282-285 
on   industrial  location,   215-219,   282-285 
on  levels   of  consumption,   214-219 
on  market  area  size,  271-273,  274n 
on  price  of  urban  land,  200 
on  sales   volume,   200-201 
on  trade,  215-219,  282-285 
on  urban  land  use,  200,  271,  280,  282-285 

emphasis  on,  in  Weberian  doctrine  by  as- 
sumption of  constant  weights,  96 

impact  on  urban-metropolitan  structure, 
11,  68-70,  270-286 

impact  on  trade  and  location  in  simplified 
case,  210-219,  282-283 

implications  of  rank-size  findings  for  regu- 
larities  associated  with,   57-60 

introduction  of,  into  trade  theory,  211-219, 
281-282 

migration  and  the  intervening  opportuni- 
ties hypothesis,  64n-65n 

need  to  consider,  in  calculating  opportunity 
costs,   211-212,   281-282 
to    fuse    trade    and    location    theory,    209, 
281 

need  to  develop  gravity  models  to  handle 
more  adequately,   209 

neglect  of,  in  trade  theory,  209,  215n 

sketches  of  effect  of,  284-285 

substitution  between,  and  transport-orien- 
tation,  96-112,   222-230 

transformation  line  between,  locational 
shifts   associated   with   shifts   of,    116 

transformation    relations    between,    96-112, 
222-223 
as  embraced  by  relations  between  trans- 
port inputs,   114-119,  222-223 

transport  cost  restraints  on  variation  in, 
in  the  locational  polygon  case,  98- 
101,   lOln 

value  of,  as  restrained  by  spatial  trans- 
formation   function,    223-230 

variations  in,  as  derived  from  transforma- 
tion relations  between  transport  in- 
puts, 96 

variation   of,    as   yielding   profit   maximiza- 
tion in  locational  polygon  case,  226- 
230 
as   yielding   profit   maximization   in   loca- 
tional triangle  case,  222-226 

see  also  Distance  ;   Space 
Dominant  weight,  and  non-existence  of  Laun- 
hardt-Palander    construction,    258n 


304 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Dominant  weight — continued 

and  non-existence  of  weight  triangle,   120- 

121,  258n 
definition  of,   120,  225n 
Dunn,    and    graphic    analysis    under   assump- 
tions   of    changing    yields    and    unit 

costs,  244n 
and     non-operational     general     equilibrium 

statement  for  agriculture,  243n 
concept  of  industry  rent  function,  195n 
constant    unit    cost    on    farm    in    algebraic 

statement  of,   244,    244n,    247 
proper  determination   of  rent,   192-194 
proper  procedure  to  determine  equilibrium 

of  farm  enterprise,  192-194,  247 
yield    per   acre   as    invariant   with   distance 

from  city  in   algebraic  statement  of, 

244,  244n,  247 
Dynamics,  in  general  location  theory,  54 
in   Weigmann's   location   theory,   38-41 

Economic    evolution,    see    Development   proc- 
esses 
Economic  processes,  see  Production  processes 
Economies    of   scale,    addition    to    Launhardt- 
Palander  construction,  265-267 

and  boundary  changes  in  Launhardt-Pa- 
lander  model,  266-267 

and  emergence  of  different  sizes  of  cities, 
57-58 

and  extent  of  market  areas,  58,  148-151, 
153,   173-174 

and  graduation  of  transport  rate  structure, 
105 

and   hierarchy  of  cities,   57-58 

and  integration  of  power  system,  185 

and  length  of  commodity  flows,  58 

and  management  diseconomies,   185n 

and  national  commodities,   58 

and  shifts,  fi-om  transport  optimum  point, 
175n-176n 
to  labor  locations,    175n-176n 
to    power   locations,    175n-176n 

and  social  welfare  from  production  con- 
centration,  174 

as  a  basic  location  variable,  135n,  175-176 

as  a  basis  for  trade,  17 

as  affected  by  the  market  variable,  175n- 
176n 

as  affecting  type  of  orientation,   175n-176n 

as  basic  to  Losch's  market  area  system,  44, 
150-151,   153,   174,   267 

as  eliminating  pole  line  producers,  265-266 

as  embraced  by  production  theory,   176 

as  embraced  in  the  substitution  principle, 
95n,    135n,    173-176,   265-266 

as  included  in  agglomeration  economies, 
139,  172,  265 

as  involving  substitution  between  transport 
and  production  outlays,  174,  265,  267 

as  overlapping  with  localization  economies, 
182n,  265 

as  reducing  number  of  market-oriented  pro- 
ducers in  Launhardt-Palander  model, 
266 

as  reflected  in  net  economy  curves,  186-187 

as  related  to  number  and  spread  of  plants 
via  general  location  principle,  252- 
253 

as  requiring  market  areas  in  Launhardt- 
Palander  model,  266-267 

definition  of,  172 


Economies    of   scale — continued 

effect  of,  on  sources  of  raw  materials,  175n- 
176n 
on  structure  of  space-economy,   265-267 
on    substitution    between    transport    out- 
lays in  different  directions,  175n-176n 
geographic  specialization  resulting  from,   5 
graphic  case  of   impact  of,  265-267 
in   Ohlin's  doctrine,   52 

in   power  generation,   effect   on   per   capita 
consumption,   185n 
and   size   of   city,    184-185 
and  urbanization  economies,   184-185 
in    the    location    of    intermediary   establish- 
ments,  175n 
in  the  location  of  marketing  establishments, 

175n 
incorporation  in  sketches  of  fused  location- 
market-trade    doctrine,    256-285 
introduction  into  transport-orientation-mar- 
ket area  framework,  265-267 
localization  economies  as,   with  multi-plant 

firms,   179n 
locational  shifts  from,  173-176,  265-267 
use  of   iso-outlay  lines   in   analysis   of,   174, 

265 
use  of  outlay-substitution  lines   in  analysis 

of,   174,  265 
variation  of  substitution  points  with,   175- 

176,   175n-176n,   265-266 
with  urban   size,   hypothetical,    186-187 
Educational  services  as  basic  urban  industry, 

274n-275n 
Empirical   inquiry,   value   of,   for   theory,    55, 

77 
Enclave (s),    as    an    agricultural    hinterland, 
276n,   277 
in  agricultural  land  use  patterns,  3 
of   excluded    consumers    because   of   income 
and   taste   differences,    145-146 
End  point  solution,  see  Equilibrium  point,  as 

an  end  point 
Energy  resources,  controlling  role  of,  31n 

see  also  Natural  resources 
Englander,  and  fusion  of  market  area  analy- 
sis and  industrial  location,   143n 
and  the  evolutionary  approach,  15,  29n-30n 
and  the  general  theory  of  "local  condition- 

ality,"  31,  31n-32n,  160 
classification  of  commodities,  31n-32n 
conception  of  immobile  commodities,  94 
criticism  of  classical  trade  theory,   208 
criticism   of   Weber's    agglomeration   analy- 
sis,  180 
emphasis   on   inherited   physical   structures, 

180 
emphasis  on  relocation  costs  in  agglomera- 
tion process,   180 
failure  to  consider  simultaneous   price  and 
location  variations,   160 
England,   effect   of   international   position   of, 

on   theory,   27 
Enke,    generalization   of   his   analog   solution, 
168n 
spatial   equilibrium   problem   of,    167n 

as     a     general     transportation     problem, 

167n-168n 
as  containing  the  Koopmans  transporta- 
tion   problem,    168n 
as  encompassing  the  scale  variable,   168n 
as  excluding  the   basic  location  problem, 
168n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


305 


Environment,  physical,   adaptation  of  human 
beings  to,   68-70 
and  economic  evolution,   1-2,  6,   12 
as  a  factor  in  spatial  price  discrimination, 

164n 
as  restraining  urban  land  use  patterns,  206 
conditions  of,  and  bearing  on  labor  orienta- 
tion, 141 
effect  of,  on   agglomeration  economies,   140 
on   urban   transit   network,    185-187 
on    weighting    of    net    economy    curves, 
186-187 
in  relation  to  transport  technology,   12 
locational  effect  of  changes   in,   1 
non-uniform,    and    non-circularity    of    mar- 
ket areas,   145-146 
see  also  Natural  resources  ;  Topography 
Equalizing     differences     in     labor     costs,     see 
Labor  costs,  equalizing  differences  in 
Equations,  Losch's  system  of,  47 

system  of,  and  sets  of  spatial  co-ordinates, 
54 
and   transport   inputs,   54,   222-253 
in  a  general  location  theory,   54,   222-253 
Equilateral    triangles,    as    inferior    to   regular 
hexagons   as   market   forms,    44,    153, 
242 
as  satisfying  boundary  conditions,   153,  242 
in  Losch  scheme,   44,   153,   241-242 
Equilibrium  conditions,   for  agricultural  land 
use,   see  Agricultural  land  use 
for  farm  enterprise,  see  Firm,  agricultural 
for  industrial  firm  location,  see  Equilibrium 
point    (for  firm  location)  ;  Firm,  in- 
dustrial 
for  market  areas,  see  Losch  (location  theory 

of)  ;  Market  area  analysis 
for  trade,  see  Trade 

for  urban  land  use,  see  Urban  land  use 
Equilibrium  point    (for  firm  location),  alter- 
native   ways    of    derivation,    119-124, 
224-230 
and  comparison  of  relative  minimum  points, 

108,    108n,    124n,    229-230 
and    diminishing    marginal    rate    of   substi- 
tution     between      transport      inputs, 
116 
and    the    convexity    of    the    transformation 

line,   116 
and   the   marginal  rate   of  substitution   be- 
tween transport  inputs,  116-119,  222- 
230 
angle    conditions    for    corner   location,    122, 

257 
as   a   minimum   transport   cost   point,    122- 

124,  224-230 
as  a  saddle  point  in  game  theory,   166 
as   an   equilibrium   point  of  forces    (Varig- 

non),   121-122,  225-227 
as    corner    of    the    locational   polygon,    107- 

112,   122,   224-227,   230 
as   corner  when   forces   at  equilibrium   out- 
side  triangle,    122,    224-227 
as  end   point,   because  of  convex  iso-outlay 
lines,   107-112,   120 
because  of  graduated  rates,   107-112,   120 
because   of   large   first  zone  charge,    107- 

112,  230 
because  of  tails  on  iso-outlay  lines,   107- 

112 
conditions     for,     107-108,     122,     224-227, 
230 


Equilibrium    point — continued 

as  intermediate  location,  minor  importance 

of,   108,   113n,  230n 
as   trough   of   transport   cost  surface,    122- 

124,  224-230 
as  yielded  by  the  general  location  principle, 

222-253 
at  a  cheap  capital  site,  as  involving  further 
substitutions,   133 
determination  of,   133 
at  a   cheap   material  source,   determination 

of,  133 
at  a  cheap  labor  site,  as  involving  further 
substitutions,    130,    196 
formal   conditions   for,    129-130 
graphic  determination  of,   129-131 
at  a  cheap  power  site,  as  involving  further 

substitutions,   132 
at  a  higher-price  market,  determination  of, 

134-135 
change    in,    with   use   of   continuous   trans- 
formation  curve,    115n 
determination  of,  and  substitution  between 
groups   of  transport  inputs,   227-228 
as  labor  orientation,   129-131,   196 
as   power   orientation,    131-132 
by  the   isodapane  technique,   122-124 
by  use  of  weight  triangle,   121-122,   256- 

258 
from   differentials   in   revenue  potentials, 

159 
when   firm  influences  prices,   159-171 
when  no  competitive  reactions,   159 
with  competitive  reactions,  160-171,  264- 

265 
with  economies   of  scale,    173-176 
with     irregular    price-ratio     lines,     llOn, 

113n 
with    iso-outlay   lines,    129-137,    159,    170, 

174 
with     iso-revenue-less-outlay     lines,     134- 

135,   159,   170,   175 
with     Launhai-dt-Palander     construction, 

256-269 
with    outlay-substitution    lines,     129-137, 

159,  170,   174.   175 
with    revenue-outlay     substitution     lines, 

134-135,    159,    170.    175 
with   variations   in   transport  rates.   112 
difficulties  in  determining,  under  oligopoly, 

160-171,     264-265 
direct   determination    by   cost   comparisons, 

137,   140n,   230 
effect  on,   of  back  hauls,   113n 

of  breaks  in  transport  network,  110-112, 
230 
feasibility  of  labor  location  as.  and  critical 

isodapane.   130-131 
feasibility  of  power  location  as,   and  criti- 
cal isodapane,   132 
fuU,    change    in,    with    change    in    relative 
weights,   104 
conditions    for,    103-104,    104n,    108,    116, 

117.    123-124,   222-239 
process     of     attainment.     103-104.     104n, 
123-124.     135-137.     137n.     159,     170, 
174,   175 
possibility    of    multiple    solutions,     130n, 

230 
via  use  of  subset  isodapanes,    123-124 
with    realistic    rate    structures,     105-112, 
229-230 


306 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Equilibrium    point — continued 

minor  indeterminacy  of,  from  realistic  rate 

structures,  107n 
need  to  consider  all  variables  in  determina- 
tion  of,    185-137 
partial,  change  in,  with  change  in  relative 
weights,   104 
conditions    for,    102-104,    123-124,    135n, 

137n 
conditions    for,    in    mathematical    terms, 
103n 
similarity    with    conditions    in    produc- 
tion theory,   118 
first-order   condition   for,    116 
inadequacy  of,   135 
second-order      (stability)     condition     for, 

116 
twin  solutions,  possibility  of,   103n 
via  use  of  subset  isodapanes,   123-124 
with   realistic   rate   structures,    105-112 
shortcut    determination    by    pole    principle, 

122 
see  also  Competitive  locational  equilibrium  ; 
Firm,   agricultural ;   General  location 
principle 
Evolutionary  approach,  as  sequences  of  loca- 
tional  structures,   30 
Englander's   contribution,   29n-30n 
limitations   and   virtues   of,   30 
need  for,  in  urbanization  analysis,   183 
required  in   agglomeration  analysis,   180 
Ritschl's    contribution,    30n 
to  general  location   theory,   15,   28-30,   31n, 

54 
Weber's  contribution,   15,  27-30 
Excess  supply  functions,  potential  use  of,  to 

solve  the  location  problem,  168n 
Exchange,  see  Trade 

Exchange  ratios,  as  affected  by  distance,  215n 
as  affected  by  transport  cost,  215n,  217 
in  a  simple  three  country  case,  212-219 
need  to  specify  demand  to  determine,  212 
Export  duties,  see  Import-export  duties 
Exports,  see  Commodity  flows  ;  Trade 
External   economies,    see    Localization    econo- 
mies ;   Urbanization   economies 

Factor    costs,    differentials    in,    and    need    to 
substitute  between   outlays,    126-127 
as  a  location  factor,  126-137,   189-190 
as  bearing  upon  land  use  patterns,  199n, 

275 
as    contained    in   the   substitution   frame- 
work,  199n 
as   excluded   in   Launhardt-Palander   con- 
struction, 256 
as     recognized     in     agricultural     location 
theory,   199n 
see   also  Costs  ;   Labor   costs ;   Power,   costs 
of  ;   Prices  ;   Transport  costs 
Factors,    classification    of,    and   transport   in- 
puts, 89-90,  119n 
Englander's  classification  of,  31n-32n 
geographic     distribution     of,     and     general 
equilibrium  theory,  32-33 
and  location,  32-33 
in  terms  of  use-units,  34-35 
immobility  of,  in  international  setting,  283 

and  limited  competition,  37-38 
immobility     of     groups     of,     and     location 

theory,  41 
local   differences    in   supply   of,    52,    52n 


Factors — continued 

market  structure  of,   40-41 
mobility  of,  and  Ohlin's  concepts  of  regions, 
51,  52n 
effect  of  political  variable  on,   283 
effect   on  geographic  specialization,   282- 

285 
effect  on  structure  of  industrial  districts, 

282-285 
effect  on  trade,   282-285 
effect    on    urban-metropolitan    structure, 

282-285 
effect  on  urban  land  use,  282-285 
intranationally,   283 
perfect  mobility  of,  33,  53 
prices  of  types  of,   86 

proportions     of,     and     interrelations     with 
rent,    192-194,    275 
and   substitution   principle,    95n,    275 
as  affected  by  distance  variable,  275 
as  affected  by  location  of  farm,   194-195, 

275 
as  affected  by  net  farm  price,   194-195 
as  affected  by  price  of  land  inputs,  275 
as  related  to  farm  output,  190-194,  275 
as  related  to  intensity  of  land  use,   194- 
195 
services  of,  as  incorporated  in  transport  in- 
puts, 79 
Factory  prices,   differences   in,   and   effect  on 
market    areas    of    competing    firms, 
146-147,  239 
Farm   enterprise,   see   Firm,   agricultural 
Fetter,    fixed    firm    locations    in    market   area 
analysis,  160 
market  area  theory  of,   as  yielded  by  gen- 
eral location   principle,   239 
Fictitious   distance,   see  Distance,    fictitious 
Firm    (agricultural),    adjustments   of,    as   re- 
flected  in   rent  function,   197,   276 
when  multiple  markets,   198-199,  276 
analysis  of,   and   industry  analysis,   case  of 
meaningless  distinction  between,  247n 
as    industry    analysis     in    extreme    case, 
248 
and   aggregative  analysis,   need  to  consider 
changes     in     land     use     intensity    to 
unify,  247-248 
need  to  consider  changes  in  unit  cost  to 
unify,   247-248 
and  crop  changes  as  involving  substitution, 

197,  276 
and   industrial,   analysis   of   differentials   as 
common   to   both,    189-190,    196,    199, 
275 
as  forced   into  efficient  operations  by  com- 
petition,  197-199 
behavior  of,   as   if  having  complete  knowl- 
edge,  196-197 
determination    of   equilibrium   output,    190- 

194 
determination    of   rent   payments   for,    190- 

194 
effect   of   locational   position    of,    on    factor 
proportions,    194-195,   275 
on  farm  operations,   194-195,   275 
on  intensity  of  land  use,  194-195 
on  net  farm  price,   194-195 
on  rent,  194-195,  275 
equilibrium  of,  analysis  for  in  an  improved 
agricultural  location  theory,  198-199, 
275-276 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


307 


Firm     (agricultural) — continued 

analysis  for,  when  crop  combination  con- 
sidered,  199,   248 
and  equality  of  net  farm  price  and  mar- 
ginal costs,   190-191 
and  substitution  between  land  inputs  and 

other  inputs,    193,   196,   275 
and  substitution  between  rent  outlays  and 

other  outlays,  193,  196,  275 
as  a  condition  for  optimum  land  use  pat- 
terns.   198-199,    275-276 
many  substitution  paths  to,   193n-194n 
importance   of   internal   spatial   dimensions 

of,   189-190 
indifference   to   location    within    rent   yield- 
ing  hinterland,    196-197 
location  of,  and  substitution  between  trans- 
port and  rent  outlays,   189-190,   196, 
196n,  275 
interrelation    with    diverse    factors,    190- 
199 
operations  of,  as  affected  by  resource  con- 
tent of  land,  194,  194n,  275 
as  affected  by  taxes,  194,  194n 
as  affected  by  transport  routes,   194 
output  of,  as  related  to  distance  from  mar- 
ket,  190-194,  275 
as  related  to  factor  proportions,  190-194, 

275 
as  related  to  market  price,  190-194 
as  related  to  production  costs,  190-194 
as  related  to  transport  cost,   190-194 
if  rent  were  zero,  190-191 
profits  of,  conditions  for,  192-194 
if  rent  were  zero,   190-191 
procedure  in  determining,   190-194 
use    of    iso-product    curves   to   determine, 

191-194 
use  of  price-ratio  lines  to  determine,  192- 

194 
use  of  scale  lines  to  determine,  191-194 
rent    differentials    as    basic    in    location    of, 

189-190,  194-199,  275 
shift  of,  and  substitution  between  rent  out- 
lays    and     other     outlays,      195-196, 
196n 
see  also  Agricultural  land  use  ;  Agricultural 
location  theory 
Firm   (industrial),  analysis  of,  as  interrelated 
with    regional     analysis,     159n-160n, 
199 
and  agricultural,  analysis  of  differentials  as 
common   to   both,    189-190,    196,    199, 
275 
as  equal  in  size  in  Losch,  240 
as    restrained    by    spatial    transformation 

function,  223-253 
assumption  of  negligible  influence  on  price 

as  invalid,  158,  265 
definition  of,  91n 

differential  bargaining  abilities  in   agglom- 
eration,  180-181,   181n 
in    multifirm     market-supply    area    frame- 
work, 235-243 
interdependence  of,  in  Triflin's  theory,  50n 
labor   oriented   equilibrium,    127-131 
localization  problem  of,  in  multi-plant  case, 

179,   179n 
location   analysis   of,   as  a  level  of  inquiry, 
92,   188-189 
as    interrelated    with    aggregative    analy- 
sis.  93.   189,   198,   199,  248 


Firm     (industrial) — continued 

location  of,  and  differentials  in  net  revenue 
potentials,   159 
and    effect   upon    regional   income,    159n- 

160n 
and    substitution    between    distance   vari- 
ables, 96-112,  222-230 
and    substitution    between    transport    in- 
puts,   112-124,    222-230 
as  affected  by  regional  income,  159n-160n 
effect    of    agglomeration     economies     on, 

173-188 
effect  of  economies  of  scale  on,   173-176 
effect  of  localization  economies  on,   176- 

182 
effect  of  raw  material  supplies  on,  175n- 

176n 
effect  of  urbanization  economies  on,  182- 

188 
in  line  case,  95-97,   117,   119-120 
in    polygon    case,    98-101,     117,    122-124, 

226-230 
in  triangle  case,  97-98,  101-119,  120-122, 

222-226 
under    competitive   reactions,    160-171 
under   different   spatial   pricing   systems, 
158-171 
location   of,    use   of   total   cost   comparisons 
to  determine,   137,   137n,  230 
when  no  competitive  reaction,   159 
with   finite   number   of   transport   routes, 

101-112,  255 
with  influence  on  price,   158-171 
with    realistic   transport    rate    structures, 
104-112,  229-230,   255 
location    situations    of,    with    negligible    in- 
fluence on  price,  158 
location   theory  for,   as   comparable  to  that 
for    agricultural    firm,    189-190,    199, 
275 
multiplant,  transport  inputs  within,  91n 
optimum  size  of,  as  affected  by  spatial  dis- 
tribution  of  market,   175n-176n 
as  affected  by  spatial  distribution  of  ma- 
terial sources,    175n-176n 
other   forms    of   orientation,    131-137 
possibility    of    location    at    source    of    pure 

material,   121-122,  225n 
power  oriented   equilibrium,    132 
significance   of   rent   differentials   for,    189- 

190,   199 
sloping  demand  curve  of,  because  of  space, 

158-159 
transport-oriented  equilibrium,  91-125,  222- 

230 
with    market    areas    and    supply    areas    as 

variables,   231-235 
see  also  Competitive  locational  equilibrium  ; 
Equilibrium    point     (for    firm    loca- 
tion) 
Firm   (urban,  commercial),  analysis  of,  value 
of   substitution   framework   for,   205- 
206,  280 
determination  of  equilibrium  location,  200- 

206 
determination     of     equilibrium     operations, 

200-206 
see  also  Urban  land  use 
Fixed     proportions,     see    Commodities,     fixed 

proportions  of 
Flow    phenomena,    stability    of,    and    general 
location  theory,  22 


308 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Flows,  see  Commodity  flows :  Population 
flows 

Food,  as  a  raw  material  in  transport-orienta- 
tion, 127n-128n 
transport    costs    on,    and    equalizing   differ- 
ences in   labor  costs,   127n,   lS9n 

Footloose    industry,    growth    of,    and    cheap 
labor,  8-9 
locational   tie  to  basic   industry,   8-9 

Force   of   Diversification,    and   stable   interac- 
tions over  distance,  60 
use  of,  to  explain  spatial  framework,  78n- 
79n 

Force  of  Unification,   and  stable  interactions 
over  distance,  60 
effect  of   technological  advance  on,   79n 
use  of,  to  explain  spatial  framework,  78n- 
79n 

Formkoeffizient  as  a  technical  concept,  36n 

France,   cities  in,   rank-size  findings  for,   57n 

Friction  of  distance,  see  Distance ;  Distance 
variable 

Furlan,    criticism    of    classical    trade    theory, 
208 
his  attempt  at  general  location  theory,  31n 

Fusion  of  location-market-production  theories 
via  general  location  principle,  221- 
253,  286 

Fusion  of  location-market-trade  doctrines  via 
sketches.  256-286 

Game  theory,  and  a  saddle-point  solution,  166 

and  complications  of  different  size  agglom- 
eration units,  180-181 

and    difficulties    of    converting    localization 
into   a    constant-sum   game,    181n 

and  rational  behavior,   160,   166,   265,   286 

and   the  use   of   mixed  strategies,   166 

and  types  of  strategy,   166 

as  pertaining  to  situations  of  interest  con- 
flict,  165-166 

basic  elements  of,   166-167 

coalition  problem  of,  as  complicated  by  re- 
location costs,   180-181 

conceptual  complications  of,  167 

difficulties  in  use  of,  from  non-symmetrical 
location  factors,   ISln 

need  to  develop  for  agglomeration  analysis, 
180,  286 

overemphasis    of    interdependence    of    reac- 
tions in  a  spatial  setting,   167 

postulate     of     complete     information,     166, 
166n 

postulate    of    precise    value     of    outcomes, 
166 

postulate  of  transferability  of  utility,   166 

postulate  of  well  specified  variables,   166 

present    inadequacy    for    location    analysis, 
160,  265 

problems  of  empirical  verification,   167 

relevance  for  location   equilibrium   problem 
of  firm,    165-166,    170,   265,   286 

unrealities   of  postulates,   167 

use  of,   for  a  firm  and  coalition   of  rivals, 
166 
in  agglomeration  analysis,  180-181,  181n 

use  of  relocation  costs  with,   180-181,   ISln 

virtues  and  limitations,   165-167,  265 
General    equilibrium    theory,     and    a    dimen- 
sionless   economy,   25-26 

and  the  geographic  distribution  of  factors, 
32-33 


General     equilibrium     theory — continued 

and   the   siibstitution   principle,   32-35 

and  Triffin's  revision  of  monopolistic  com- 
petition  theory,    50,    50n 

as  a  special  case  of  a  general  theory  of 
location  and  space-economy,  26-27, 
33,   36,    53,    254 

as  including  general  location  theory,  32-33, 
35 

dependence  on  premise  of  pure  competition, 
43 

dynamical   stability   properties,    43n 

emphasis  on  a  one-point  economy,  25-27, 
33,  42 

feasibility  of  introducing  local  price  dif- 
ferences into,  42 

feasibility  of  introducing  transport  cost 
into,  42 

Hicksian  formulation,  25-26 

inapplicability   to   space-economy,    42-43 

inconsistency    of     pure    competition     and 
transport  cost,  43 

limitations    of   static   framework,    43 

Mosak's  trade  formulation,  26 

neglect   of   space   in,   25-27,   33,   42,   53 

Ohlin's  use  of,   in  location  theory,   51 

transport   cost   as   zero,   26,    33,   42,    53 

use   of,   in   Gestalt   analysis,   38 
General   location    principle,    and    the   assump- 
tion  of   profit   maximization,    221n 

as  a  core  element  of  a  general  location 
theory,   222,   252,   286 

as  applicable  to  agricultural  location  with 
raw  material  supply  areas,  248-249, 
252 

as  applicable  to  situation  with  both  supply 
and  market   areas,   235,   238 

as  fusing  various  location  and  market  theo- 
ries, 222-253 

as    implying   concentric   zones,   244-246 

as  implying  various  existing  location  theo- 
ries,  222-253,   286 

as  involving  marginal  rate  of  substitution 
between  transport  inputs,  224-253, 
286 

as  involving  ratios  of  transport  rates,  224 

as  involving  the  substitution  principle,  224- 
253,  286 

as  permitting  a  generalized  transport- 
orientation,  226-230,  252 

as  permitting  a  more  generalized  agricul- 
tural location  theory,  252 

as  permitting  a  more  generalized  Losch 
scheme,  252 

as  relating  scale  economies  and  number 
and  spread  of  plants,  252-253 

as  relating  spatial  extent  and  capital  in- 
tensity   of    production,    252-253 

as  yielding  agricultural  location  theory, 
243-251,  252,  286 

as  yielding  equilibrium  point  of  firm,  222- 
253 

as  yielding  Losch  market  area  theory,  240- 
242,  252,  286 

as  yielding  market  boundary  conditions, 
239.  252 

as  yielding  supply  area  analysis,  235,  238. 
252,  286 

as  yielding  traditional  market  area  theory. 
239,  252,  286 

as  yielding  transport-orientation,  222-230, 
252,  252n.  286 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


309 


General    location    principle — continued 

form    of,    as    unchanging    with    concept    of 
social  surplus,  234-235 

general  statement  of,  252,  286 

need    of    a    multicommodity    framework    to 
apply  to  agricultural  location,  243 

pervasiveness   of,    221,    286 

statement  of,  for  agricultural  location  prob- 
lem.  246 
for  locational  polygon   case,   227 
for  simple  Weberian  triangle  case,  224 
for  single  firm  market  area  case,  233 
for     two     groups     of     transport     inputs, 

228 
in  multifirm,  varying  unit  cost  case,  238 
which  fuses  transport-orientation,  market 

and    supply    area    analysis,    239 
with  realistic  rate  structures,  230 

use  to  fuse  location-market-production  the- 
ories,  222-253,   286 
General  location  theory,  and  aggregative  anal- 
ysis, 21 

and  concept  of  basic  form,  38-42 

and  disaggregation   of  industries,   21 

and   geographic  distribution   of  inputs   and 
outputs,   27,   53 

and    geographic    variations    in    prices    and 
costs,  27,  53 

and    Gestalt   analysis,    38-42,    54 

and    individual    and    group    space    prefer- 
ences, 22-23 

and    interindustry   linkage,    20-21 

and   interregional  analysis,   21-22 

and  interrelations  of  various  location  theo- 
ries, 23 

and  principle  of  limited  competition,  37-38 

and   production    stage   analysis,    19-21 

and   stability   of  spatial  flows,   22 

and  statics  and  dynamics,  39-41 

and  structure  of  market,  39-41 

and  the  assumption  of  profit  maximization, 
22  In 

and    the    principle    of    substitution,    32-36, 
54,  221 

as  a  dynamic  theory,   38-41,   54 

as  a  synthesis  of  partial  location  theories, 
91,    221-253,    254-287 

as  a  system  of  market  nets,  44-48 

as  broader  than  MarshaUian  doctrine,  254 

as  capable  of  yielding  specific  location  theo- 
ries, 91,   252 

as  containing  urban  land  use  theory,   205- 
206 

as     embracing     narrowly     conceived     trade 
theory.  53-54,  208 

as   included   in   general  equilibrium   theory, 
32-33,  35 

as    incorporating    Weber    and    Thiinen    in 
one   framework,    92-93,    252-253,    286 

as    transportation    theory,    22,    213n,    221n- 
222n,  286 

as    yielding    transport-orientation    via    spe- 
cific assumptions,  252n 

conception   of,   26-27,   53-54,   254 

Englander's   contribution  to,   29n,   31,   31n- 
32n 

equivalence  with  broadly  conceived  monop- 
olistic competition  theory,  50,  54,  254 

evolutionary  approach  to,  15,  28-30,  31n,  54 

Furlan's  attempt  at.  Sin 

general  equilibrium  theory  as  a  special  case 
of,  26-27,  38,  86,  58,  254 


General  location  theory — continued 

general    location    principle    as    a    core    ele- 
ment in,  222,  252,  286 
German  contributions  to,  27 
inadequacy  of  existing,  207 
limitations  of  Losch's  system,  48,  48n,  49 
Losch  approach  plus  Thunen,  15-16 
Losch's  contribution  to,  43-50 
need  for,  9-15,  31,  75,  93 
need     for     complete     transport-orientation 

framework,   113 
need  for  multicommodity  framework  in,  to 
encompass   agricultural  location   the- 
ory, 243 
need    for,    in    urban-metropolitan    analysis, 

201n 
need  to  consider  aggregate  regional  demand 

and  income,  207 
neglect  of,  by  classical  school,   27 
Ohlin's  contribution   to,   51,   53,   208 
Palander's   contribution   to,   42-43 
Palander's   skepticism   of,    42-43 
possible  approaches  to,   15-23 
Predohl's  contribution  to,  32-36 
Ritschl's  contribution  to,   3  On 
synonymous    with    broadly    conceived    trade 

theory,    53,    54,    254 
Thiinen  and  basic  methodology,  27-28 
Thiinen    approach   plus    Losch   and   Weber, 

16-19 
value  of  a  system  of  equations,  42 
value  of  empirical  study  for,  36n-37n 
value  of  input-output  analysis  for,  49 
value    of    monopolistic    competition    frame- 
work,  27n,   37-38,   49-50 
value  of  price-cost  analysis  for,  49-50 
value  of  Weberian  theory  for,  36n-37n 
Weber's  contribution  to,  27-30 
Weigmann's    contribution   to,    37-42,    54 
see  also  Location   theory 
General  theory  of  location,  see  General  loca- 
tion theory 
General    theory    of    space-economy,    see    Gen- 
eral    location     theory ;     Space-econo- 
my 
Generalized    index,    and    existence    of    weight 
triangle,   121 
definition  of,   121 
Geographic      balance,      and      decentralization 
policy,   14 
and  vulnerability,   14 
Geographic  immobility,  see  Immobilities 
Geographic  inequalities  of  resources,  see  Nat- 
ural   resources,    geographic    inequali- 
ties of 
Geographic  shifts,  see  Locational  shifts 
Geographic    specialization,    among    metropol- 
itan regions,   12,   17-18 
and  uneven  resource  endowment,  5 
as  affected  by  factor  mobility,   282-285 
as  affecting  structure  of  industrial  districts, 

282-285 
as  dictated  by  rent  functions,  197-199 
as  related  to  urban  land  use,  282-285 
as  related  to  urban-metropolitan  structure, 

282-285 
changes  in,  and  advance  in  transport  tech- 
nology, 22 
effect    of    change    in    distance    variable    on, 

215-219,  283-285 
in  a  simple  three  country  trade-location  ex- 
ample, 213-219,  282-285 


310 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Geographic    specialization — continued 

increase   in,    from   a   fall  in   the   transport 
rate,  87 
German    Historical    School,    contributions    to 
Raumwirtschaft,   27 
study  of  development  stages,  27,  28n 
German   National   Bureau   of   Statistics,   as   a 
source  of  international  flow  data,  73- 
75 
Germany,   cities,  rank-size  findings  for,   57n 

South,  pattern  of  settlements  in,  60n 
Gestalt   analysis,    and    the   structure   of   mar- 
kets, 39-42 
use  of,  by  Weigmann,  38-42 

in  a  dynamic  general  location  theory,  54 
Government  subsidy,  and  aircraft,   12 
and  atomic  energy,  13 
and  optimum  transport  network,   9 
distribution  among  areas,  9 
Governmental    activities    as    basic    urban    in- 
dustry, 274n-275n 
Graduated     transport     rate     structures,     see 
Transport  rate  structures,  graduated 
Graham's    trade    theory,    appeal    of,    to    loca- 
tion theorists,  210 
as   long-run   doctrine,   209-218 
emphasis  of,  on  supply  and  cost  conditions, 

210 
fusion  of,  with  location  theory,  210-219 
multicountry,  multicommodity  approach  of, 

210 
neglect  of  transport-orientation  in,   210 
relative  neglect  of  transport  cost  in,  210 
Gravity    models,    as    an    element    of    regional 
science,  287 
as   appropriate   for   short-run   trade  analy- 
sis, 209 
need   to   develop,   to   explain   location   more 
adequately,  209 
to  explain  trade  more  adequately,  209 
to    handle    distance    variable    more    ade- 
quately, 209 
to  study  structure  of  space-economy,  287 
to   synthesize  with   other  techniques,   287 
to  treat  substitution   in   the   large,   287 
Greenhut   and   integration   of   competitive   lo- 
cational    equilibrium    and    Weberian 
doctrine,   171n 
Gregarious    instinct,    and    pattern    of    settle- 
ment, 2 
and  space  preference,   84-85 
Gross  regional  product,   projection   of,   as  an 
element  of  regional  science,   287 
as  restraining  metropolitan  structure,  287 
need   to   synthesize   with    other   techniques, 

287 
use  of,  to  study  structure  of  space-economy, 
287 
to  treat  substitution  in  the  large,  287 
see  also  Income,  regional 
Groups,    social    and    economic,    space    prefer- 
ences of,  23 

Haberler  and  the  problem  of  fusing  trade  and 

location  theory,  220n 
Hexagons,  regular,  as  a  pure  theoretical  con- 
cept, 274n 
as    derived    through    substitution    principle, 

153,  240-242 
as    derived    when    Losch's    uniformity    as- 
sumptions used  in  Launhardt-Palan- 
der  model,  267 


Hexagons — continued 

as  inferior  to  distorted  circle  in  a  general 

case,  242n-243n 
as  precluded  in  realistic  market  area  analy- 
sis, 274n 
as  satisfying  boundary  conditions,  153,  241- 

242 
as  superior  to  squares   and  equilateral  tri- 
angles   as    market    forms,     44,     153, 
241-242 
as  the  ideal  market  form,  44,  153,  242,  242n 
distortion    of,    in    modified    Losch   diagram, 

271-273,  274n 
in   Losch  scheme,   44,   153,   241-242 
inconsistency  of,  with  resulting  population 

distribution,  153-154,  271 
Losch  diagram  of  system  of  nets  of,  270 
modification  of,  to  square  with  population 

distribution,  271-273 
size    of,    as    related   to    economies    of   scale, 
153,   174 
as  related  to  transport  costs,   153 
superimposition   of   nets   of,   and   hierarchy 
of  sites,   153-154,  270-271 
Hicksian   theory,    and    interrelations   of   mar- 
kets, 25 
and  the  general  equilibrium  problem,  25-26 
as    a   special   case    of    a   general   theory   of 

location  and  space-economy,  26-27 
emphasis    on    a    one-point   economy,    25-26, 

26n 
fii-st    and    second    order    equilibrium    condi- 
tions,  118 
rejection  of  monopolistic  competition,  26n 
transport  cost  as  zero,  26 
Hierarchy,  of  cities,   and  economies   of  scale, 
57-58 
and  regularity  of  flows  over  distance,  58- 

60 
Christaller's,  60n 
desirable  changes  in,   183 
optimum,   183 

use   of   transport   inputs   in   the   analysis 
of,  255 
of    city-regions,    and    commodity    classifica- 
tion, 18 
and    geographic    inequality    of   resources, 

18,  255 
as  related  to  new  basic  industry,  19,  19n 
as  related  to  transport  cost  level,  19n 
of  flows,  and  hierarchy  of  cities,  58-60 
and  spatial  patterning  of  cities,   58-60 
by  volume  and  length,  58 
of  focal  points,  as  characteristic  of  realis- 
tic space-economy,  230,  251,  273,  287 
as  related  to  a  multipunctured  transport 

cost  surface,  230,  251 
need  for  improved  analysis  of,  287 
of  industrial  districts,   in   an   urban-metro- 
politan sketch,  278-280 
localization   economies   within,   278-280 
of  interstitial  areas,   11,   183 
of  regions  and  spatial  substitution  in  input- 
output  analysis,  49 
of    sites,    and    inconsistency    of    uniformity 
assumptions,   153-154,   271 
as  related  to  transport  cost  level,   19n 
as  related  to  transport  network,  272-273 
desirable  changes  in,   183 
in  modified  Losch  analysis,  272-273 
in  Losch's  scheme,  17,  153-154,  270-271 
within  city,  12,  183.  272-273 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


311 


Hierarchy — continued 

within  urban-metropolitan  reRion,  11,  12, 
17,    183,   272-273 

of  trade  relations  among  rppions,   22 

of  trade  routes,  as  characteristic  of  space- 
economy,  251,  287 
as  related  to  transport  cost  level,  19n 

of    transport    routes,    need     for    improved 
analysis  of,  287 

of  urban  areas,  sketch  of  agricultural  hin- 
terlands  of,    276-278 

see  also  Rank-size  rule  for  cities 
Hinterland  (s),    agricultural,    as    affected    by 
resource  content  of  land,  276-277 
as  irregularly  bounded,  276-277 
boundaries   of   as  yielded   by  supply   area 

analysis,  276n 
sketch  of  for  urban-metropolitan  regions, 
276-278 

decline  of,   17-18 

demarcation  of,  16-17 

effect     of     geographic     inequalities     of     re- 
sources upon,   18 

expansion  of,   16-18,  78 

extent  of,  5-6,  17-18 

as    related    to    use    of    transport    inputs, 
81-82,  255 

of  city-regions,  3,  16-17,  276-278 

of   firms    in    competitive   locational   equilib- 
rium,  161-165 

of  metropolitan  region,  and  impact  of  dis- 
tance   upon,    68-70,  270-286 

of  towns   in   competitive  locational  equilib- 
rium,  161-165 

rent-yielding    and    the    indifference    of    the 
farm    enterprise   to    location    within, 
197 
Historical     approach,     see    Evolutionary     ap- 
proach 
Historical  inertia,  and  industrial  location,   10 

and   relocation,    14-15 
Hoover's  location   analysis,   and  categories   of 
commodities,  94n 

and    equalizing    differences    in    labor    costs 
and  transport-orientation,   127n-128n 

and  fusion  of  market  area  analysis  and  in- 
dustrial  location,    143n 

and  market  areas   for  two  producers,   148- 
151 

and  minor  importance  of  intermediate  loca- 
tion, 108 

and    spatial    price    discrimination    in    com- 
petitive  equilibrium,    164n 

and  the  likelihood  of  concentration   at  ini- 
tial location,   174n 

and  the  location  of  intermediary  establish- 
ments,  175n 

and    the    location    of    marketing    establish- 
ments,  175n 

and    the    simultaneous    existence    of    point, 
line,  and  areal  markets,   235-236 

and  the  use  of  margin  lines,  149-150,   154n 

classification    of    agglomeration    economies, 
172 

definition  of  isodapane,  122 

definition  of  localization  economies,  172 

definition  of  scale  economies,  172 

definition  of  urbanization  economies,   172 

emphasis  upon  cost  conditions,  210n 

modifications    of,    in    supply    area   analysis, 
155n-157n 

outline  of,  3  On 


Hoover's   location   analysis — continued 

patterns    of    markets,    with    constant    cost 

producers,  235-236 
relative   neglect  of   demand,   210n 
rent  surface  of,  as  identical  with  rent  func- 
tion,  195n 
use  of  isodapanes  for  transport-orientation 

solution,  122-124 
use  of  isotims  to  construct  isodapanes,  122- 
123 
Hotelling,   and   agglomeration   tendency,   162 
and     movement    along    the    revenue-outlay 

substitution  line,   170 
and   substitution   among   transport  outlays, 

170,  170n 
and    substitution    between    production    and 

transport    outlays,    170n 
and  the  Cournot  problem  when  firms  infini- 

tesimally  close,   161n 
assumption   of  simplified   line   case,    160 
locational  equilibrium  when  price  and  loca- 
tion   vary    simultaneously,    160-162 
solution  (s)    of,    as    borne    out   by    Zeuthen, 
160 
as  yielded  by  substitution  principle,   170, 

170n 
invalidity   of,    162-163,    163n 
stability  of,  161-162 
when  both  firms  mobile,   162 
when  no  undercutting,  160 
when  one  producer  immobilized,   160 
when  one  trades  autonomously,   160 
when   producers  undercut,   161-162 
when  production  costs  are  zero,   161 
undercutting    as    related    to    proximity    of 
producers,  161 
Human    ecology,    see   Agricultural   land   use ; 
Pattern    of    Settlement;    Space-econ- 
omy ;  Urban  land  use 
Human  resources,  geographic  inequalities  in, 
and  difficulty  for  Losch  theory,  48-49 
and  the  substitution  principle,  34-35 
and  variations  in  local  input  costs,   132- 

133 
as  ignored  in  competitive  locational  equi- 
librium   models,    169-170 
in  OhHn's  doctrine,  52 
significance  of,   19n 
uniform    distribution    of,    in    Losch   theory, 
44 
Hyperbolas,   as  market  boundaries,   146,  239, 
261 
as   supply   area   boundaries,    157 
Hypercircles,     as     market     area     boundaries, 
147n,  239 
as  supply  area  boundaries,   157 
Hyson,  definition  of  market  boundaries,  147n, 
239 
market  area  theory  of,  as  yielded  by  general 
location  principle,  239 

I.C.C.    data,    use    of,    to    measure    commodity 

fiows,  70-73 
Ideal  weights,  as  locational  forces  in  a  loca- 
tional triangle,   122 
conversion  of  actual  weights  into,  228 
use  of,  in  computing  locational  weight,  141 
to  adjust  for  commodity  rates,  109n,  120- 

122,  228 
to   consider   substitution   between   groups 
of   transport  inputs,   228 
valid  use  of,  by  Weber,   109n 


312 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Immobile    commodities,    as    goods    of    infinite 
weight  with  infinite  weight  loss,  32n, 
94 
Englander's   conception,   32n,   94 
in  a  commodity  classification,  93-94 
Immobilities,    and   cheap   labor,    128n 
and  Ohlin's  concept  of  region,  51 
and  secondary  labor,   128n 
and    substitution     possibilities     in     location 

analysis,  94 
and  the  locational  line  case,  96 
and  the  locational  triangle  case,   97 
and  Weigmann's   principle  of  Hmited  com- 
petition, 37-39 
as   affecting    industrial   location,    8 
as  an  element  in  general  location  theory,  27 
as  reflecting  relocation  costs,  283n 
basic  role  in   location  theory,   37-39 
effect   on   trade   and   geographic   specializa- 
tion,  283-285 
effect  on  urban-metropolitan  structure  and 

land  use,  283-285 
in  the  capital  goods  market,  41,  283,  283n 
in  the  classification  of  commodities,  93-94 
in  the  labor  market,  40-41,  283,  283n 
in  the  land  market,  40 

inadequacy  of  Classical  trade  theory  prem- 
ises on,  208 
of  individual  producers  in  agricultural  loca- 
tion theory,  93 
spatial,   in   Ohlin's  interdependence  system, 

51 
see  also  Factors,  mobility  of 
Imperfect      competition,      see      Competition ; 

Monopolistic  competition 
Import-export     duties,     effect     on     iso-outlay 
lines,   112 
possible  effect  on   equilibrium  point,    112 
Imports,   see   Trade ;   Commodity   flows 
Income,  effects,  differences  in,  from  different 
basic  industry,  284 
inequalities    of,    and    enclaves    of    excluded 
consumers,   146n 
and  noncircularity  of  market  areas,  145- 
146 
locational  effect  of  geographic  patterns  of, 

21 
regional    (urban),    as    it   affects    firm   loca- 
tion,  159n-160n 
as  restraining  urban  land  use,  206 
effect  of  basic  activities  on,   278 
effect  of   firm's  location   on,   159n-160n 
effect  on   commercial  and  service   activi- 
ties, 278 
effect  on   industries  using  ubiquities,   278 
need     to     consider     in     general     location 

theory,  207 
need  to  consider  in  trade  theory,  207 
need  to  study  relations  with  metropolitan 
structure,  287 
Increasing  cost  conditions,  market  area  anal- 
ysis  under,    149-154 
supply  area  analysis  under,   155-158 
Increasing    returns,    and    population    nuclea- 
tion,  2 
centripetal  effect  of,   4 
Indeterminacy,    in    locational    line    case,    119- 
120 
minor  degree  of,   from  realistic  rate  struc- 
tures,  107n 
of    competitive    equilibrium    as    related    to 
market  discontinuities,  165 


Indeterminacy — continued 

of  firm  location,  case  of,  with  scale  econo- 
mies,  174n 
of  firm  location   in   oligopolistic   situations, 

160-171 
of    locational    equilibrium    from   twin    solu- 
tions,  103n,   104n 
of    market    boundaries    from    discrete    con- 
sumer spread,   146n 
Index  of  labor  costs,  see  Labor,  costs  of 
India,  cities  in,  rank-size  findings  for,  57n 
Indispensability,  and  substitution  possibilities 
in  location  analysis,  94 
and  the  locational  line  case,  95-96 
and  the  locational  polygon  case,  98 
and  the  locational  triangle  case,  97 
in  the  classification  of  commodities,  93-94 
Industrial   aggregation,    see   Aggregation,   in- 
dustrial 
Industrial     complex     analysis,     see     Complex 

analysis 
Industrial  complexes  within  metropolitan  re- 
gions,  13-14 
Industrial  concentration,  see  Production,  con- 
centration of 
Industrial   decentralization,    see   Decentraliza- 
tion 
Industrial  disaggregation,  see  Disaggregation, 

industrial 
Industrial  districts,  a  structure  of,  consistent 
with  localization  economies,  278-280 
hierarchy     of,     in     an     urban-metropolitan 

sketch,  278-280 
structure  of,  as  related  to  distance  variable, 
282-285 
as  related  to  factor  mobility,   282-283 
as    related    to    geographic    specialization, 

282-285 
as  related  to  political  variable,  283-285 
as  related  to  trade,  282-285 
Industrial  land  use,  see  Urban  land  use 
Industrial    location,    aggregate    patterns    and 
agglomeration  economies,  21,  78n-79n 
and  decentralization  policy,  14-15 
effect  on,   of  aircraft,   12 
of  atomic  energy,   13 

of  breaks  in  transport  network,   110-112 
of  technological  advance,  7,  10,  12-13,  22, 
79n,  258-259 
effect  on  agricultural  location,   7-8 
use    of    activity    analysis    in    determining, 

168n-169n 
value  of  agricultural  location   analysis  for, 

189 
see    also     Industrial    structure ;     Location  ; 
Location  theory 
Industrial    stratum,    primary,    effect    on    sec- 
ondary industrial  stratum,  29 
relation  to  agricultural  stratum,  7,  29 
secondary,  composition  of,  29 

dependence    on    primary    industrial    stra- 
tum, 29 
Industrial  structure,   as   affecting   urban-met- 
ropolitan  structure,   284-285 
as   related  to  agricultural  stratum,   7,   29 
as   related   to   transport   network,   8 
impact  of  atomic  energy  upon,   13 
interrelations  within,  29 
of  nations,  as  affected  by  distance  variable, 

215-219,  282-285 
processes  in  development  of,  6-15 
sketches  of,  262-285 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


313 


Industrialization,   see   Basic    industry ;   Indus- 
trial structure 
Industry,    agricultural,   definition    of   by   city- 
region,  249 
basic,  see  Basic  industry 
classification  of,  Colin  Clark  type,  21 

Leontief  type,  21 
definition  of,  and  agglomeration  economies, 
92n 
and  monopolistic  competition,   92n 
in  location  analysis,  92,  92n 
location   analysis   of,   as  a  level  of   inquiry, 
92 
Inelasticities,   spatial,   as   an  element  in   gen- 
eral location  theory,  27,  37-38 
in  the  capital  goods  market,  41 
in   the  labor  market,   40-41 
in  the  land  market,  40 
see  also  Immobilities 
Innovation,   see   Technological   advance 
Input-output     analysis,     as     appropriate     for 
short-run  trade  doctrine,   209 
inclusion  of,  in  a  broadly  conceived  monop- 
olistic competition  theory,  50 
incorporation    into,    of   local   multiplier   ef- 
fects, 49 
of  locational  shifts,  49 
interregional,    as    an    element    of    regional 
science,  287 
need  to  synthesize  -with  other  techniques, 

287 
use  of  to  study  structure  of  space-econ- 
omy, 287 
use  of  to  treat  substitution  in  the  large, 
287 
limits  to  substitution  within,  49 
spatial    substitution    in,    via    bill    of    goods 
change,  49 
via     iterative     approach     and     coefficient 

change,  49 
via  matrix  change,  40 
via  regional  breakdown,  49 
use  of,  to   identify  substitution  points,   49 
value  of,  in  spatial  theory,   49 
Instability,  see  Stability 

Interest  outlays,   and  substitution   with  labor 
outlays,  36 
differentials    in,    incorporation    in    an    out- 
lay-substitution line,   133 
Interest  rate,  as  a  distorting  factor  in  space- 
economy,   138-140 
effect  of,  on  supply  curve  of  transport  in- 
puts,  88n-89n 
on  the  spatial  extent  of  production,  88n- 

89n 
on  the  transport  rate,   88n-89n 
transport   rate   contrasted   with,    88 
unsystematic       variation       with       distance, 
138 
Interlocal   trade   theory,   see   Trade  theory 
Intermediary   establishments,   location   of,   see 
Location,    of   intermediary    establish- 
ments 
Intermediate   location  (s),   as   a  location   type 
in    Launhardt-Palander    model,    257- 
258,  262-264 
economies  of  scale  as  reducing  number  of, 
in    Launhardt-Palander    model,    265- 
266 
in  case  of  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw 

materials,  262-264 
overestimate  of,  by  Weber,  109 


Intermediate   location  (s )  — continued 

shifts    of,    with   technological   change,    258- 

259 
small  likelihood  of,   108,   113n,   230n 
International  trade,  see  Trade 
Intervening     opportunities     hypothesis,     see 

Stouffer 
Intraregional   trade,    see   Trade 
Iron  and  steel  industry,  and  economic  devel- 
opment, 6-7 
as  a  basic  industry,  18-19,  128n,  284 
as    a    case    of    transport-orientation,    21  In, 

215-219 
as    an    agglomerating-inducing    activity,    8, 

19n 
as  having  different  income  effect  than  tex- 
tiles, 284 
as    having    different    land    use    effect    than 

textiles,  284-285 
as    having    different    multiplier   effect   than 

textiles,  284 
as  partially  labor-  and  partially  transport- 
oriented,  217-219 
deviating  effect  of  cheap  labor  upon  inter- 
national location  of,  216-219 
effect  on  hierarchy  of  cities,  19,  19n,  79n 
geographic  shift  of,   10 
international    location    of,    via    opportunity 

costs,   211-219,   282-285 
labor  costs  as  minor  in  intranational  loca- 
tion of,  211n 
location    of,    6-8,    10,    19n,    37n,    211n,    and 
minimization     of     transport     inputs, 
80n,    118n,   215,   216 
locational  effect   on   steel  fabricating,   8 
technological  advance  in,   7-8,    10 
Iron    ore    deposits    and    relation    to    iron    and 

steel  location,  6-8,   10,   19n,   118n 
Irrationality,   see   Rationality 
Isodapane   technique,    applicable   to   four    (or 
more)    sided   polygons,    122n 
as  embracing  realistic  transport  situations, 

122n 
cumbersome  to  handle,   122n 
more  flexible  than  weight  triangle  method, 

122n 
substitution    between    transport    inputs    in- 
volving    same     basic     considerations, 
123-124 
use    of,    for    transport-orientation    solution, 
122-124 
Isodapanes,     as    contour    lines    of    transport 
cost  surface,   122-124 
construction   based    on    isotims,    122-123 
construction   based   on   isovectors,    122-123 
critical,  definition  of  in  agglomeration  anal- 
ysis,  176n 
definition  of  in  labor  orientation,  130n 
determinants  of,  176n 

disadvantage  relative  to  substitution  ap- 
proach in  labor  orientation,   130-131, 
131n,  259 
distance     from,     and     pull    on     producer, 

178 
ideal   distance  from,   and  best  labor  site, 

130 
intersection    of,    in    agglomeration,    176- 

178 
to    determine    feasibility    of    labor    loca- 
tion.   130-131,   142,   259-260 
to  determine  feasibility  of  power  orienta- 
tion,  132,  259 


314 


Isodapanes — continued 

use  in  analysis  of  urbanization,   183,   188 
use   to   determine   market  area   of   cheap 

labor  site,   259-260 
use  to  determine  market  boundary,   259- 

260 
Weber's  use  of.  130-131,   132,   176-178 
decrease    of    non-circularity    of,    with    dis- 
tance of  deviation,  141 
definition  of,  as  an  incremental  concept,  by 

Weber.   130n 
definition   of,   by   Palander.   122 
distance    between,    and    likelihood    of    labor 

orientation,   141 
effect    of    locational    weight    upon    distance 

between,   141 
effect  of  transport  rate  upon   distance  be- 
tween,  141 
movement  from  subset  to  subset  of,  as  in- 
volving  substitution,    123-124 
non-circularity  of,   141 
subset  of.  and  use  by  Palander.  123-124 
Isolated  city-region,  see  Agricultural  location 

theory ;     City-region 
Iso-outlay   lines,    see   Price-ratio    (iso-outlay) 

lines 
Iso-product  curve,  definition  of,   19  In 

use  of,  in  agricultural  location  theory,  191- 
194 
with  scale  lines,  191-194 
with  price-ratio  lines,   192-194 
Iso-revenue  lines,  use  of.  in  determination  of 

firm's  location,  159 
Iso-revenue-less-outlay  lines,  as  convex    (con- 
cave)   because  of  firm's  influence  on 
price,   159 
construction  of.   133-134 

for   revenue   potentials   and   transport   out- 
lays,  133-134 
use  of.  to  derive  Hotelling's  solutions.   170, 
170n 
to  determine  equilibrium  point,   133-135, 

159 
to   determine   orientation   to   higher-price 

markets,  133-135 
with     revenue-outlay     substitution     line, 
134-135,   159.  175 
Isotants   as   market  boundary  lines,   239 
Isotims,   as   contour  lines   of   transport  cost. 
122 
definition  of.   122 
use  of,  by  Hoover,   122-123 

to  construct  isodapanes.   122-123 
Isovectors.  as  contour  lines  of  transport  cost, 
122-123 
definition  of.  122-123 

movement  along,  as  equivalent  to  substitu- 
tion between   transport   inputs.    123- 
124 
use  of,  by  Palander,  122-123 

to   construct   isodapanes,    122-123 

Journey    to    work,    pattern    of,    as    basic    to 
analysis   of  space-economy,   281 
effect  on  urban  land  use,  281 
problem  of,  increase  in  with  urbanization, 
185 

Knight,   capital  theory  of,   defects   of   its   im- 
plications,  83n 
distinction    between    resources    and    serv- 
ices, 89-90 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Knight — continued 

implications     of,     for     theory     of     space- 
economy,    83n 

Koopmans  transportation  problem,  see  Trans- 
portation analysis,  Koopmans 

Labor,  aggregate  demand  in  market  for,  40- 
41 
as  a  major  location  factor,   138-140 
attraction  of,  as  Alternativattraktion,  130n 
as    involving    discrete    geographic    jump. 
130n 
cheap,  as  a  deviating  force,  216-219 

as  a  location   factor,   8-9.   10.   31n.   128n, 

211-219 
and  minimum  subsistence,  128n 
causes  of,  8-9,  10,  127n-128n 
concept  of,   127n-128n 
effect  on  international  steel  location,  216- 

219 
effect  on   textile  location,   10,   140n,   211- 

219 
efficiency  vs  money  wages,  127n 
from  cultural  factors,  128n 
from  low  transport  cost  on  food.  127n 
in  surplus  food  regions,  127n 
possible    inclusion    in    transport-orienta- 
tion.    127n 
force,    structure    of,     and    decentralization 

policy,   14-15 
geographic    distribution    of,    and    economic 

activity   between   men,    53n 
immobilities   of,    see   Immobilities 
market  for,  and  nature  of  capitalism.  40n- 
41n 
and  types  of  migration,  40 
productivity,   need   to   study   relations   with 

metropolitan  structure,  287 
secondary,  attraction  for  parasitic  industry, 
128n 
definition   of.    128n 
generated   by   basic   industry,   128n 
immobility  of.   128n 
skilled,  agglomeration  economies  in  the  use 
of,   182,  185 
as  a  location  factor,  10 
increasing  cost  of  from  urban  congestion, 
185 
spatial  inelasticity  of,  40 
structure  of  market  for,  40-41 
structure   of   requirements   for,   and   decen- 
tralization policy.   14 
see  also  Factors  ;  Labor  costs  ;  Labor  orien- 
tation 
Labor  coefficient,   as  a  measure  for  different 
industries    of    potential    deviation    to 
labor  location,   141 
as  a  technical  concept,   36n 
as  labor  cost  per  locational  ton,   141 
assumptions   in  the  use  of,   141 
definition  of,   141 
general  applicability  of,   142 
power    coefficient    as    a    parallel    to,    132n, 

141-142 
pros  and  cons  of  ratio  of  labor  cost  savings 
to    additional   transport   outlays,    142 
relation   to   substitution   between   transport 

and  labor  outlays,  141-142 
to  establish  priorities  for  attraction  of  in- 
dustries,  141 
use  of.  to  derive  ratio  of  labor  cost  savings 
to   additional   transport   outlays,    142 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


315 


Labor  cost  savings,  need  to  express  in  terms 
of  opportunity  costs,  217-219 
ratio    of    to    additional    transport    outlays, 
advantages     over     labor     coefficient, 
142 
as  derived  from  labor  coefficient,    142 
as   indicating  labor  orientation,   142 
as   measuring   savings   of   labor   location, 

142 
determination  of,  142 
of  less  general  use  than  labor  coefficient, 

142 
use    to    answer    basic    location    questions, 
142 
Labor  costs,  as  a  distorting  factor  in  space- 
economy,   138-140,  260 
as    determining    industrial    distribution    by 

regions,  172 
as   ignored   by   competitive   locational  equi- 
librium  models,   169-170 
as  major  in  textile  location,  211n 
as  minor  in  iron  and  steel  location,  211n 
compression  of  index  of,   141 
equalizing  differences  in,  as  contrasted  with 
real   differences,    127n,    139n 
as  reflecting  transport  cost  differences  on 

consumer  goods,  127n,  139n 
inclusion      of      in      transport-orientation, 
127n-128n 
for   labor   intensive   firm   as   comparable   to 

rent   for   farm   enterprise,    189-190 
index  of,  and  labor  orientation,   141 
real  differences  in  vs.  equalizing  differences, 

139n 
regularity  in  geographic  pattern  as  related 

to  transport  cost,  139n 
stable  geographic  pattern,  138 
unsystematic  geographic  pattern,  138,  139n, 

140n,   202n,  259 
see  also  Factor  costs  ;  Labor  ;  Labor  outlays 
Labor  inputs,  as  embodied  in  capital  inputs, 
81 
as  embodied  in  transport  inputs,   80n,   81, 

89-90 
substitution    between,    at   cheap    labor    site, 

131 
substitution     for     other     inputs,     at     cheap 

labor  site,   131,   131n,   196 
substitution  with  transport  inputs,  36,  81- 
82 
inadequacy  of,   126-127 
Labor-interest    coefficient,    difficulties    in    use 

of,   137n 
Labor  locations,  as  centers  of  agglomeration, 
179 
market   area   of,    as   determined   by   critical 

isodapanes,  259-260 
shifts    to,    and    the    substitution    principle, 

95n,   135 
see  also  Labor  orientation 
Labor    orientation,    agglomeration    at    points 
of,   179 
and  ideal  distance  from  critical  isodapane, 

130 
and  index  of  labor  costs,   141 
and   locational  weight,    141 
and    percentage    of    compression    of    labor 

cost  index,   141 
and   relative    position    of   locational   figures 

and  labor  locations,   141 
and  transport  rates,  141 
as  included  in  extended  trade  doctrine,  219 


Labor    orientation — continued 

as  indicated  by  the  ratio  of  labor  cost  sav- 
ings to  additional  transport  outlays, 
142 

as  involving  additional  transport  outlays, 
127-131,    141-142,    216-219 

as  involving  substitution  between  transport 
and  labor  outlays,  127-131,  140n.  189- 
190,  196,  259,  275 

as  yielded  by  substitution  principle,  127- 
131,   196,  259,   275 

cases  of  internationally,  as  transport-orien- 
tation   intranationally,    219 

critical  isodapane  and  feasibility  of,  130- 
131,  259-260 

definition  of,  in  international  framework, 
217 

determination   of  market  areas  in,   259-260 

discontinuities  in  potential  sites  of,  130n, 
196 

effect  of  economies  of  scale  on,  175n-176n 

in  international  steel  location,  217-219 

incorporation  of,  in  Launhardt-Palander 
construction,  259-260 

labor  coefficient  and  priorities  for  attrac- 
tion  of  industries,    141 

labor  outlay  differentials  as  central  in,  275 

likelihood  of,  and  distance  between  isoda- 
panes, 141 

need  to  state  in  terms  of  opportunity  costs, 
210-219 

point   of,    and   use   of    iso-outlay   line,    129- 
131 
and  use  of   outlay-substitution  line,   129- 
131 

possibility  of  for  different  industries,  as 
indicated  by  labor  coefficient,  141 

role  of  replacement  deposits  in,  131n,  135, 
141 

sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  lo- 
cation-market-trade doctrines,  256- 
285 

some  cases  of  parasitic  industries  as  ex- 
ceptions, 128n 

use  of  market  area  analysis  in,  260-261 
Labor   outlays,   and   production   outlays,   rela- 
tions  between   via  substitution  prin- 
ciple, 259 

and  transport  outlays,  substitution  between 
in  boundary  formation,  264 
substitution  between  in  labor  orientation, 
127-131,   140n,  189-190,   196,  259,  275 

as  a  variable  in  transport-orientation  anal- 
ysis,  113 

by  types,  substitution  between,  130,  196, 
259 

differentials  in,  as  central  in  labor  orienta- 
tion, 127-131,  275 
incorporation     in     an     outlay-substitution 
line,   127-129 

in  Predohl's  framework,  33 

in  terms  of  use  units,  35 

substitution   with   interest  outlays,   36 

substitution    with   transport   outlays,    36 

see    also    Labor    costs ;    Labor    orientation ; 
Production  outlays 
Land    inputs,    and   other    inputs,   substitution 
between  in  operation  of  farm  enter- 
prise,  193-194,  275 

as  embodied  in  capital  inputs,  81 

as   embodied   in   transport   inputs,   80n,   81, 


316 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Land  inputs — continued 

different  direct  requirements  of,  by  type 
basic  industry,  285 

different  indirect  requirements  of,  by  type 
basic  industry,   285 

price    of,    as    affecting    factor    proportions, 
275 
as  decreasing  with  distance  from  market, 

275 
see  also  Rent 

see  also  Agricultural  land  use 
Land  market,  relation  to  aggregate  demand, 
40 

spatial  inelasticity  of,  40 

structure  of,  40 

see  also  Agricultural  land  use ;  Hinterlands, 
agricultural 
Land  use,   see  Agricultural  land  use ;   Urban 

land  use 
Land-use  outlays,   see   Land-use  units 
Land-use    theory,    see    Agricultural    location 

theory ;   Urban   land-use   theory 
Land-use  units,  and  rent  outlays,  34 

definition  of,  34 

in   Predohl's  framework,   33-34 

invalid  use  of,  34-35 
Land  values,  see  Rent ;  Urban  land  price 
Launhardt,    and   comprehensive   market   area 
analysis,   143n,   153 

and  separate  analysis  for  market  areas 
and  production  for  one-point  mar- 
ket,  143n 

emphasis   on  cost  conditions,   210n 

first  significant  treatment  of  industrial 
location  theory,   143n 

fixed  fii-m  locations  in  market  area  analysis 
of,  160 

market  area  theory  of,  as  yielded  by  gen- 
eral location  principle,  239 

relative  neglect  of  demand,  210n 

use  of  pole  principle  for  transport-orienta- 
tion  solution,    122,   256-258 

see      also      Launhardt-HoteUing      problem ; 
Launhardt-Palander    construction 
Launhardt-Hotelling  problem,  160-163 
Launhardt-Palander    construction,    ability   of, 
to     consider     technological     change, 
258-259 

addition  to,  of  economies  of  scale,  265-267 
of   localization   economies,    267-268 
of   urbanization   economies,    268-270 

and  discontinuities  in  market  areas,  264 

and  economies  of  scale  as  yielding  Losch 
theory  under  uniformity  assump- 
tions, 267 

as  applicable  to  an  area  of  consumers,  256- 
258 

as  emphasizing  localized  raw  material  use, 
274 

as  excluding  agglomeration  economies,  256 

as  excluding  differences  in  local  prices, 
256 

as  implied  by  substitution  principle,  267 

as  involving  angle  conditions,  257 

as  relating  consumer  districts  to  material 
sources  via  industrial  producers,  263- 
264 

as  yielding  an  infinite  number  of  produc- 
tion points,  257-258 

as  yielding  hexagonal  market  areas  from 
use  of  Losch's  uniformity  assump- 
tions, 267 


Launhardt-Palander  construction — continued 
as  yielding  market,  material,  and  interme- 
diate locations,   257-258,   262-264 
changes  in  boundaries  in,  from  scale  econo- 
mies, 266-267 
gross  overstatement  in,  of  number  of  pro- 
ducers, 265 
incorporation     into,     of    cheap     production 
sites,  260 
of  cheap  tax  sites,  260 
of  labor  orientation,  259-260 
of  power  orientation,  260 
market  areas  required  in,  from  scale  econ- 
omies, 266-267 
modified,    fusion    of    with    modified    Losch 
scheme    to    yield    urban-metropolitan 
structure,  274-275 
neglect  in,   of  advertising,   265 

of     competitive     locational     equilibrium, 

264-265 
of   firm  location   policy,   265 
of   firm   pricing   policy,   264-265 
of  oligopolistic  behavior,  265 
non-existence   of,    when   a   weight   is   domi- 
nant, 258n 
procedure  for  developing,   256-257 
symmetry  of,  257 
uniformity   assumptions   of,    256 
use  in,  of  market  area  analysis,  260-267 
of  pole  lines,   256-258 
of   weight   triangle,   256-258 
use  of,  in  analysis  of  changing  weight  re- 
lations, 259 

nalysis  of  new  material  source,  259 
in  dynamic  analysis,   258-259 

the    fusion    of    location-market-trade 
doctrines,  256-285 
in    transport-orientation,  256-258 
to  consider  several  differentials,  259-260 
to    convert    transport-orientation    into    a 
more    generalized    location    problem, 
256-269 
to  delineate  consumer  districts,  262-264 
to  delineate  market  areas,  262-264 
to   identify  locational  shifts,  258-259 
to  portray  locational  interrelations,  256- 

268 
with    two    sources    of    each    of    two    raw 
materials,  262-263 
Leontief,   see   Input-output  analysis 
Lerner  and  Singer,  demand  elasticity  in  com- 
petitive   locational    equilibrium,    163- 
164 
effect  of  market  size  on  solution,  164 
effect  of  transport  cost  on  solution,  164 
more  realistic  undercutting  policy,   163-164 
price   limit   in   competitive   locational   equi- 

Hbrium,    163-164 
solutions   in   competitive   locational  equilib- 
rium, 163-164 
spatial  price  discrimination  in  competitive 
equilibrium,   164n 
Limited    competition,    see    Immobilities ;    Mo- 
nopolistic competition 
Line    charges,    as    causing    local    minima    on 
transport    cost    surface,    229-230 
effect  of  graduation  of,  on  equilibrium  con- 
ditions,  229-230 
on  statement  of  general  location  princi- 
ple, 229-230 
graduation  of,   as  affecting  industrial  loca- 
tion,  107,  229-230 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


317 


Linear   programming,   see   Activity   analysis 
Linkage,   interindustry,   and   commodity  com- 
position  of  trade,   20-21 
and   geographic   split   of   production,    20- 

21 
as    generating    agglomeration    economies, 

21 
as   related  to   production   stage,   21 
Loading  charges,   see  Terminal   charges 
Localization,  a  pattern  of,   in   an   urban-met- 
ropolitan region,  278-280 
a  simple  case  of,  268 

analysis  of,   as   overlapping  with  urbaniza- 
tion  analysis,    182 
as  a  historical  process,   180,   287-288 
as   embraced   by   the  substitution   principle, 

179-182 
as   involving  increase  in  transport  outlays, 

179,  267 
as    involving   substitution    between    produc- 
tion and  transport  outlays,  179,  179n, 
267 
centers    of,    advantage   of   existing   produc- 
tion points  as,   180 
as   influenced  by  side  payments,   180-181, 

181n 
as  pulled  to  superior  bargainers,  180 
clearest    analysis    of,    as    yielded    by    social 
welfare   approach,    268 
for   new  regional  development,   268 
complications  because  of  the  coalition  prob- 
lem,  181n 
conditions  for,   176-178 

decrease    in    validity    of    Weber's    assump- 
tions  with   increase   in,    179n 
difliculties     from     non-symmetric     location 

factors,   181n 
difficulties  of  converting  to  a  constant-sum 

game,   181n 
effect  of  differential  bargaining  abilities  on, 

180-181,   181n 
labor  locations  as   centers  of,   179 
minimization    of   transport   costs    as    deter- 
mining  point   of,    177-178 
need    for    critical    isodapanes    to    intersect, 

176-178 
point    of,    as    affected    by    replacement    de- 
posits,  178 
difficulty  in   determining,   267-268 
use    of    transport-orientation    techniques 
to  indentify,  178 
problem   of,    in    multiplant   firm,    179,    179n 
requisite  total  output  for,   176-178 
size    of,    and    distance    from    critical    isoda- 

pane,   178 
significance     of     inherited     physical     struc- 
tures  for,    180 
significance  of  relocation  cost  for,  180-181, 

181n 
theory    of,    and    complications    of    coalition 
problem   from   relocation   cost,    181n 
sketches    showing    fusion    of    with    other 
location-market-trade  doctrines,   256- 
285 
use  of  game  theory  in,   180-181,   181n 
use  of  side  payment  to  induce,  179n 
see     also     Agglomeration  ;     Agglomeration 
theory  ;  Urbanization 
Localization   diseconomies,   see  Deglomeration 

economies  ;   Localization   economies 
Localization  economies,  addition  of,  to  Laun- 
hardt-Palander    model.    267-268 


Localization  economies — continued 

analysis  of  effect  of,   175-182,  267-268 

as   external  economies,   267 

as     included     in    agglomeration    economies, 

139,    172,    265,   267 
as    scale   economies    with   multiplant   firms, 

179n 
definition  of,   172,  267 
effect    of,    on    structure    of    space-economy, 

268 
in  large  lot  buying  and  selling,  182 
in  the  use  of  auxiliary  facilities,  182,  267 
in  the  use  of  skilled  labor,  182 
incorporation  of,  in  sketches  of  fused  loca- 
tion-market-trade   doctrines,    256-285 
locational   shifts   from,    268 
overlapping  with  economies  of  scale,   182n, 

265 
overlapping    with    urbanization    economies, 

182,  265 
structure   of    industrial   districts   consistent 

with,  278-280 
see  also  Agglomeration  economies 
Localized     raw     materials,     activities     using, 
plus     market-oriented     activities     as 
yielding     urban-metropolitan     struc- 
ture,   274-275,    278-280 
and  a  Thiinen-Losch  model,    18-19 
and  the  Zipf  theoretical  framework,  79n 
deposits  of,  and  implications  for  population 

concentrations,  79n 
failure  of  Losch  theory  to  treat,   154,   158, 

274 
strength  of  Weberian   theory  for  handling, 

158,  274 
use  of,  as  emphasized  in  Launhardt-Palan- 
der  construction,   274 
Location,    and   adaptability   of   capital   goods, 
41 
and   mobility   of   groups   of   factors,   41 
and  the  geographic  distribution  of  factors, 

32-33 
and  the  geographic  pattern  of  local  supply 

prices,  31 
and     the     simultaneous     determination     of 
commodity  flows,   207,   215,   219,  282- 
285 
and    trade,    a    simplified    case    of,    210-219, 
282-285 
interrelations   of,    6-7,    3 In,    50-54,    167n- 

169n,   207-220,   281-285 
simultaneous    determination    of,    6-7,    50- 
54,    207,    215,    282-285 
as     determined    by    a    set    of    substitution 

points,  33-34,  94 
case    of    transport-orientation    intranation- 
ally  as  other  orientation  internation- 
ally,  219,  282 
continuity  of,   in   agriculture,   196 
discontinuity    in,    95n,    101-112,    113,    130n, 

176n,  196,  230,  251,  264 
effect  of  changes  in  distance  variable  upon, 

215-219,  283-285 
fundamental  questions  of,  9-15 
general   principles   of,   and   interrelation   of 
strata,  30 
non-operational   character   of,    23 
use  of,  23 
international,    as    affected    by    the    political 

variable,  283-285 
need  to  develop  gravity   models   to  explain 
more  fully,  209 


318 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Location — continued 

need  to  specify  demand  to  determine  pat- 
tern of,  212 

non-additive   character   of,    21 

of  aluminum  industry  and  substitution  be- 
tween power  and  transport  outlays, 
189-190 

of  intermediary  establishments  and  substi- 
tution among  transport  outlays,  175n 

of  intermediary  establishments  and  sub- 
stitution between  transport  and  pro- 
duction outlays,   175n 

of  interrelated  production  stages,   20-21 

of  iron  and  steel  industry,  see  Iron  and 
steel  industry 

of  manufacturing,   52 

of  marketing  establishments  and  substitu- 
tion   among   transport   outlays,    175n 

of  marketing  establishments  and  substitu- 
tion between  transport  and  produc- 
tion outlays,   175n 

of  raw  material  production,   52 

of  textile  industry,   see  Textile  industry 

patterns   of,   as   associated  with   commodity 
flows,  281 
as  associated  with  population  flows,  281 
changes     in    with    technological    change, 

258-259 
under    constant    cost    assumptions,    235- 
236 

rich  and  poor  sectors  of,  in  Losch,  270-273 

spatial  coordinates  of,  45-46 

simultaneous  existence  of  at  markets,  raw 
material  sites,  and  intermediate 
points,  235-236 

see  also   Industrial  location  ;   Location   the- 
ory ;    Space-economy,    structure    of 
Location   factors,   agglomerative  and  deglom- 
erative    factors    as    a    major    group, 
139-140 

classification    of,    into    three    groups,    138- 
140 
overlapping  of  groups,   138,   138n-139n 

labor,     power,     interest,    taxes,     etc.    as     a 
major  group   in,   138-139 
Location  theory,  and  equilibrium  among  spa- 
tially separated   markets,   167n-169n, 
213n,  286 

and  fusion  of  the  several  doctrines  via  sub- 
stitution principle,  189-199,  221,  252, 
255,  259,  275,  286 

and  Graham's  trade  theory,  some  common 
elements  of,   210 

and  need  for  a  sharply  defined  concept  of 
rational  behavior,   286 

and  neglect  of  mobility  of  groups  of 
factors,  41 

and   price  theory,   23,   32,   42n 

and  principles  to  reduce  number  of  poten- 
tial  locations,    168n-169n 

and   production   theory,   fusion  of   via  gen- 
eral  location    principle,    23,    252-253, 
286 
fusion  of  via  substitution  principle,   113, 

221,   252-253,   255,   259 
need  to  spell  out  fusion  in  detail,  286 
parallel  use  of  substitution,  135-137,  252- 

253 
similarity  of  first-  and  second-order  con- 
ditions,  118 

and  trade  theory,  fusion  of,  23,  50-54,  207- 
220,  281-282 


Location  theory — continued 

need     to     explore     relations     comprehen- 
sively, 286 
and    transport   cost   as    a    function    of   dis- 
tance,  35,   138-140,  210 
as  contained  in  a  total  analysis  for  Ohlin's 

district,    52-53,    53n 
as   contrasted   to  the   Samuelson-Beckmann 
market-transportation    model,    168n- 
169n 
as     generalized     around     the     Thiinen     ap- 
proach, 249-251 
as    generally    assuming    continuous    space- 
economy,  251 
as  generally  precluding  use  of  regular  hex- 
agons, 274n 
as  related  to  the  Koopmans  transportation 

problem,   168n-169n 
as    traditionally   exchiding   urban    land   use 

theory,  200 
as   treating  separately  production  for  one- 
point   market   and   for   market   area, 
143n 
existing,    as    implied    by    general    location 

principle,   222-253,   286 
extension  of,   as   including  developments  in 
long-run    trade    theory,    219-220,    282 
by    fusion    of   trade    doctrine    and    trans- 
port-orientation,   217-219,    281-282 
through     opportunity     cost     formulation, 

210-219,   281-282 
to     include     production     theory     through 
concept    of    transport    inputs,     118- 
119,  252-253 
fused   location-market-supply  statement  of, 

250-251 
generalized   Thiinen   approach   as  more  de- 
sirable than  generalized  market  area 
approach,  249 
inadequate   treatment    of   costs    in,    for    in- 
ternational  analysis,   210 
incorporation    of    Weber    and    Thiinen    in 
one   framework,    92-93,    188-189,    275 
most  general  frameworks  of,  249,  252,  285- 

286 
need    to   consider   transport   rate   structure 

as  variable,   213n,  286 
need   to   develop    operational   models,   287 
need    to    express    in    terms    of    opportunity 

costs.  210-219 
partial,  and  firm  analysis,  91-124 

as  yielded  by  general  location  theory,  91, 

252 
Dean's  contribution,  3 In 
fusion    of    with    use    of    general    location 

principle,   221-253 
Hoover's  contribution,  30n 
synthesis    of   in    general   location   theory, 

91,  221-253,  254-287 
Usher's   contribution,   3 In 
the  Weber-Thiinen  dualism  in,   92-93,   188- 

189,  275 
traditional,  and  assumption  of  fixed  trans- 
port rate  structures,   213n 
and  assumption  of  monopolistic  elements 

in  transportation,  213n 
and    neglect    of    transport    rates    as    de- 
pendent on  flow  volumes,  213n 
emphasis   upon   costs   in,   210n 
relative   neglect  of   demand   in,   210n 
use   with    a    general    market-transportation 
model,   168n-169n,  286 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


319 


Location  theory — continued 

see  also  Agricultural  location  theory  ;  Gen- 
eral location  theory 
Locational    analysis,    as    generalized    around 
the   Thunen   approach,   249-251 

different  levels  of  inquiry,  92-93,   189 

firm  level  of  inquiry,  92 

generalized  Thunen  approach  as  more  de- 
sirable than  generalized  market  area 
approach,  249 

industry   level   of   inquiry,   92 

most   general  frameworks   of,   249,   252 

regional    (world)    level  of  inquiry,   92 

use  of  excess  supply  function  in,  168n 

use  of  Launhardt-Palander  construction  in, 
256-268 

see  also  Agricultural  location  theory  ;  Gen- 
eral location  theory  ;  Location  theory 
Locational  equilibrium,  see  Equilibrium  point 
(for  firm  location)  ;  Firm,  indus- 
trial ;  Firm,  agricultural  ;  Competi- 
tive locational  equilibrium ;  Firm, 
urban  ;  Agricultural  land  use  ;  Urban 
land  use 
Locational  forces,  as  generally  precluding 
hexagonal  markets,  274n 

as  ideal  weights,   121-122 

as  transport  cost  per  unit  distance,   122 

equilibrium  outside  triangle,  and  angle 
conditions,  122 

equilibrium  outside  triangle,  and  corner  lo- 
cation,  122 

mathematical  presentation  of  equilibrium 
of,   in  simple  polygon  case,  226-227 

mathematical  presentation  of  equilibrium 
of,   in  simple  triangle  case,  225 

use  of  mechanical  model  to  determine  equi- 
librium   of,    121 

use   of   weight   triangle  to   determine   equi- 
librium of,   121 
Locational    line    case,    as    a    simplified    trans- 
port-orientation problem,  96-97,  119- 
120 

as  substitution  between  distance  variables, 
96-97 

as  substitution  between  transport  inputs, 
117.   119-120 

assumptions  of,  95-96 

determinacy  with  use  of  a  weight-losing 
material,   120 

determinacy  with  use  of  an  ubiquity,  120 

end  point  solution  for,  107,  107n 

indeterminacy  with  graduated  transport 
rates,   120 

most  simple  situation,  indeterminacy  of, 
119-120 

Weberian    propositions    derived    via    trans- 
formation and  price-ratio  lines,  119- 
120 
Locational  polygon  case,  as  a  simplified  trans- 
port-orientation   problem,    98-101 

as  handled  by  the  isodapane  technique,  122- 
124 

as  substitution  between  distance  variables, 
subject  to  transport  cost  restraint, 
98-101,  lOln,  226-227 

as  substitution  between  transport  inputs, 
subject  to  transport  cost  restraint, 
117,  226-230 

assumptions  of,  98-100 

complications  of  the  substitution  problem 
in,   98-101.   lOln 


Locational  polygon  case — continued 

conditions  for  corner  location,  226,  229-230 

conditions  for  minimum  point  of  transport 
cost  surface   in,   226,   229-230 

conditions  to  be  satisfied  by  equilibrium 
point,   104,  226-227 

end  point  (corner)  solution  for,  107-112, 
113n,  229-230 

first-order  conditions  for,  in  terms  of  modi- 
fied  transport  rates,   229-230 

invalid  use  by  Weber  of  fictitious  distances, 
109,   109n 

possibility  of  several  minimum  points,  229- 
230 

profit  maximization  in,  as  reduced  to  vari- 
ation in  distance  variables,   226 

need  for  direct  total  transport  cost  com- 
parisons, 230 

second-order  condition  for,  in  terms  of 
modified    transport    rates,    229-230 

small  likelihood  of  intermediate  location, 
108,   113n,   230n 

use  of  realistic  rates  and  weights  to  de- 
rive transport  cost  restraint,  lOOn, 
229-230 

valid  use  by  Weber  of  ideal  weights,  109n, 
228 

with  finite  number  of  transport  routes,  101 

with  realistic  rate  structures,  229-230 
Locational  shifts,   and   advance  in  transport 
technology,  22 

and  decentralization  policy,  14-15 

and  guiding  new  industrial  growth,  14-16 

and    industrialization,    9-10 

and  national  commodity  production,  17-18 

and  substitution  between  outlays,  33-34,  49, 
179,   179n 

and  substitution  between  outlays  and  reve- 
nues, 49,  174-175,  175n-176n 

and  substitution  between  transport  inputs, 
49,  251 

from  focal  point  to  focal  point,  as  substitu- 
tion  in  the  large,   251 

in  terms  of  substitution  and  transforma- 
tion lines,  175n-176n 

incorporation  in,  in  input-output  analysis, 
49 

of  agricultural  firm  and  eflfect  on  farm 
operations,   194-195 

problems  of.  9-10 

resulting  from  localization  economies,  268 

resulting  from  scale  economies.  265-267 

resulting  from  technological  advance,  7, 
12-13,  258-259 

resulting  from  urbanization  economies,  269- 
270,  273-274 

role  of  price  changes  in,  243 

use  of  Launhardt-Palander  construction  to 
identify,    258-259 
Locational  triangle  case,  as  a  simplified  trans- 
port-orientation problem.  97-98.  101- 
104 

as  handled  by  the  isodapane  technique.  122- 
124 

as  substitution  between  distance  variables, 
97-98 

as  substitution  between  transport  inputs, 
114-119,    120-122,   222-226 

assumptions  of,   97,   102 

conditions    for   corner   location,    225-226 

conditions  for  minimum  point  on  transport 
cost  surface.   223-225 


320 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Locational    triangle    case — continued 

end  point  (corner)  solution  for,  107-112, 
121-122 

mathematical  formulation  of,  222-226 

profit  maximization  in,  as  reduced  to  varia- 
tion of  three  distance  variables,  222- 
226 

situation  of  single  minimum  point,  224 

smaU  likelihood  of  intermediate  location, 
108,   113n 

solution  with  the  use  of  price-ratio  and 
discontinuous  transformation  lines, 
101-112 

transport  cost  surface  as  convex  downward 
in,  224 

when  Dean's  index  less  than  unity,  and 
substitution,   121 

when  material  index  less  than  unity,  and 
substitution,   120-121 

when  weight  triangle  exists,  and  substitu- 
tion,  121-122 

with  finite  number  of  transport  routes, 
101-112 

with   realistic   rate   structures,    104-112 
Locational  weight,  as  a  technical  concept,  36n 

as  an  element  of  the  labor  coefficient,  141 

as  based  on  ideal  weights,  141 

effect  on  distance  between  isodapanes,  141 

use  of,  in  labor  orientation,  141 
Long-run  trade  theory,  see  Trade  theory 
Losch   (location  theory  of),  and  a  non-opera- 
tional general  equilibrium  system  for 
agriculture,   243n 

and  causes  of  interregional  trade,  17 

and  constant  unit  cost  on  farm,  244,  247 

and  consumer  indifference  on  market  boun- 
daries, 46-47,  240 

and  exhaustion  of  plain  by  net  of  market 
areas,  46-47,  241 

and  frequency  distribution  of  cities,  59-60 

and  fusion  of  market  area  analysis  and  in- 
dustrial location,   143n 

and  general  equilibrium  under  monopolistic 
competition,  43-50 

and  hierarchy  of  sites,  17,  153-154,  270-271, 
273 

and  invalidity  of  pure  competition  assump- 
tions,  158-159 

and  market  area  as  small  as  possible,  46-47 

and  market  orientation,   16,   274 

and   margin   lines,    150-151 

and  maximum  coincidence  of  locations,  271 

and  maximum  number  of  independent  pro- 
ducers, 46 

and  maximum  local  demand,  271 

and   minimum   shipments,    271 

and  minimum  sum  of  shortest  distances, 
271 

and  natural  markets,  150-151 

and  optimum  agricultural  pattern,  48 

and  optimum  consumption  pattern,  48 

and  pattern  of  production  centers,  270-271 

and  price  equals  average  cost,  43,  46-47, 
240 

and  regular  hexagons  as  precluded  in  real- 
istic market  analysis,   274n 

and  sloping  demand  curve  for  the  firm, 
158-159 

and  substitution  between  production  out- 
lays  for  two  producers,   153-154 

and  substitution  between  transport  inputs, 
153-154,  240-242 


Losch    (location  theory  of) — continued 

and  the  Chamberlinian  tangency  solution, 
46 

and  the  construction  of  a  firm's  aggregate 
demand  curve,  159n 

and  the  effect  of  differentials  in  input 
prices  on   agricultural  location,   199n 

and  the  hexagon  as  a  pure  theoretical  con- 
cept, 274n 

and  the  maximizing  of  social  welfare  with 
hexagonal  market  areas,   153,  242 

and  the  superiority  of  hexagonal  to  equi- 
lateral triangular  market  areas,   242 

and  the  superiority  of  hexagonal  to  square 
market  areas,  241-242 

and  use  of  ubiquitous  materials,  16,  274 

and  yield  per  acre  as  invariant  with  dis- 
tance from  city,  244,  247 

anemic  character  with  respect  to  substitu- 
tion points,  49 

applicability  to  urban-metropolitan  re- 
gions, 154 

arrangement  of  nets  about  common  pro- 
duction   center,    270-271 

as  a  logical  point  of  departure  for  regional 
analysis,   154 

as  a  supplement  to  agricultural  location 
theory,  16-19 

as  a  simplified  market  area  problem,  239- 
240 

as  an  outgrowth  of  Fetter-Launhardt  ap- 
proach, 153 

as  applicable  to  location  of  service  activi- 
ties,  154,  274 

as  derived  from  Launhardt-Palander  con- 
struction with  economies  of  scale, 
267 

as  derived  from  the  substitution  principle, 
153-154,    239-242,   267 

as   excluding  material  orientation,   274 

as  implying  regular  geometric  shapes  of 
market  areas,  241 

as  implying  same  size  for  all  producers, 
240 

as  implying  straight  line  boundary  between 
any   two   producers,    240-241,   274n 

as  inapplicable  to  localized  material  using 
industry,    154,    157,   274 

as  involving  multicommodity  framework, 
44-49,    153-154,   270-271 

as  yielded  by  the  general  location  principle, 
240-242,    252,    286 

boundary  equations  of  original  model,  45-46 

central  place  theories  of,  60,  60n 

concept  of  market  net,  44,  239,  270-271 

concept  of  system  of  market  nets,  44-45, 
143-144,   239,    270-271 

concept  of  the  market,  44,  151,  270-271 

criticism  of  Classical  trade  theory,  208 

criticism  of  Ohlin's  trade  theory,   53n 

criticisms   of,   48,   48n,   153-154,   271-273 

derivation  of  hexagonal  market  area,  44, 
153,    174,   239-242 

derivation  of  market  net,  44,  153 

derivation  of  system  of  nets,  44-45,  153, 
154 

difficulties  of,  with  non-uniformity  assump- 
tions, 48-49,   153-154 

economies  of  scale  as  a  basic  variable,  44, 
150-151,   174,  267 

emphasis  on  economic  activity  between 
men,  53n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


321 


Losch    (location  theory  of) — continued 

empirical    findings    and    the    distance    vari- 
able, 60n 
equality    of   number   of   equations    and   un- 
knowns in,  45-47 
extension  via  general  location  principle,  252 
fusion      of     modified      Launhardt-Palander 

scheme  with  modified  scheme  of,  274- 

275 
fusion   with   other   schemes   in   a   sketch   of 

urban-metropolitan     structure,     274- 

275 
inconsistency    of    market    system    of,    with 

resulting  population  distribution,  271 
introduction   of  space  through  assumption, 

78 
modification  of  market  system  of,  to  square 

with  population  distribution,  271-273 
modified,  sketch  of  as  fused  with  sketch  of 

agricultural  land  use,  272,  277-278 
modified  system,   difficulty   in   constructing, 

274n 
neglect    of    agglomeration    economies,    153- 

154 
regularities  of  flows  and  spatial  pattern  of 

cities,   58-60,    60n 
resource    inequalities    and    spatial    pattern 

of  cities,  60 
rich   and    poor   sectors    of   production   sites 

in,  270-273 
role   of   competition   and   freedom   of   entry 

in,  44-45,  240 
simple  diagram  of  system  of  nets  of  market 

areas,  270 
simplified   boundary   equations   in,    240 
sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  loca- 
tion-market-trade   doctrines,    256-285 
statement  of  knowns  and  unknowns,  45 
symbols   of  spatial  arrangement,   45-46 
the    set    of    equilibrium    conditions,    45-47, 

239-243 
transport  cost  as  a  basic  variable,  44,  150- 

151,  267 
transport   costs   on   raw   materials    as   zero 

in,  239-240 
transport  network  in,   270-271 
uniformity    assumptions,    44,    152-153,    239, 

267 
urbanization  economies  in,  270-271 
use  in  general  location  approaches,  15-20 
use  of  average  cost  pricing  in,  240 

Marginal  cost,  advantages  relative  to  average 
cost  in  boundary   definition,   236n 
and  average  cost,   same  difference  between 

for  all  producers  in  Losch,  240 
as   affecting   farm   output,    190-194 
effect   of   changes   in,   on   competitive   equi- 
librium,  165n 
effect  on   margin   line,   150,   149n-150n,   173 
equality  with  net  farm  price  in  equilibrium, 

190-191,  197 
use  of,  for  pricing,  and  loss  possibility  for 
producer,  236n 
to    define    boundaries    in    multifirm    case, 

236-239 
to  identify  optimum  space-economy,  236n 
see  also  Cost  curves 
Marginal  cost  curves,  see  Cost  curves 
Marginal   cost  pricing,   see  Pricing  system 
Margin    lines,    and    definition    of    competitive 
market  areas,  150-151 


Margin  lines — continued 

and  effect  of  economies  of  scale,  173-174 
and  Losch  market  area  analysis,  150-151 
as    indicating    delivered    price    variation    at 
edge    of    markets    of    different    size, 
148-150 
changes    in,    with   changes    in   pricing   sys- 
tem,   150,    149n-150n 
construction  of,   148-150,   154n 
Market  (s),  active,  39 

and  iron  and  steel  location,  10,   118n 
allocation   of,    by   use   of   aggregate   supply 

curve,   156n-157n 
allocation  to  supply  sources,  and  changes  in 
demand,    156n-157n 
and    changes    in    transport    rates,    156n- 
157n 
as    affected    by    economies    of    scale,    175n- 

176n 
classification     of,     according    to    structure, 

39-41 
inactive,  39 
local,  58,  58n 
locational  pull  of,   10 
major  regional,  58,  58n 
minor  regional,  58,  58n 

multiple,    as   affecting   patterns   of   agricul- 
tural land  use,   198-199,  249-251,  276 
national,   58,  58n 
size    of,     effect    on     competitive    locational 

equilibrium,   164 
spatial  distribution  of,  effect  on  economies 
of  scale,   175n-176n 
effect  on  substitution  points,   175n-176n 
spatial    division    of,    and    price   discrimina- 
tion,  164n 
spatially  separated,  equilibrium  among,  and 
spatial  price  equilibrium,  167n-168n 
as   allied   to   the  location   problem,    167n- 

169n 
as    allied   to   the   transportation   problem, 

167n-169n 
as   derived  by   Enke,   167n-168n 
as  related  to  activity  analysis,  168n-169n 
as  stated  by  Samuelson,   168n 
structure   of,   and   Weigmann's   basic   form, 

39-42 
types  of,  and  city  rank,  58,  60 

and   volume  and   length   of  flows,   58 
see  also  Market  areas 
Market  area(s),   a  Losch  diagram  of  system 
of  nets  of,   270 
a    modified    Losch    diagram    of   systems    of, 

272 
and    the   competition    field,    38-39 
and    the    simultaneous    existence    of    point, 

line,  and  areal  markets,  285-236 
and  the  use  of  space  discount,  85-86 
as  distinct  from  supply  area,  154n 
as    distorted    hexagons    in    modified    Losch 

scheme,   271-273 
as    interrelated    with    other    market    areas 

and  all  production   sites,   238 
as    non-hexagonal    in    an    optimum    space- 
economy     if     Losch's     postulates    re- 
laxed, 242n-243n 
as    overlapping    with    supply    areas    in    the 

general  case,  235 
as    required    by    scale    economies    in    Laun- 
hardt-Palander   model,    266-267 
at   the   core   as    points    in    modified    Losch 
diagram,  271-273 


322 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Market  area(s) — continued 

changes  in,  with  technological  change,  258- 

259 
circular,  and  substitution  between  transport 

inputs  in  different  directions,  147 
competitive,  and  substitution  between  trans- 
port inputs  on  products  of  two  pro- 
ducers, 147-148 
as  defined  by  margin  lines,  150-151,  173- 
176 
conditions     for     non-competitive    situation, 

151 
consumer  space  preferences  as  an  explana- 
tion   of    transport    inputs    incurred, 
144-145 
content  of,  as  changing  with  conception  of 

social  surplus,  234-235 
delineation  of,  by  means  of  Launhardt-Pa- 

lander   construction,    262-264 
demarcation     of,     as     substitution     in     the 

small,  251 
derivation  of  hexagonal  form,  44,  153,  174, 

239-242 
discontinuity     of,     in     Launhardt-Palander 

construction,  264 
distortion   of,   with  realistic  transport  rate 

structures,  239n 
division   of  a  region   into,   236 
enclosed,    conditions    for,    146-147 
equilateral    triangular,    as    exhausting    do- 
main, 241 
extent  of,  and  economies  of  scale,  58,  148- 
151,   153,  173-174 
and  transport  cost,   148-151,  153 
under    different    pricing    systems,    149n- 
150n,  239n 
for   raw   material   producers,    154 
fusion   of   modified    Losch   system   of,    with 
sketch  of  agricultural  land  use,   272, 
277-278 
hexagon    as   the   ideal   form,   44,    153,    242, 

242n 
hexagonal,  as  exhausting  domain,  241 

as    involving    minimization    of    transport 

inputs,  242 
as  maximizing  social  welfare,   153,  242 
as   yielded   by  the  general   location   prin- 
ciple, 242 
as   yielded   by   the  substitution   principle, 

153,   240-242 
when     Losch's     uniformity     assumptions 
used    in    Launhardt-Palander    model, 
267 
in     a     market-orientation     case     with    two 
sources   for   each   of   two   raw   mate- 
rials, 261-262 
interrelation  of  size  and  number  of  produc- 
tion sites  in  sector  system  of,  273 
limits  to  the  extent  of,   146-147,  150 
Losch's,  and  maximum  coincidence  of  loca- 
tions, 271 
and  maximum  local  demand,  271 
and  minimum  of  shipments,  271 
and  minimum  sum  of  shortest  distances, 

271 
and  rich  and  poor  sectors  of  production 

sites,  270-271 
arrangement    about    common    production 

center,  270-271 
as     related     to     pattern     of     production 

centers,  270-271 
as  related  to  transport  routes,  271 


Market  area  (s )  — continued 

boundary   equations   of,   45-46,   240,   241 
concept  of,  44,   150-151,  270-271 
concept  of  net  of,  44,  153,  239-242,  270- 

271 
concept  of  system  of  market  nets,  44-45, 

153,  270-271 
inconsistency    of    with    resulting    popula- 
tion distribution,   153-154,   271 
modification    of    to    square   with    popula- 
tion  distribution,    271-273 
natural,    in    absence    of    competition,    150, 

231-235 
of  labor  locations,  as  determined  by  critical 

isodapane,  259-260 
overlapping,   because   of   advertising,   264 
because   of   non-price   competition,    264 
because  of  oligopolistic  behavior,  264 
because  of  price  discrimination,  264 
pattern  of,   in   multifirm  varying  unit  cost 
case,  238 
with  constant  cost  producers,  235-236 
population    content    of,    as    changing    with 

distance  from  core,  278 
single  firm,  conditions  for  circular,  145-146 
non-circular,  because  of  directional  varia- 
tion in  transport  rates,  23  In 
because     of    geographic    irregularities, 

145-146 
because  of  income  inequalities,  145-146 
because   of   transport   scale   economies, 

145-146 
because    of    uneven    consumer    spread, 
145-146 
size    of,    and    commodity    classification,    17, 
153,  271 
as  affected  by  substitution  between  trans- 
port inputs,  233n 
as   increasing   with  distance  from  major 

transport  route,   274n 
as    related    to    intensity    of    agricultural 

land  use,  271 
as   related   to   intensity   of   industrial  ac- 
tivity, 271 
as  related  to  population  density,  271 
increasing  with  distance  from  core,  271- 
273,  274n 
spatial  array  of,   and  the  basic  form,  38- 
41 
in    Ohlin's   interdependence  system,   51 
spatial  extent  of,  and  limited  competition, 

37-38 
square,  as  exhausting  domain,  241 
structure   of,    as   related   to   transport   net- 
work, 272-273 
superiority  of  hexagonal  to  equilateral  tri- 
angular, 44,  241-242 
superiority    of    hexagonal    to    square,     44, 

241-242 
two  competing   firms,   when   factory   prices 
differ,   146-147 
when  factory  prices  the  same,   146 
when  transport  rates  differ,   146-147 
when  transport  rates  the  same,  146 
when   social   surplus   maximized,    multifirm 
case,  235-239 
single  firm  case,  231-235 
with  a  straight  line  boundary,  146,  151-153, 

239,  240-241 
with  an  hyperbolic  boundary,  146,  239 
with  hypercircular  boundary,  146-147,  147n, 
239 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


323 


Market  area(s) — continued 

see  also  Consumption,  areas  of ;  Market 
area  analysis ;  Market  boundaries  ; 
Markets 
Market  area  analysis,  and  conditions  for  max- 
imum social  surplus,  232-239 
and  effect  of  constant  consumption  density 
on  conditions  for  maximum  surplus, 
233n 

and  incidence  of  transport  inputs  in  dif- 
ferent producer-consumer  situations, 
144-145 

and  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between 
production   outlays  of  firms,   148 

and  marginal  rate  of  substitution  between 
transport  inputs,   148,  233-239 

and  marginal  rates  under  constant  cost 
production,   148 

and  relaxation  of  one-point  market  assump- 
tion, 143,  260 

and  substitution  between  production  out- 
lays of  two  producers,  148-154,  260- 
261 

and  the  defining  of  market  boundary  in 
terms  of  consumer  indifference,  231- 
232,  236,  236n,  237 

and  the  hexagon  as  a  pure  theoretical  con- 
cept, 274n 

and  transport-orientation  framework,  com- 
plex  boundaries   in,   262-264 
discontinuous  markets   in,   264 
introduction  of  scale  economies  into,  265- 
267 

and  use  of  margin  lines,   148-154 

and  use  of  Stieltjes  integral,  233n 

and  use  of  substitution  between  transport 
inputs  for  groups  of  consumers. 
235n 

as  involved  in  transport-orientation  with 
many  market  points,  260 

as  involving  explicit  use  of  social  surplus, 
249 

as  treated  separately  from  production  for 
one-point  market  in  traditional  the- 
ory,  143n 

as  substitution  between  transport  inputs 
on  producers'  products,  147-154 

as  yielded  by  the  substitution  principle, 
147-154,   231-239,    260-267 

as  yielding  more  precise  results  than  com- 
petitive  location   analysis,    169 

as  yielding  precise  results  by  abstracting 
from   complex   factors,    169 

conditions  for  reduction  to  one-point  analy- 
sis,  145 

consumers  along  a  straight  line,   148-151 

consumers  distributed  in  an  area,  151-154 

demarcating  boundaries  as  essential  core 
of,  231 

derivation  of  Losch,  from  a  two  firm  case, 
153 

different  producer-consumer  situations  in, 
144-145 

extended  to  embrace  raw  material  supply 
areas,  235,  238-239 

failure  of  Launhardt  to  fuse  with  indus- 
trial location  theory,   143n 

failure  of  Weberian  theory  to  encompass, 
143n 

for  cases  of  two  sources  of  each  of  two 
materials,  261-264 

for  raw  material  producers,   154 


Market    area    analysis — continued 

form    of,    as    invariant   with    conception   of 

social  surplus,  234-235 
fusion   of,   with  transport-orientation,  231- 

239 
with     transport-orientation     and     supply 

area  analysis,   235,   238-239 
generalized,  as  less  desirable  than  general- 
ized   Thiinen    approach,    249 
in   a   fused   location-supply-production   doc- 
trine, 252-253,  286 
inapplicability    to,    of   transport-orientation 

for    an    infinite    number    of    market 

points,  231 
inclusion     of,     in     a     generalized     Thiinen 

framework,  250-251 
Losch  scheme  as  a  simplified  case  of,  239- 

240 
mathematical     formulation     of,     in     simple 

multifirm  case,  235-239 
in   simple  single  firm  case,  231-235 
multifirm,    under    varying    unit    cost,    236- 

239 
multiple   stationary   points   in,   from   varia- 
tion in  density  of  consumption,  233 
need     to     consider     production     sites     with 

boundaries   as  variables   in,   231 
need    to    integrate    with    competitive    loca- 

tional   equilibrium,    170 
one-point  market  analysis  as  a  special  case 

of,   143,   145,   231 
realistic,    as    precluding    regular    hexagon, 

274n 
sketches     showing    fusion     of,    with    other 

location-supply-trade   doctrines,    256- 

285 
supply  area  analysis  as  reverse  of,  155-158 
to    determine    districts    served    by    different 

combinations     of     material     sources, 

261-264 
traditional,   as  yielded  by  the  general  loca- 
tion principle,   239,   252,  286 
transition  from  a  straight  line  to  an  areal 

case,   151-153 
under  different  pricing  systems,  236n,  239n 
under    some    simple    conceptions    of    social 

surplus,  234-235 
under     uniformity     assumptions,     152-153, 

239-242 
use  of  boundaries  to  reduce  infinite  num- 
ber of  variables   in,   237-238 
use  of,   in  labor  orientation,  260-261 

in  Launhardt-Palander  construction,  260- 

267 
where  consumer  may   purchase  more  than 

one  unit  of  product,   234-239 
where     consumer    purchases     one    unit    of 

product,  232-233 
with     realistic    transport    rate    structures, 

239n 
see  also  Market  areas  ;  Market  boundaries 
Market  boundai-y  (ies),  advantage  of  marginal 

cost    definition,    236n 
and   constant  cost  conditions,    148,   235-236 
and  increasing  cost  conditions,  149-154 
as  a  circle,  conditions  for,   145-146,  239 
as    a    hyperbola,    conditions    for,    146,    154, 

239,  261 
as  a  hypercircle,  conditions  for,   146,   147n, 

239 
as  a  perpendicular  bisector,  conditions  for, 

146,  153,  154,  239.  261 


324 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Market  boundary  (ies) — continued 

as  a  series   of  boundary  stretches,   266-267 

as  blurred,  because  of  advertising,  264 
because  of  non-price  competition,  264 
because  of  oligopolistic  behavior,  264 
because  of  price  discrimination,   264 

as  changing  with  conception  of  social  sur- 
plus,  234-235 

as    defined    by    maximum    price    consumer 
will  pay,  231-232 

as  determined  by  margin  lines,   150-151 

as  loci  of  points  of  equal  delivered  prices, 
146-147,   237,   240 

as  non-circular  when  transport  rate  varies 
with   direction,    231n 

as   straight   line  perpendicular  bisectors   in 
Losch,  240-241,  274n 

changes  in,  with  introduction  of  economies 
of  scale,  266-267 

complex  character  of,  in  transport-orienta- 
tion-market area  problem,  262-264 

conditions    of,    as    yielded   by   general   loca- 
tion principle,  239,  252 

definition  of,   146,   146n,   147n 

in  terms  of  consumer  indifference,  46-47, 
231-232,  236,  236n 

delineation    of,    by    means    of    Launhardt- 
Palander  construction,  262-264 

demarcation  of,  as  essential  core  of  market 
area   analysis,    231 

distortion   of,   by   transport   rate  structure, 
239n 

equation    of,    for   isolated   monopolist,    231- 
232 
under    different    pricing    systems,    236n, 
239n 

for  raw  material  producers,  154,  262 

formation     of,     and     substitution     between 
transport  and  labor  outlays,  264 
and    substitution    between    transport    in- 
puts,   148,    233-239,    264 

in  a  sketch  of  a  Losch  system,  270 

in  a  sketch  of  a  modified  Losch  system,  272 

in  cases  with  two  sources  for  each  of  two 
raw  materials,   261-264 

Losch's  equations  of,  45-46 

minor  indeterminacy  of,  from  discrete  con- 
sumer spread,   146n 

need    to    consider    as    variables    in    market 
area   analysis,   231 

shift  of,   with  shift  of   production  sites   in 
Losch,   241-242 

simplified    equations    of,    in    Losch    scheme, 
240 

socially   efficient,   formation   of  and   chang- 
ing   marginal    rates    of    substitution, 
148 
formation    of    and    substitution    between 

production  outlays,  148-154,  262 
formation    of    and    substitution    between 
transport    inputs,    147-148,    233-239, 
262 

use  of  critical  isodapane  to  determine,  259- 
260 

use  of  marginal  cost  to  define,  236-239 

use  to  reduce  an  infinity  of  variables  to  a 
finite  number,  237-238 

where   social   surplus    maximized   in    multi- 
firm   case,   235-239 

where   social   surplus    maximized    in    single 
firm  case,  231-235 

see  also  Market  area  analysis  ;  Market  areas 


Market    interpenetration,    see    Market    areas, 

overlapping 
Market-orientation,  a  case  of,  involving  mar- 
ket area  analysis,  261-262 
and  the  Losch  framework,  16,  274 
as   a   location   type   in    Launhardt-Palander 

model,   257-258,   262-264 
changes  in,  with  technological  change,  258- 

259 
effect  of  economies  of  scale  on,  175n-176n 
in  iron  and  steel  industry,  6-7,  118n 
in  case  of  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw 

materials,   261-264 
when   product   weight   is   dominant,   258n 
see  also  Transport-orientation 
Market-oriented    activities,    as    the    basis    for 
cities,    57,   274-275,    274n-275n 
effect  of  basic  industry  on,  19,  278 
number  of,  and  size  of  city,  57 
plus    localized    material   using   activities   as 
yielding     urban-metropolitan     struc- 
ture,   274-275,    278-280 
spatial  pattern  of,  as  affected  by  basic  ac- 
tivity, 278n 
Marketing     establishment,     location     of,     see 
Location      of      marketing     establish- 
ments 
Marshallian  approach,  and  the  incorporation 
of  transport  function  within,  90 
neglect  of  space  in,   24-25,  254 
Material  index,  as  a  technical  concept,  36n 
value  of,  and  existence  of  weight  triangle, 
120-121 
Material-orientation,   as  a  location  type  in 
Launhardt-Palander     construction, 
257-258,  262-264 
as  excluded  in  Losch  scheme,  274 
changes  in,  with  technological  change,  258- 

259 
in  case  of  two  sources  of  each  of  two  raw 

materials,  262-264 
when    raw    material    weight    is    dominant, 

258n 
see  also  Transport-orientation 
Medical    services    as    basic    urban    industry, 

274n-275n 
Metropolitan   region,   see  Urban-Metropolitan 

region 
Migration,  as  varying  inversely  with  distance, 
64n 
distance  of,  and  the  intervening  opportuni- 
ties hypothesis,  64n,  65n 
intercounty,  in  Sweden  and  the  intervening 

opportunities  hypothesis,  65n 
net  interstate  and  the  intervening  opportu- 
nities hypothesis,  65n 
number    of    families    moving    varying    dis- 
tances, 63-64 
step-by-step   character,   40-41,   40n-41n 
time  stage  of,  and  the  labor  market,  40 
see  also  Population  flows 
Mineral  Resources,   see  Natural  resources 
Mobilities,  see  Immobilities 
Moller,    and    spatial    price    discrimination    in 
competitive    equilibrium,    164n 
and  stability  in  competitive  locational  equi- 
librium,  165n 
Monetary  system,  as  a  cultural  institution,  6 

locational  effect  of,  6 
Money,   see  Monetary  system 
Monopolistic    competition     (theory    of),    and 
general  location  theory,   27n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


325 


Monopolistic    competition     (theory    of) — con- 
tinued 

and  price-cost  relations  for  space  analysis, 
49 

and  space  as   a  basic  variable,   24-25,   25n, 
26n,  27n,  50,  54 

and   the  definition   of  industry,   92n 

and    the   friction    of    distance,    38-39 

and  the  isolated  monopolist,   144-145 

and  the  spatial  array  of  markets,  38-41 

Chamberlin's  statement  of,  as  a  particular 
equilibrium   theory,    50n 

equivalence    of    broad    conception    of,    and 
general  location  theory,  50,  54,  254 

in  Losch's  general  equilibrium  framevsrork, 
43-50 

rejection  of,  by  Hicks,  26n 

resemblance  of  Triffin's  approach  and  spa- 
tial substitution,   50 

role   of,    in   determining   hexagonal   market 
areas,   44-45 

Triffin's   general  structure  of  firm  interde- 
pendence, 50n 

Triffin's     use     of,     in     general     equilibrium 
framework,  50,  50n 

value   for   general   location   theory,    49-50 

Weigmann's   version   of,   as   limited   compe- 
tition, 37-39 
Morgenstern,   see   Game   theory 
Multicommodity  framework,  see  Commodities, 

use  of  multicommodity  framework 
Multiplier    effects,    differences    in,    from    dif- 
ferent basic  industry,   284 

local,  from  new  basic  industry,   19 

incorporation  of  in  input-output  analysis, 
49 
Municipal  functions,  and  urbanization  econo- 
mies, 185-186 

relations    with    other    activities    in    urban- 
metropolitan  region,  11-12 

National  boundaries,  see  Political  variable 
National   Bureau   of   Economic   Research  and 

value  of  empirical  inquiry,   77 
National   commodities,    see   Commodities,    na- 
tional 
Natural  law  in  locational  structures  and  the 

the  German  Historical  School,  28n 
Natural  resources,  accessibility  of,  and  trans- 
port innovation,   3 In 
complementarity   of,    and   trade   among  re- 
gions, 22 
effect  on  iron  and  steel  location,  7-8 
geographic    inequalities    of,    and    difficulty 
for  Losch  theory,  48-49,  153 
and  hierarchy  of  flows,  58 
and  need  for  supply  area  analysis,   154 
and  spatial  pattern  of  cities,  58,  60 
and  the  need  to  use  transport  inputs,  255 
and   the    resulting    spatial   spread    of    so- 
ciety,  78,  78n,   84,  255 
and   the   substitution   principle,   34-35 
and  variations  in  local  input  costs,   132- 

133,  202n 
as  affecting  farm  operations,  194n,  202n, 

275 
as  affecting  urban  land  use,  202n 
as  distorting  agricultural  zones,  276 
as  ignored  in  competitive  locational  equi- 
librium   models,    169-170 
effect  on  agricultural  land  use,   18,   194n, 
276-277 


Natural  resources — continued 

effect   on    agricultural   specialization,    18, 

194n 
effect  on  hierarchy  of  sites,  16,  255 
effect  on  hinterlands,   18 
effect  on  market  nets,  16 
effect  on  trade  among  regions,  6,  18,  22, 

75 
implications  for  non-herd  existence,  84 
in  Ohlin's  doctrine,  52 
significance  of,   19n,   194n,   202n,  255 
locational  effect  of,  6,   138-140 
military    and    political    factors    in    the    use 

of,   14 
need   to   study   relations   with   metropolitan 

structure,  287 
uniform    distribution    of,    in    Losch   theory, 

44,  239 
utilization  and  conservation  of,   14 
value  of,  as  related  to  technology,  31n,  258 
see  also  Environment,   physical 
Net  economy   curves,   as   representing   econo- 
mies of  scale,   186-187 
difficulty    in    selecting    representative    ones, 

186-188 
in  power  generation,  184-185 

as   dependent  on   transport  cost,   187-188 
in     providing     diverse    municipal    services, 
186 
as  dependent  on  transport  cost,   188 
in  providing  fire  and  police  protection,  186 
in  providing  recreation  services,   186 
in  providing  sanitation  services,   186 
in  the  use  of  skilled  labor,   185 
in  urban  transit  operation,  186 

as  dependent  on  power  cost,  187-188 
interdependence   of   sets   of,    187-188 

as   a   fruitful  area  for   research,    188 
invalidity  of  summing  procedure,   186-188 
need  for  deeper  analysis  of,  287 
non-additive   character   of,    188 
summing   of,    and   the   problem   of   weight- 
ing,  186-187 
summing  representative  ones  to  derive  ur- 
banization  economies   index,    186-187 
weighting   of,   by  consumption   patterns   of 
city,  188 
by  income  of  city,   187 
by  industrial  composition  of  city,  187 
by  physical  environment  of  city,  188 
by  social  organization  of  city,   188 
Net    farm    price,    as    affected    by    location    of 
farm,   194-195,  244 
as  affecting  farm  output,  190-194 
as  depressed  by  transport  outlays,  205 
definition  of,   190 

effect  on  factor  proportions,   194-195 
equality  with  average  costs  in  equilibrium, 

190-191,   197 
equality  with  marginal  costs  in  equilibrium, 
190-191,  197 
Net   supply   price   and   the   aggregate   supply 

curve,   15on-156n 
New  town  and  size  of  textile  factory,  10 
New  York  as  the  peak  of  population  poten- 
tial, 66-67,  78 
Nodes,  centrality  of,  and  industrial  growth,  8 
hierarchy   of,   within   metropolitan   regions, 
11 
Nuclear  power,  see  Atomic  energy 

Occupational  Immobility,  see  Immobilities 


326 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Ocean  freight  (world),  variation  of,  with  dis- 
tance, 73-75 
Ohlin,  and  equalizing  differences  in  labor  costs 
and  transport-orientation,  127n-128n 

causes  of  interregional  trade,   17 

classification  of  agglomeration  economies, 
172 

concept  of  district,  52 

concept  of  region,  51 

contribution  to  general  location  theory, 
50-53,  208 

criticism  of,  by  Losch,   53n 

limitations  of  his  doctrine,  51-53,  53n 

limitations  of  his  interlocal  trade  theory, 
52n 

outline  of  his   location   approach,   51-52 

trade  theory  as  part  of  a  general  localiza- 
tion theory,   50-54,   208 

trade  theory  of,  formulated  in  more  con- 
crete terms,  217 

use  of  general  interdependence  framework, 
51 

use  of  Weberian  dogma,   52 
Oligopolistic  situations,  and  indeterminacy  of 
firm  locations,  160-171 

as  leading  to  overlapping  areas,  264 

neglect  of,  in  Launhardt-Palander  con- 
struction, 265 

see  also  Game  theory 
Opportunity   costs,   and   the   international   lo- 
cation  of  iron   and   steel,   211-219 

as   relocation   costs,    180 

extension  of,  to  include  transport-oriented 
industries,  211-219 

in  a  transport  input  formulation  to  yield 
superior  approach,  215,   219,   281-282 

need  to  consider  distance  variable  in  cal- 
culating,  211-212 

need  to  consider  transport  inputs  in  calcu- 
lating, 211-214 

need  to  state  labor  cost  differentials  in 
terms  of,   217-219 

need  to  state  labor  orientation  in  terms  of, 
210-219 

need  to  state  location  theory  in  terms  of, 
210-219,   281-282 

need  to  state  transport  cost  diff'erentials  in 
terms   of,   217-219,   281-282 

need  to  state  transport-orientation  in  terms 
of,   210-219,   281-282 

table  of,  in  simple  three  country  case,  211 
Optimum  location  patterns,  alternative  views 
of,  221n-222n 

and  decentralization,   14-15 

and  individual  and  group  space  preferences, 
22-23 

simultaneous  determination  of,  with  opti- 
mum transportation  system,  22  In- 
222n 

use  of  substitution  analysis  to  determine,  36 

with    fixed    transport     facilities     and     rate 

structures,    221n-222n 
see    also    Space-economy  ;    Surplus,    social  ; 
Welfare,  social 
Optimum  spatial  patterns,  see  Optimum  loca- 
tion   patterns  ;    Space-economy,    opti- 
mum ;  Surplus,  social ;  Welfare,  social 
Ore  as  a  localized  raw  material,   19 
Outlay-substitution  lines,  as  incorporating  in- 
terest cost  differentials,  133 
as    incorporating    labor    cost    differentials, 
127-129 


Outlay-substitution    lines — continued 

as  incorporating  material  cost  differentials, 

133 
as    incorporating    more   than    two   differen- 
tials,   136-137,   137n 
as    incorporating    power    cost    differentials, 

131-132 
as   reflecting   for   sites   two   sets   of   outlays 

variables,    127-129 
construction  of,   127-129,   131-132 
for  interest  and  transport  outlays  as  vari- 
ables,  133 
for  labor  and  transport  outlays  as  variables, 

127-129 
for  power  and  transport  outlays   as  varia- 
bles,  131-132 
for  raw  material  and  transport  outlays  as 

variables,   133 
for  transport,  labor  and  interest  outlays  as 

variables,   136-137 
for  two  groups  of  outlays  as  variables,  137, 

137n 
points    on,    correspondence    with    transfor- 
mation  line,   127-128 
possibility  of  positive  slope,   130n 
use  of,  in  analysis  of  scale  economies,  174, 
265 
to  derive  Hotelling's  solution,   170,   170n 
to  determine   equilibrium  point,    129-137, 

259 
to  determine  labor  orientation,  129-131 
to  determine  orientation   to  cheap   mate- 
rial source,   133 
to     determine     orientation     to     point    of 

cheap   capital,    133 
to   determine   power   orientation,   131-132 
with    iso-outlay    Hne,    129-137,    174,    259, 
265 
Outlays,    see   Labor   outlays  ;    Power   outlays ; 
Production    outlays ;    Transport    out- 
lays 
Outlays    and    revenues,    substitution    between, 

see  Substitution  points 
Output,  see  Production 

Palander  (location  analysis  of),  and  autono- 
mous and  "superpolitisch"  trade,  163 

and  categories  of  commodities,  94n 

and  constant  price  fluctuation  when  firms 
near  each  other,   162-163 

and  fusion  of  market  area  analysis  and  in- 
dustrial location,   143n 

and  hinterland  defense,  conditions  for  and 
solution,  163,  163n 

and  inconsistency  of  Hotelling's  agglomera- 
tion,  163n 

and  limitations  of  general  location  theory, 
42-43 

and  market  sharing  policy,  conditions  for 
and  solution,   163,   163n 

and  minor  importance  of  intermediate  loca- 
tion, 108,  108n 

and  occurrence  of  relative  minimum  points, 
108 

and  relaxing  unrealistic  general  equilibrium 
assumptions,  42-43 

and  substitution  possibilities  between  trans- 
port media,   112n 

and  the  Launhardt-Hotelling  problem,  160- 
163 

and  undercutting  policy,  conditions  for  and 
solution,  163,  163n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


327 


Palander     (location    analysis    of) — continued 
contribution  to  general  location  theory,  42- 

43 
criticism   of   Weber's   agglomeration   analy- 
sis,  180 
definition  of  isodapane,  122 
emphasis  of,  on  cost  conditions,   210n 
on  inherited  physical  structures,   180 
on  relocation  cost  in  agglomeration  proc- 
ess,  180 
inapplicability   of   general   equilibrium   the- 
ory to  space-economy,  43 
insistence    on    studying    development    proc- 
esses,  43 
invalid   criticisms   of   Predohl's   substitution 

principle,  95n 
invalidity  of  Hotelling's  solution  for  auton- 
omously trading  firms,  162-163 
localization    economies    as    scale    economies 

with  multiplant  firm,   179n 
outline  of  locational  approach  of,  43 
relative  neglect  of  demand,  210n 
use  of  isodapanes  for  transport-orientation 

solution,   122-124 
use    of    isovector    to    construct    isodapanes, 

122-124 
use  of  pole  principle  for  transport-orienta- 
tion solution,  122,  256-258 
use    of    subset   of    isodapanes    in    isodapane 

technique,   123-124 
see  also   Launhardt-Palander   construction 
Parasitic  industry,  cases  of,  as  exceptions  to 
labor  orientation,   128n 
growth  of,  and  cheap  labor,  8-9,  128n 
locational  tie  to  basic  industry,  8-9,  128n 
Pareto's  law  of  income  distribution  and  simi- 
larity to  rank-size  rule  for  cities,   56 
Partial  equilibrium   location,   see  Equilibrium 

point,   partial 
Pattern   of  settlement,   and   Christaller's   cen- 
tral place  theory,  60,  60n 
and  deglomerative  forces,   78,   84 
and  ecological  processes,  68-70,  144n-145n 
and  geographic  inequalities  of  resources,  78, 

84 
as  related  to  topography,  3 In 
early  stages,  2-7 
general  processes,  1-15,  78 
with  industrialization,  8-15,  31n 
Zipf's  explanation  of,  78n-79n 
see     also     Agricultural     land     use ;     Cities ; 
Population   distribution  ;   Space-econ- 
omy ;  Urban  land  use  ;  Urban-metro- 
politan   region  ;    Urban-metropolitan 
structure 
P/D  factor,  see  Zipf,  the  P/D  factor 
Pi  •  P2/D  factor,  see  Zipf,  the  Pi  •  P2/D  factor 
Pick's   description   of   Varignon's   mechanical 

model,  121 
Pole   principle,   as   a   short  cut   to   determine 
equilibrium  point,   122 
failure  to  identify  transport  costs  as  basic 

economic  force,   122 
use    of,    in    transport-orientation    problem, 
122,    256-258 
Political    variable,    as    reflecting    values    and 
ideals.  287 
effect  of,  on  factor  mobility,  283 

on   geographic   specialization,   283-285 
on  international  locations,  283-285 
on    overall    structure    of    space-economy, 
19n-20n,  283-285,  287 


Political    variable — continued 

on  rank-size  distribution  of  cities,   57n 
on   structure  of   industrial  districts,   283- 

285 
on  trade,   19n-20n,   283-285 
on  urban  land  use,  283-285 
on  urban-metropolitan  structure,  283-285 
see  also  Cultural  values  and  institutions 
Population,    as    basic    variable    in    Stewart's 
social  physics,   65-68 
growth   of,    and    increase   in   spatial   extent 

of  economy,   78 
internal   structure   of   cluster   of,    3,    4,    19- 

20 
nucleus  of,  and  associated  hinterland,  3,  78 
size  of,  and  bus  passenger  movements,  BI- 
OS 
and  railway  express  shipments,  60-61 
and  telephone  messages,   61-62 
spatial  configuration,  3-4 
urban,  different  effects  on  of  different  basic 
industries,  284 
size  of,  as  affecting  commercial  and  serv- 
ice activities,  278 
size  of,  as  affecting  industries  using  ubiq- 
uities, 278 
size  of,  as  related  to  basic  activities,  278 
Population    density,    see    Population    distribu- 
tion 
Population  distribution,   and  nucleation  from 
increasing  returns,  2-3 
and  the  Forces  of  Unification  and  Diversi- 
fication, 78n-79n 
areal,  and  market  analysis,   151-154 
as  related  to  deglomeration  forces,  78 
as  related  to  industrial  distribution,   19-20 
as  related  to  resource  patterns,   58,   60,  78, 

255 
density  of,  as  affected  by  intensity  of  agri- 
cultural land  use,  271 
as  affecting  market  area  size,  271 
as   decreasing  with   distance   from   urban 

core,  68-70,  271-273 
as   related    to   intensity   of   industrial   ac- 
tivity,  271 
as  related  to  transport  network,  272-273 
effect  on  urban  transit  system,   185 
inconsistency     of     Losch's     uniformity     as- 
sumption,  15-16,    153-154,   271 
straight  line,  and  market  analysis,   148-154 
uneven,  and  noncircularity  of  market  areas, 

145-146 
see  also  Rank-size  rule  for  cities 
Population    flows,    association    of,    with    city 
patterns,   281 
with  land  use  patterns,   281 
with  location  patterns,  281 
basic  to  analysis  of  space-economy,  281 
hierarchy  of,  by  volume  and  length,   58 
length  of,  and  size  of  city,  58 
need  for  finer  analysis  of,  287 
variety  of,  in  reality,  281 
volume  of,  and  size  of  city,  58 
see  also  Migration  ;  Population  mobility 
Population    mobility,    changes    in,    and    rural 
population  movement,  88n 
as  reflected  in  dispersion  in  metropolitan 
region,   87-88 
effect  on,  of  aircraft,   12,   87-88 
of  automobile  and  bus,  87-88 
of  street  and  electric  railway,   87-88 
see  also  Immobilities  ;  Population  flows 


328 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Population      potential,      and      deglomeration 
forces,   78,   78n 
and    geographic    inequalities    of    resources, 

78,   78n 
as    an    inverted    measure    of    proximity    to 

people,    66 
cities  as  local  peaks,   66-67 
concept  of,   65-66 
falling   off  with   distance   from  New   York, 

66-67,    78 
linear    relation    of,    with    density    of    rural 
non-farm  population,  68 
with  density  of  rural  population,   68 
with  flow  of  bank  checks,  68 
with  number  of   wage  earners   in  manu- 
facturing,  68 
with  railroad  mileage  per  square  mile,  68 
with   rents   of  rural  non-farm  dwellings, 

68 
with  rural  road  mileage  per  square  mile, 

68 
with  value  of  farmland  per  acre,  68 
population   and  distance  as  basic  variables 

of,   65-66 
problems    of    computation    and    interpreta- 
tion,  66,  66n,  68n 
Stewart's  map  of,  for  United  States,  67 
Port    development,    relation    of,    to    regional 

growth,   9,   10 
Power,     as     a     distorting     factor     in     space- 
economy,    138-140,   260 
as  a  location  factor,  12-13,  131-132,  138-140 
consumption  as  varying  by  type  city,   184 
costs    of,    as    ignored    by    competitive    loca- 
tional   equilibrium   models,    169-170 
as  dependent  on  transport  costs,   187-188 
for  power  intensive  firms  comparable  to 
rent  for  farm  enterprise,  189-190 
economies   of   scale   in   generation    of,    184- 

185,   185n 
generation,     and     urbanization     economies, 

184-185,    185n 
generation  economies,  as  affected  by  degree 
of  system  integration,  185 
as  affected  by  proximity  of  cities,  185 
as  affected  by  size  of  cities,  184-185,  185n 
effect  on  per  capita  consumption,  185n 
generation,    management    diseconomies    in, 

185n 
regularity    in    geographic    cost    pattern,    as 
related   to   transport  cost,    138n-139n 
stable  geographic  cost  pattern,   138 
unsystematic  geographic  cost  pattern,   138, 

202n,  259 
see  also  Power  orientation 
Power    coefficient    as    a    parallel    concept    to 

labor  coefficient,  132n 
Power  cost  savings,   use  of  ratio  of,  to  addi- 
tional transport  outlays,  132n 
Power     inputs     and     substitution     for     other 

inputs   at  cheap   power  site,   132 
Power  orientation,    and   substitution   between 
power  outlays  and  transport  outlays, 
132,   189-190,   259,  275 
as    included     in     extended    trade    doctrine, 

219 
as    involving    additional    transport    outlays, 

132 
as    yielded    by    substitution    principle,    132, 

259,   275 
centi-al   role   of   differentials   in   power   out- 
lays in,  275 


Power    orientation — continued 

critical    isodapane    and   feasibility    of,    132, 

259 
incorporation     of,     in     Launhardt-Palander 

construction,   260 
point  of,  and  use  of  iso-outlay  line,  132 
and  use  of  outlay-substitution  line,   131- 
132 
role  of  replacement  deposits  in,  135 
Power    outlays,    and    transport    outlays,    sub- 
stitution  between    in   power   orienta- 
tion,  132,  189-190,  259,  275 
as  a  variable  in  transport-orientation  anal- 
ysis, 113 
differentials  in,  as  central  to  power  orienta- 
tion, 275 
incorporation    in    an     outlay-substitution 
hne,    131-132 
see   also    Power,    costs    of ;    Power   orienta- 
tion ;   Production   outlays 
Predohl,    and    geographic    inequalities    of    re- 
sources,  34 
and  location  theory  as  price  theory,   32-33 
and  minimum  cost  location,  33-34 
and   the   distribution   of  groups   of  factors, 

32-33 
and  use  units,  34-35 
contribution     to     general     location     theory, 

32-36 
criticism  of  classical  trade  theory,  208 
invalidity  of  Palander's  criticism  of,  95n 
suggested  extensions  of,  35-36,  54 
use  of  the  substitution  principle,  32-36,  54, 
94,   130,   254 
Price    discrimination,    as   leading   to    overlap- 
ping market  areas,   264 
neglect     of,     in     Launhardt-Palander     con- 
struction,   265 
spatial,    and    Lerner   and    Singer's   solution 
in  competitive  locational  equilibrium, 
164n 
as  fostered  by  distance,   164n 
as  fostered  by  geographic  obstacles,  164n 
profitability   of   and   number  of   competi- 
tors,   164n 
Price   equilibrium,   spatial,   as   allied   to   com- 
petitive locational  equilibrium,  167n- 
169n 
as  allied  to  the  Koopmans  transportation 

problem,    167n-169n 
as   related   to   the   general   location   prob- 
lem,   167n-169n 
Beckmann's   formulation  of,   168n 
Samuelson's  formulation  of,   168n 
Price  gradients,  continuous  field  of,  48n 
Price    mark-up,    as    a    relevant    variable    in 
urban    rent   analysis,    200-202,    200n- 
201n 
as  affecting  urban  land  use,  200-201 
as  the  price  of  a  retail  activity,  201n 
effect  on  rent  function,   203-204 
variation  of,  and  sales  volume  curves,   200, 
201n 
Price-ratio    (iso-outlay)    lines,   as   a  series   of 
rectangles   and   squares,    105-112 
as  convex    (concave)    because  of  firm's  in- 
fluence on  price,   159 
as  reflecting  actual  weights,  104 
based    on    I.C.C.    railroad    rate    structures, 

105-112 
change  in  slope  with  change  in  rent,   192- 
194 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


329 


Price-ratio      (iso-outlay)      lines — continued 
changed  content  of,   with  use  of  transport 

inputs  as  variables,  115-116 
convexity  of,  and  end  point  solutions,   107- 
112 
because  of  graduated  rates,   106-107,   120 
effect  on,   of  breaks   in   transport  network, 
110-112 
of  variations  in  transport  rates,  112,  113n 
for  labor  outlays  and  transport  outlays,  129 
for  interest  outlays  and  transport  outlays, 

133 
for    power    outlays    and    transport    outlays, 

131-132 
for    raw    material    and    transport    outlays, 

133 
for  transport,   labor,   and   interest  outlays, 

136-137 
for  two  groups  of  outlays,  137,  137n 
irregularities     in,     and     determination     of 
equilibrium  point,    llOn,   113n 
when  breaks   occur,   11  On 
problems     in     the     construction     of,     when 

breaks   occur,    llOn 
slope  of,  dependence  upon  relative  weights, 

104,   115 
tails  of,  and  end  point  solutions,  107-112 
because  of  large  first  zone  charge,   106- 
108 
under    realistic    rate     structures,     105-112, 

112n-113n 
use  of,  in  analysis  of  scale  economies,  174, 
265 
to  determine  equilibrium  of  farm  enter- 
prise,   192-194 
to  determine  orientation  to  cheap  capital, 

133 
to  determine  orientation   to  cheap  mate- 
rial  source,    133 
to   determine   point  of  labor   orientation, 

129-131 
to   determine   power   orientation,    131-132 
with  iso-product  lines,    192-194 
with    outlay    substitution    lines    to    deter- 
mine equilibrium  point,  129-137,  159, 
174,   259,   265 
with  scale  lines,   192-194 
with    transformation    lines    to    determine 
equilibrium   location,    101-124 
Price  theory,   relation   of,   to  location  theory, 

23,   32,   42n,   49-50 
Prices,     assumed     as     given     in     agricultural 
location  theory,  210n,  243-244,  276 
assumed  as  given  in  Weber's  location  the- 
ory, 222 
changes  of,  effect  on  zonal  pattern,  243 
geographic   pattern   of,   and   effect  on  loca- 
tion,  31,   32,   127-128,   133-135,   254 
interrelatedness   of,   and   locational   equilib- 
rium,   160n 
local,    differences    in,    and    differentials    in 
revenue   potentials,    126n 
and  general  location  theory,  27,  53,  254 
and  international  trade,  51 
as   excluded   in   Launhardt-Palander  con- 
struction,  256 
as  reflecting  different  markets,  43 
as  reflecting  monopoly,  43 
as    reflecting   product  differentiation,    43 
in  Ohlin's  interdependence  system,  51 
market,    changes    in    and    change    in    rent 
functions,    198 


Prices — continued 

changes   in,   to   equate   aggregate  supply 
and  demand,   198 
need   to   consider  changes   in,   in   a   general 

agricultural  system,  243 
weakness    of    assumptions    on,    in    agricul- 
tural location   theory,   243 
see     also     Costs ;     Factor     costs ;     Pricing 
system 
Pricing  policy,   and  need  for  sharply  defined 
concept  of  rational  behavior,  286 
differences     in,     and     overlapping     market 

boundaries,   264 
neglect     of,     in     Launhardt-Palander     con- 
struction,  265 
realistic,  need  for  in  competitive  locational 

equilibrium  models,   169,  286 
see  also.  Pricing  system 
Pricing  system  (s),  as  a  cultural  institution,  6 
changes  in,  effect  on  cost  curves,   150n 
effect  on  margin   line,   149n-150n,   150 
effect  on  market  size,  149n-150n 
effect  on  sales,  149n-150n 
locational  effect  of,  6,  20,  21 
spatial,   and   competitive  locational  equilib- 
rium,   158-171 
see  also  Prices  ;  Pricing  policy 
Primary  industry,  see  Basic  industry 
Principle   of   Least   Effort,   and   stable   inter- 
action over  distance,  60 
use  of,  to  explain  spatial  framework,  78n- 
79n 
Product  differentiation,   and  spatial  position, 
27n 
as  a  reflection  of  differences  in  local  prices, 
43 
Production,     allocation     of,     as     affected     by 
changes    in    transport    rates,     156n- 
157n 
to  several  market  points,   156n-157n 
concentration  of,  as  affecting  market  area 
size,  271 
as  affecting  population  density,  271 
as  likely  at  initial  location,   174n,   180 
as  related  to  level  of  transport  rate,  87 
as    related    to    transport    network,    272- 

273 
as  socially  desirable,  174 
with  economies  of  scale,   173-176 
pattern  of,  in  a  simple  three-country  trade- 
location   example,   214-219 
point    of    concentration,    and    substitution 
between    transport   outlays   and    pro- 
duction  outlays,    174-175 
spatial    extent    of,    and    relations    between 
direct  and  indirect  labor,  82n 
and   the   use   of   transport   inputs,    81-82, 

255 
as  affected  by  the  interest  rate,  88n-89n 
as  related  to  capital  intensity,  253 
cumulative  growth  in,  82n 
increase  in  from  a  fall  in  transport  rate, 

87,   255 
limitations  to  increase  in,   86 
time  extent  of,  and  relations  between  direct 
and  indirect  labor,  82n 
and  the  use  of  capital  inputs,  82 
cumulative  growth  in,   82n 
Production    coefficients    assumed    as    fixed    in 

Weberian  location  theory,   222 
Production    outlays,    and    revenues,    substitu- 
tion between  from  crop  shifts,  197 


330 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Production    outlays — continued 

and     transport     outlays,     substitution     be- 
tween, and  concentration  of  produc- 
tion,   197 
and  localization,  179,  179n,  182,  267 
and  optimum  size  of  firm,   175n-176n 
and  social  welfare,   182,   262 
and  urbanization,  188,  269 
as    induced    by    economies    of    scale,    174, 

265,   267 
in    determining    point    of    agglomeration, 

174-175,   267,   269 
in  Hotelling's  problem,   170n 
in  location   of  marketing  establishments, 
175n 
at  several  sources,  substitution  among  and 

social  welfare,  155-157,  262 
differentials  in,  and  the  use  of  Launhardt- 

Palander   construction,   260 
effect    on,     of    competition    in     land     uses, 
286 
of  complementarity  of  land  uses,  200,  280 
for    two    producers,    substitution    between, 
and  Losch  location  theory,   153-154 
substitution  between,  and  market  bound- 
ary formation,   148-154,   260-261 
marginal  rate  of  substitution  between,  and 

market  boundary  formation,   148 
relations  by  type  of,  via  substitution  prin- 
ciple, 259 
relations    with    labor   outlays    via    substitu- 
tion principle,   259 
substitution   between,   and   location   equilib- 
rium, 159 
and  optimum  size  of  firm,   175n-176n 
from  crop  shifts,   197 
Production   processes,   as  a  determinant  of  a 
population  cluster,   19-20 
conditions  for  geographic  split  of,  20 
split  of,  and  interindustry  linkage,  20-21 
and  relation  to  trade,  20 
and  technological  advance,  20 
total    set    of,     as    a    complex    substitution 
problem  in  space,   94-95,  95n 
Production    sites,    as    potential   market    sites, 
250n 
as  potential  raw  material  sources,  250n 
finite  number  of,  as  a  special  case  of  zonal 

cultivation,  250n 
number  of  intervening,  as  affected  by  size 

of  concentrations,  273 
rich  and  poor  sectors  of,  in  Losch  scheme, 

270-273 
size  of,  as  affecting  number  of  intervening 

sites,   273 
see  also  Location 
Production  theory,  and  location  theory,  fusion 
of  via  general  location  principle,  23, 
252-253,  286 
fusion  of  via  substitution  principle,   113, 

118-119,  221,  252-253,  255,  259,  286 
need  to  spell  out  fusion  in  detail,  286 
parallel  use  of  substitution,   135-137,  255 
similarity  of  first  and  second  order  con- 
ditions,  118 
as  embracing  economies  of  scale,   176 
extension    to    include    location    factor    via 

transport  inputs,   91,    118-119,   252 
integration   of   agglomeration    theory   with, 

172-188 
substitution   processes    in,    135-137 
transport  cost  as  a  variable  in,  26n 


Profits,  maximization  of,  as  basic  to  general 
location  theory,  221n 
as  transport  cost  minimization  in  trans- 
port-orientation, 222-223 
surplus,    elimination    by    competition,    196, 

196n-197n,   202 
validity    of    principle    of    maximization    of, 

221n 
see  also  Surplus,  social 
Pure    competition,    inapplicability    to    space- 
economy,  37-38,   43,   158-159 
inconsistency  with  location  theory,  37-38 
inconsistency  with  transport  cost,  43 
norms    of,    as    meaningless   for   space-econ- 
omy,  50n 
Pure     material,     possibility     of     location     at 
source  of,   121-122,   225n 
underestimate  of  pull  of,  by  Weber,  225n 

Quantity  elasticity,  definition  of,   42n 

Radial      transport      routes,      see      Transport 

routes,    radial 
Railroad  shipments,  Class  I,  variation  of  with 
distance,  70-73 
by  type  I.C.C.  commodity  group,  72n 
Railway  express  shipments,  and  the  Pi-P2/D 
factor,  60-61 
variation     with    population     and     distance, 
60-61 
Railway  passenger  movements,  variation  with 

population  and  distance,  62n 
Rank     of    cities     and    sites,     see    Hierarchy ; 

Rank-size  rule  for  cities 
Rank-size   rule   for   cities,   empirical   findings 
on,  Austro-Hungary,  57n 
Canada,   57n 
France,   57n 
Germany,  57n 
India,  57n 

United  States,  56-57,  57n 
implications  of  findings  on,  for  regularities 
associated     with     distance     variable, 
57-60 
mathematical  formulation,  55-56 
similarity   to    Pareto's    law   of    income   dis- 
tribution,  56 
universality  of,  57 
validity  of,  57 

Zipf's    interpretation    of    deviations    from, 
57n 
Rationality,  and  unnecessary  distance,  96-97, 
97n,   lOln,   107,   113n 
in  behavior  and  game  theory,  160,  166,  265, 

286 
in  behavior,  difficulties  of  identifying,   160, 

265,   267,   286 
in    location    decisions,    need    to   study   rela- 
tions   with    metropolitan    structure, 
287 
in  site  selection,  2 
need  to  sharply  define  and  apply  to  location 

theory,  286 
similar  degrees  of,  in  agricultural  location 
and  urban  land  use  theory,  205 
Raumwirtschaft,  contributions  to,  by  German 

Historical  School,  27 
Ravenstein     and     migration     as    varying    in- 
versely with  distance,   64n 
Raw  material (s),  cheap  source  of,  as  a  loca- 
tion factor,   133 
conception  of,  274n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


331 


Eaw    material  (s) — continued 

sources  of  supply,  and  effect  on  economies 
of  scale,    175n-176n 
as   affected   by  economies   of  scale,   175n- 

176n 
effect  on  location,   175n-176n 
effect   on    substitution    points,    175n-176n 
sources,  see  Supply  sources 
supply    of,    as   distorting   concentric    zones, 
248 
effect  on  agricultural  land  use  patterns, 
248-249 
use  of  new  sources  in  agglomeration,   178 
see  also  Localized   raw  materials  ;   Natural 
resources ;     Supply     area     analysis ; 
Supply   sources 
Raw  material  outlays,  as  ignored  in  competi- 
tive   locational    equilibrium    models, 
169-170 
attraction  of  source  of  cheap,  as  involving 

discrete  spatial  jump,   133 
differentials  in,  incorporation  in  an  outlay- 
substitution  line,   133 
see  also  Factor  costs ;  Production  outlays  ; 
Raw  materials 
Region  (s),  changes  in  geographic  specializa- 
tion  of,   22 
complementarity  of  resources  of,  22 
concept  of,   as  a  competition  field,  38-41 
effect   of   advance    in   transport   technology 

on,  22 
hierarchical      order      of      trade      relations 

among,   22 
hierarchy  of,  22 

use   with   input-output   analysis,   49 
impact  of  atomic  energy  on,  13 
interrelations   of,   21-22 
location  analysis  of,  as  a  level  of  inquiry, 

92 
locational  shifts  within,   22 
Ohlin's  concept  of,  51 

planning  of,  and  changes  in  the  hierarchy 
of  cities,  183 
and  control  of  land  use  intensities,   183 
and  control  of  traffic,  183 
fundamental  questions   in,   9-15 
optimum  hierarchy   of   cities,   183 
optimum  spatial  distribution  of  city,  183 
validity  of  Weber's  agglomeration  analy- 
sis for,   181-182 
processes  in  development  of,  1-15,  22 
trade  among,  22 
trade  within,  22 

see    also    City-regions ;    Regional    analysis ; 
Space-economy ;    Urban-metropolitan 
region 
Regional  analysis,   and   need  for  research  on 
interdependence  of  sets  of  net  econ- 
omy curves,   188 
as  aUied  to  the  general  market-transporta- 
tion-location   problem,    167n-169n 
as     bearing     upon     agricultural     location 

theory,    199 
as  bearing  upon  equilibrium  land-use  pat- 
terns, 199 
as  interrelated  with  firm  and  income  analy- 
sis,  159n-160n,   199 
as  required  to  specify  total  restraints,   199 
Losch  theory  as  a  point  of  departure  for, 

153-154 
need   to   modify    Losch's   simplified    frame- 
work, 153-154 


Regional    analysis — continued 

use  of  activity  analysis  in,   168n-169n 

see  also  Regional  Science  ;  Space-economy  ; 

Urban-metropolitan    region  ;    Urban- 
metropolitan  structure 
Regional  income,  see  Income,  regional 
Regional  science,   activity  analysis  as  an  ele- 
ment of,   169n,  287 
as     involving     study     of     regional     income, 

resources    and    consumption     as    re- 
straints,  287 
as     involving     study     of     restraints     upon 

urban-metropolitan    structure,    287 
gravity  models  as  an  element  of,  287 
gross    regional    product    projections    as    an 

element   of,   287 
industrial  complex   analysis   as   an   element 

of,  287 
interregional    input-output    as    an    element 

of,   287 
need  to  study  space-economy  as  a  hierarchy 

of  focal  points,  287 
need  to  study  substitution  in  the  large,  287 
Reilly's  law  of  retail  gravitation  and  relation 

to  demographic  force,  65n 
Relative-maximum,     concept     of,     see     Basic 

form  of  space-economy 
Relative  minimum    points,    and   procedure   to 

determine     equilibrium     point,     108, 

108n,   124n,  229-230 
occurrence  of,  in  transport-orientation,  108, 

108n,   124n,   133,  229-230,  251 
Relocation,  see  Locational  shifts 
Relocation   costs,   and  game  theory,   180-181, 

181n 
as  affecting  collusive  action,  181n 
as    deviating    agglomeration    from    optimal 

transport  point,   180-181 
as  excessive,  for  urban  relocation,   183 
as   opportunity   costs,    180 
as  reflected  in  immobilities,   283n 
significance  of,   in  agglomeration  analysis, 

180-181,  181n 
Rent(s),  and  supply  area  analysis,   155n 
and   the  process   of   elimination   of   surplus 

profits,   196n-197n,   202 
as  affected  by  location  of  farm,  194-195 
as  an  explicit  cost  in  cost  curves,  191,  193- 

194 
as   generated   by   competition   in   land   use, 

158,    202-206 
central    role    of,    in    agricultural    location 

theory,   189-199,  275,  280 
in   urban   land  use   theory,   202-206,   275, 

280 
determination   of,   and   the  entry   and   exit 

of   producers,    196n-197n,   202 
determination    of    payments    of,    for    firm, 

190-194,   202-206 
determination  through  substitution  between 

transport  inputs,  246n 
effect  of  interest  rate  on,  88n-89n 
effect  on  farm  output  when  zero,   190-191 
emphasis    on    maximization    of,    with    fixed 

prices  in  agricultural  location  theory, 

210n 
for  farm  enterprise  as  comparable  to  labor 

cost    of    labor    intensive    firms,    189- 

190,   275 
for  farm  enterprise  as  comparable  to  power 

cost  of  power   intensive   firms,   189- 

190,  275 


332 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Rent  (s )  — continued 

inadequate    treatment    of    space    in    tradi- 
tional analysis  of,   25n 
interrelations  with  factor  proportions,  192- 

194,    197,   275 
interrelations    with    scale    of    output,    192- 

194,  197,    275 

marginal,  equation  of,  in  determination  of 
zonal  boundaries,   247 

maximum  for  each  site,  as  insured  by  com- 
petition, 196,  197 

rise  in,   and  deglomeration,   139,   183 
and  urban  diseconomies,   183,   186 

social,  conditions  for  maximization  of,  245- 
251 
maximization  of  as  affected  by  raw  mate- 
rial supply,  248 
maximization      of      in      fused      location- 
market-supply    framework,    250-251 
substitution  between  transport  inputs  in 

maximizing,    246 
use    of    rent    functions    in    maximizing, 
245-247 

see    also    Rent    functions ;    Rent    outlays ; 
Urban   land   price 
Rent    functions    (marginal),    as    applying   to 
crop   combinations,    199,   276 

as  basic  to  agricultural  location  and  urban 
land  use  theory,  205,  280 

as     determining    patterns     of     agricultural 
land  use,  195,   197-199,  246,  276 

as  determining  spread   of  urban   activities, 
204-205,   280 

as     identical    with    Dunn's     industry    rent 
function,    195n 

as    identical    with    Hoover's    rent    surface, 
195n 

as  involving  rent  surfaces  in  the  area  case, 
205n 

as    reflecting    adjustments    of    farm    enter- 
prise,   197,    275-276 

as  related  to  farm  locations,   194-195,  276 

as    related    to    the    distance    variable,    194- 

195,  197,   201-205,   244 

as    restricting    an    activity    to    a    relatively 

few  sites,   204-205 
as  varying,  by  type  crop,  195,  197-199,  276 

by  type  urban  land  use,   203-205 
as  yielded  by  the  substitution  principle,  276 
derivation  of,  194-195,  197,  201-204,  244 
effect  on,  of  advertising  outlays,  203-204 
of  competition,   204-205 
of   complementarity,   204-205 
of  price  mark-up,  203-204 
of  product  and  service  quality,  203-204 
intersection  of,  as  determining  zonal  bound- 
aries, 247,  276 
secondary  peaks  in,  and  secondary  peaks  of 
sales   volume,   203 
at  satellite  centers,   203 
shift  of,  from  change  in  market  price,  198 

to  equate  supply  and  demand,  198 
straight  line,  invalidity  of,   195n 
system  of,  with  multiple  markets,  198-199 
transition  from  line  to  area  situation,  205n 
use  of  cost  curves  to  determine,  201-205 
use    of    sales    volume    curves    to   determine, 

201-205 
use  of,   to  determine  urban   land  use,   204- 
205,   276,   280 
to  identify   Thiinen   rings,   195,    198,   246, 
276 


Rent    functions    (marginal) — contintied 

when  intensity  of  land  use  invariant  with 
distance,   195n 
Rent  outlays,  and  other  outlays,  substitution 
between,  in  operation  of  farm  enter- 
prise,  193-196,   196n,   275 
substitution  between,   in  urban  land  use, 
205-206,  276 
and    revenue     potentials,     substitution    be- 
tween, in  urban  land  use,  206 
and  transport  outlays,  substitution  between 
in  farm  enterprise  location,   189-190. 
196,   196n,   275 
as  proportional  to  land-use  units,  34-35 
differentials  in,  as  a  location  factor,  133 
as    basic    to    agricultural    firm    location, 
189-190,    194-199.    275 
see  also  Rent 
Rent    surfaces,    as    a    generalized    rent    func- 
tion,  205n 
use  of,  to  depict  areal  land  values,  205n 
Rent  theory,  see  Agricultural  location  theory  ; 
Rent ;    Rent   functions  ;   Urban   land- 
use   theory 
Replacement   deposits,    as    affecting   point   of 
agglomeration,    178 
handling    of,    as    a    phase    of    supply    area 

analysis,   131n 
increasing  role  of,  with  increase  of  devia- 

tional  distance,   141 
role  of,  in  labor  orientation,  ISln,  135.  141 
Residential  land  use,  see  Urban  land  use 
Resources,    see    Natural    resources ;    Human 

resources 
Retail  sales,   decrease  of,  with  distance  from 
urban   core,    68-70 
importance   in   urban   structure,   200n-201n 
Revenue-outlay  substitution  line,   as   incorpo- 
rating  more   than   two   differentials, 
136-137 
as    incorporating    revenue   potential   differ- 
entials,  134 
as  reflecting  for  sites  the  revenue  potential 

and  outlays  variables.   134 
construction  of,   134,   135n 
for  revenue  potential  and  transport  outlays 

as  variables,   134 

movement  along  in  Hotelling's  solution.  170 

use  of,   in  analysis  of  scale  economies,   175 

to  derive  Hotelling's  solution,  170,   170n 

to  determine  equilibrium  point,   134-135. 

159 
to   determine   orientation   to   higher-price 

market,   134-135 
with  iso-revenue-less-outlay  line,  134-135, 
159 
Revenue  potentials,  and  rent  outlays,  substi- 
tution   between,    in    urban    land    use, 
206 
as  affected  by  transport  outlays   (time-cost) 

by  consumer,   205 
differentials  in,  and  substitution.   126,  126n 
as  a  location  factor,   126-137 
incorporation  in  revenue-outlay  substitu- 
tion line,   134-135 
net,  determination  of  maximum,   159 
differences  in  at  different  locations,   159 
Revenue-substitution    lines,    as    incorporating 
more  than  two  differentials,  136-137, 
137n 
use  of,  to  determine  firm  equilibrium  loca- 
tion.  136-137 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


333 


Revenues,  substitution  between,  see  Substitu- 
tion  points 

Riemann  integral,  use  of,  in  agricultural 
location   analysis,   245n 

Ritschl  and  the  evolutionary  approach,  15, 
30n 

Roscher  and  the  evolutionary  approach,  15, 
28n 

Sales  revenue,  changes  in,  along  substitution 

paths,   246,  246n 
Sales  volume,  as  affected  by  transport  outlays 
(time-cost)    by  consumers,  205 
as  falling  with  distance  from  core,  68-70 
curves  of,  under  different  assumptions,  200- 
201 
with   n-variables,   201n 
desirability   of  measuring  in   dollars,  200n- 

201n 
effect  of  complementarity  of  land  uses  on, 

200 
secondary   peaks   of,   and   need   for  general 
equilibrium   approach,   201n 
and   secondary  peaks   in   rent  functions, 

203 
as  affected  by  complementarity,  201n 
as   identifiable   when   urban   pattern   set, 

201n 
at  different  distances  from  core,  201 
difficulty    to    identify    with    fluid    urban 
pattern,   201n 
use  of  curves  of,  to  determine  rent  func- 
tions,  201-205 
variations  of,  at  different  locations,  200-201 
with  distance  from  core,  200-201 
Samuelson,  and  discontinuities  in  the  produc- 
tion function,   103n,   118 
and  dynamic  stability  properties  of  a  gen- 
eral equilibrium  system,  43n 
and  extension  of  the  Enke  solution  to  many 

regions,   168n 
and  the  Koopmans  transportation  problem 
as    contained    in    the    Enke    market 
problem,  168n 
and    the     neglect   of     certain    basic    loca- 
tional    forces    in    market-transporta- 
tion  model,   168n-169n 
needed   extension   of   market-transportation 
model  for  location   analysis,   168n 
Satellite  cities,   see  Cities,   satellite 
Scale  effect,  and  consumer  behavior,  87-88 
and    the    dispersion    of    urban    population, 

87-88 
from  a  fall  of  transport  rate,  87-88,  255 
from  increase  in  population  mobility,  87-88 
Scale  lines,  definition  of,   191n 

use  of,  in  agricultural  location  theory,  191- 
194 
with  iso-product  curves,   191-194 
with  price-ratio  lines,   192-194 
Scale  of  output,  analysis  of,  for  agricultural 
firm,   190-194 
as  a  variable  in  the  Enke  market  problem, 

168n 
as    fixed    in   the   Koopman's   transportation 

problem,  168n 
interrelations   with  rent,    192-194,   197,   275 
see  also  Economies  of  scale 
Schaffle   and   the   evolutionary   approach,    15, 

28n 
Schneider,  and  price  policy  for  spatially  fixed 
competitors,  160n 


Schneider — continued 

and  spatial  price  discrimination  in  competi- 
tive equilibrium,   lG4n 
Scrap  and  iron  and  steel  location,  10,  118n 
Secondary    industry,    and    location    analysis, 
21 
as  related  to  basic  industry,  8-9,  19,  128n, 

278 
relation  of,  to  agricultural  stratum,  7 
see  also  Service  activities 
Sectors,  city-rich  and  city-poor,  270-273 
industrial,  pattern  of,  278-280 
interdependence     of,     and     decentralization 
policy,   13-15 
and   Weigmann's  basic   form,   39-42 
in  a  general  location  theory,  26-27 
meaningful    urban-metropolitan,    13-14 
urban-metropolitan,  as  related  to  transport 
network,  271-273 
in  a  modified  Losch  diagram,  272 
in  Losch's  diagram,   270 
Self-sufficiency  as  related  to  distance  factor,  5 
Service    activities,    as    basic    urban    industry, 
274n-275n 
as  related  to  urban  income,  278 
as  related  to  urban  population,  278 
differential  effects  on,  of  different  basic  in- 
dustries, 284 
effect  of  basic  activities  on,  19,  19n,  278 
location     of,     and     applicability     of     Losch 

theory,   154,  274 
market     oriented     plus     localized     material 
using    activities    as    yielding    metro- 
politan   structure,    274-275,    278-280 
quality  of,  as  affecting  cost  functions,  203- 
204 
as  affecting  rent  functions,  203-204 
as  affecting  urban  land  use,  200-201 
spatial  pattern  of,  as  affected  by  basic  in- 
dustry, 278n 
structure  within  metropolitan  region,  12 
Service    receipts,    decrease   of,   with   distance 

from  urban   core,   68-70 
Settlement,  see  Pattern  of  settlement 
Shopping  trip   patterns,  as  basic  to  analysis 
of  space-economy,  281 
effect  on  urban  land  use,  281 
Short-run  trade  theory,   see  Trade  theory 
Side     payments,     use     of,     in     agglomeration 
theory,   179n,  180-181,   181n 
in  game  theory,  180-181,  181n 
Site  selection  effect,  among  cities,  8-9,  19 
in  national  commodity  production,   17-18 
among  port  sites,  9 
and  aircraft,   12 
and  technological  advance,  12 
and  transport  development,   12 
from  a  faU  in  transport  rate,  67 
Site  selection  for  initial  habitation,  2 
Skilled  labor,  see  Labor,  skilled 
Smithies,  competitive  locational  solutions  with 
linear  demands,  164 
effect  of  changes  in  marginal  cost  on  com- 
petitive equilibrium,  165n 
hinterland   demand   as   a  function  of  price 

and   location,    164 
spatial  price  discrimination  in  competitive 

equilibrium,    164n 
types  of  competitive  behavior,  164n-165n 
Social  physics,  see  Stewart 
Social  surplus,   see   Surplus,   social ;   Welfare, 
social 


334 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Social  welfare,   see   Surplus,   social ;   Welfare, 

social 
Soil  characteristics,  effect  of,  on  agricultural 

land  use,   276-277 
on  settlement  pattern,   2,   3,   5 
Sources,  raw  material,  see  Supply  sources 
Sources,  supply,  see  Supply  sources 
Space,   and   overemphasis   of  interdependence 

of  game  theory  reactions,   167 
and  principle  of  limited  competition,  37-39 
and   product  differentiation,   27n 
as  a  basic  factor,  24-27,  76 
as  a  cause  of   immobilities,   37-38 
as  a  monopoly  element,   54 
basic    role    in    agricultural   location    theory, 

189-199 
importance    internally    to    firm,    189 
In   monopolistic   competition   theory,   24-25, 

25n,  26n,  27n,  50,  54 
limit  of,  as  precluding  analysis  of  systems 

of  supply   areas,    158 
neglect   of,   in   economic   theory,   24-27,   33, 

42 
in  rent  theory,  25n 
in  trade  theory,  25n,  26 
see  also  Distance  ;  Distance  variable 
Space  axis,  need  for,  in  analysis,  77-78 
Space  discount,  as  contrasted  with  time  dis- 
count, 85-86 
associated    with    concept    of    transport    in- 
puts, 255 
in    market    and    purchasing    area    analysis, 

85,  85n 
in  terms  of  situation  advantage,  85n 
rate  of,  as  synonymous  with  transport  rate, 

85 
to  compare  items  spatially  separated,   85 
Space-economy,   a  diagram   of   Losch's   struc- 
ture of,  270 
a  modified  Losch  diagram  of,  272 
as   a  hierarchical  set  of  focal  points,   230, 

251,  287 
as  a  hierarchy  of  centers,  273 
as  discontinuous  in  reality,  251 
as  distorted  by  labor,  power,  interest,  taxes, 

and   other  factors,    138-140 
as    reflecting    a    multi-punctured    transport 

cost   surface,    230,    251 
basic    structure    of,    as    implied    by    spatial 

regularities,  75-76,  254 
changes    in    pattern    of,    with    changes    in 

technology,   7.   10-13,   258-259 
changes  of  structure  of,  with  economies  of 

scale,  265-267 
with  localization   economies,   268 
with     urbanization     economies,     269-270, 

273-274 
continuous,    as    implied    by    most    location- 
market  analyses,   251 
development  processes  in,   1-15 
efiBcient    operation     of,     need    to     consider 

transport    inputs    in,    35-36,    79-80, 

80n,  252 
flow  phenomena  as  basic  to,  281 
focal  points  of,  need  for  improved  analysis 

of,  287 
general    theory     of,     see     General    location 

theory 
hierarchy    of   flows    in,    need   for   improved 

analysis  of,  287 
interaction  phenomena  in,  need  for  deeper 

study  of,  287 


Space-economy — continued 
need    for    deeper    study    of    social    forces 

within,  287 
need  to  study  welfare  aspects  of,  287 
optimum,    as    implying    hexagonal    market 
areas  with  Losch's  postulates,  242n- 
243n 
as   involving  nonhexagonal  market  areas 

in  a  general  case,  242n-243n 
several  views  of,  221n-222n 
use  of  marginal  cost  to  identify,   236n 
order   in,    and    regular   variation    of    trans- 
port cost  with  distance,  138-140,  210 
physical  structure  of,  as  affecting  agglom- 
eration,  180 
as  giving  rise  to  relocation  costs,   180 
realistic,    as    involving    hierarchy    of    trade 
routes,  251,  287 
as  involving  substitution  in  the  large,  251 
sector    structure    of,    and    interrelation    of 
size  and  number  of  production  sites, 
272-273 
sketch  of  agricultural  land  use  in,  276-278 
sketch    of,    as    fusion    of    modified    Losch 
market  system  and  agricultural  land- 
use   pattern,    272,    277-278 
sketch  of  urban  land-use  patterns  in,  278- 

280 
sketches   of   commodity   flows   in,   282,   284, 

285 
structure  of,   as  affected  by  political  vari- 
able, 282-285,  287 
as  fusion  of  modified  Launhardt-Palander 

and   Losch  schemes,   274-275 
as  governed  by  general  location  principle, 

286 
as  localized  material  using  activities  plus 
market-oriented     activities,     274-275, 
278-280 
as  precluding  regular  hexagons,  274n 
as  related  to  transport  network,  272-273 
need  of  activity  analysis  to  study,   287 
need  of  gravity  models  to  study,  287 
need    of    gross    regional    product    projec- 
tions to  study,  287 
need    of    industrial    complex    analysis    to 

study,  287 
need     of     interregional     input-output     to 

study,  287 
need  for  superior  concepts  to  understand, 

287 
need    to    develop    operational    models    of, 
287 
use    of    substitution    principle    to    analyze, 

254 
Weigmann's  basic  form  of,  38-42 
see  also  Agricultural  land  use  ;  Urban  land 
use ;     Urban-metropolitan     structure 
Space   preference (s),    and   centrifugal   move- 
ment,  84-85,   87-88 
and   general   location   theory,    22-23 
and  hierarchy  of  sites,   16 
and  market  nets,   16 
and  optimal  spatial  patterns,  23 
and  rural  population  shifts,  88n 
and  the  gregarious  instinct,   84-85 
and   urban-metropolitan   structure,    11,    87- 

88,  287 
as    acquired    behavior   patterns,    84-85 
as  contrasted  with  time  preference,  83-85 
by  income  groups,   88n 
changes  in,  from  technological  advance,  13 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


335 


Space    preference  (s) — continued 

consumer,   and   explanation   of  spatial  pat- 
tern  of   population,    144-145 
and   explanation   of  transport   inputs   in- 
curred,  144-145 
degree  of,   and  extroverts,   84-85 

and  introverts,  84 
differences  in,  by  type  environment,   85n 

by  type  social  activity,  85n 
effect  on  location,  21,  22-23,  78 
effect  on,   of  aircraft,   13 
of  atomic  energy,  13 
of  transport  cost   level,    19n 
effect  on  trade,  22-23 

implications   of,    for   herd    existence,    84 
of  groups  and  location  theory,  22-23 
need  for  deeper  study  of,  287 
negative  and  hermits,   84 
relation    of,    to   transport   inputs,    255 
Spatial   arrangement,   symbols   of,   in   Losch's 

model,  45-46 
Spatial  coordinates,  in  a  general  location  sys- 
tem, 54 
in  Losch's  model,  45-46 
replacement  of,  by  transport  inputs,  35-36, 

Spatial  extent  of  production,  see  Production, 

spatial  extent  of 
Spatial  inelasticities,  see  Inelasticities,  spatial 
Spatial   lengthening   of    production,    see    Pro- 
duction,  spatial  extent  of 
Spatial    pattern    of    cities,   see   Cities,    spatial 

pattern  of 
Spatial    price    equilibrium,     see     Competitive 

locational    equilibrium  ;    Prices 
Spatial    i-egularities,    and    transport    costs    as 
function  of  distance,  35,  138-140,  210 
as  associated  ■with,  distance  variable,   254 
as   implying  basic  structure  to  space-econ- 
omy,  75-76,   254 
distortion    of,    by    labor,    power,     interest, 
taxes,     and     other     factors,     138-140, 
194n,  202n 
of  flow  phenomena,  57-76 
within  the  metropolitan  region,  68-70 
Squares,    as   inferior   to   regular   hexagons   as 
market   forms,    44,    153,    241-242 
as  satisfying  boundary  conditions,  153,  241- 

242 
in  Losch  scheme,  44,  153,  241-242 
Stability,  case  of  absence  of,  with  scale  econ- 
omies, 174n 
in     competitive     locational     equilibrium     as 
related  to  market  discontinuity,   165, 
165n 
in  farm  equilibrium,  193-194 
in   Hotelling's   problem,    160-162,   170 
Stability    conditions,    see    Equilibrium    point 

(for  firm  location) 
Stages     of    production,     locational     interrela- 
tions   of,    and    interindustry    linkage, 
20-21 
Statics  in  Weigmann's  location  theory,  38-41 
Steam-steel  complex,  emergence  of,   8 
Steel  fabricating  activities,  agglomeration  of, 
8 
location  with  respect  to  steel,  8 
Steel  industry,  see  Iron  and  steel  industry 
Stewart,  and  concept  of  demographic  energy, 
65 
and   concept  of  demographic   force,    65 
and  concept  of  population  potential,  65-66 


Stewart — continued 

and  social  physics,  65-68,  78 

map    of    population    potential    for    United 

States,  67 
problems    in    computing    population    poten- 
tials, 66,  66n,  68n 
Stieltjes   integral,    use   of,    in   agricultural   lo- 
cation analysis,  245n 
in  market  area  analysis,   233n 
Storage     costs,     transport     costs     contrasted 

with,  86n 
Stouffer,   distance,   migration,   and   the   inter- 
vening opportunities  hypothesis,  64n- 
65n 
number    of    families    moving    varying    dis- 
tances, 63-64 
Straight  line,  as  market  boundary,   146,   151- 
153,   154,   239,  240,   241,  261,   274n 
as  supply  area  boundary,   157 
Strata,  interrelations  of,  and  city  growth,  29 
and   Weigmann's  basic   form,   39-42 
and  zone  formation,  29 
in  early  development,  7-8 
need  for  general  rules,  30 
Street  and  electric  railway,  and  dispersion  of 
urban   population,   87-88 
effect  on  metropolitan  structure,  87-88 
Subregions,   use  of,   in   Ohlin's   analysis,    52n, 

53 
Subsidization,   see   Government   subsidy 
Substitution  (s),   as  subject  to  transport  cost 
restraints,    98-101,    lOln 
change    in    paths    of,    with    introduction    of 

raw  material  supply  areas,  235 

in    the    large,    existence    in    space-economy, 

94,  95n,  130n,  133,  176n,  196,  251,  254 

inadequate   recognition   of,   251-252,    287 

need  to  study  in  regional  science,  287 

in    the    selection    among   destinations   for   a 

commodity,  94 
in    the    small,    existence    in    space-economy, 
94,   130n,  251,   254 
in   demarcating   market   areas,   251 
in  demarcating  supply  areas,   251 
in   the  use  of  different  commodities   in   the 
production  process,  94 
the   use   of  several   sources   of  one  com- 
modity, 94 

in  the  use  of  weight-losing  commodities,  94 
limits   to,   in    input-output   analysis,   49 
paths   of,    as    changing   with   conception    of 
social  surplus,  234-235 
as     involving    changes     in     average    unit 

costs,  246-247 
as    involving    changes    in    crop    revenues, 

246,   246n 
as  involving  changes  in  intensity  of  cul- 
tivation, 246-247 
as  involving  changes  in  transport  outlays 

on  crops,   246,   246n 
as    involving    zonal   shifts,    246-247 
in    agricultural    location    theory,    246-251, 

276 
to   farm  equilibrium,   193n-194n 
possible  types  of  and  classification  of  com- 
modities, 94 
process  of,  as  identical  for  both  agricultural 
and    industrial    firms,     189-190.    199, 
275 
spatial,  and  resemblance  to  Triffin's  substi- 
tution analysis,  50 
allowance  for  via  bill  of  goods  change,  49 


336 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Substitution  (s) — continued 

allowance  for  via  matrix  change,  49 

in   input-output  framework,   49 

the  whole  production  process  as  a  system 

of,  94-95,  95n 
via  division  of  nation  into  regions,  49 
via     iterative     approach     and     coefficient 
changes    in    input-output,    49 

see  also  Substitution  effect ;  Substitution 
points  ;  Substitution  principle ; 
Transformation  line ;  Transforma- 
tion function 
Substitution  effect,  and  consumer  behavior, 
87-88 

and  increase  in  consumer  expenditures  on 
travel,   88 

and  the  dispersion  of  urban  population, 
87-88 

component  elements  of,  87 

from  a  fall  of  transport  rate,  87-88,  255 

from  increase  in  population  mobility,  87-88 
Substitution     points,     between     diverse    labor 
outlays,  36 

between  diverse  transport  outlays,  34 

between  groups,  subgroups,  and  individual 
commodities,  95n,   259 

between   inputs   and   outputs,    135-137,   159 

between  labor  inputs  at  cheap  labor  site, 
131 

between  labor  outlays  and  interest  outlays, 
36 

between  labor  outlays  and  transport  out- 
lays, 36,  140n,   189-190,   196,  259,  264 

between  land  inputs  and  other  inputs,  193- 
194,  275 

between  outlays,  35,  49,  94,  159,  197,  199, 
206,  259,  269 

between    outlays,    need    for,    126-127,    135 

between  outlays  and  revenues,  35,  49,  54, 
94,  140n,  159,  175,  175n-176n,  188, 
197,    199,    205-206,   259,   269 

between  power  outlays  and  transport  out- 
lays,  189-190 

between  production  outlays  and  transport 
outlays,  170n,  174-175,  175n,  179, 
179n,  265,  267 

between  production  outlays  at  several 
sources,   155-157,  262 

between  production  outlays  of  two  pro- 
ducers,   148-154,    260-261 

between  rent  outlays  and  other  outlays, 
33-34,   193-195,    196n,   205-206,   275 

between  rent  outlays  and  transport  outlays, 
189-190,    196,    196n,    275 

between  revenues,  35,  49,  159,  197,  199, 
206,   259,   269 

between  spatially  defined  inputs  and  out- 
puts, 95n 

between  transport  and  labor  inputs,  inade- 
quacy of,   126-127 

between  transport  and  labor  outlays,  rela- 
tion  to  the  labor  coefficient,   141-142 

between  transport  inputs,  see  Transport 
inputs 

between  transport  inputs  and  capital  in- 
puts, 253 

between  transport  inputs  and  labor  inputs, 
36,  81-82 

between  transport  inputs  and  other  inputs, 
253 

between  transport  outlays  and  local  capital 
and  labor  outlays,  33-34 


Substitution    points — continued 
change  in,   from  a   fall  of  transport  rate, 

87-88 
with  change  in  crop,   197-199 
effect  on,  of  sources  of  raw  materials,  175n- 

176n,   262 
of  spatial  distribution  of  markets,   175n- 

176n 
inability  of   Losch  theory  to   identify,   49 
interdependence  of,  34,   130 
of  labor   inputs   for   other  inputs   at  cheap 

labor  site,   131,   131n,   196 
of  power  inputs  for  other  inputs  at  cheap 

power  site,   132 
technical,   and   Weberian  theory,   36n-37n 
use  of   input-output  to   identify,   49 
use  of  price-cost  relations  to  identify,  49 
variation    in,    with   distance    of    farm   from 

market,   197,   276 
with   economies   of   scale,    175-176,    175n- 

176n,  265-266 
see  also  Substitution  ;  Substitution  principle 
Substitution   principle,   ability  of,   to  consider 

many     market     points,     98-101,     104, 

226-230,    255-258,    276 
to    consider    many    raw    material    points, 

98-101,   104,   226-230,   255-256 
to    incorporate    realistic    rate    structures, 

108-109,    117,   229-230,   255 
advantage  relative   to   critical  isodapane  in 

labor  orientation,    130-131,   131n,   259 
and  discontinuities  in  the  location  problem, 

95n 
and  general  equilibrium  theory,   32-35 
and  general  location  theory,   32-36,   54,   221 
and    locational    equilibrium    when    firm    in- 
fluences  price,    158-171 
and  optimum  resource  utilization,   182 
as   applicable   to   agricultural   location   with 

raw   material   supply   areas,    248-249, 

276 
as   applicable   when   crop    combination   pro- 
duced on  farm,   199,  275 
as  basic  to  a  fused  location-market-produc- 
tion  doctrine,    252-253,    286 
as    embracing    scale    economies,    95n,    135n, 

173-176,  265-267 
as    embracing    localization    economies,    179- 

182,  268 

as  embracing  urbanization  economies,   182- 

183,  268-269 

as  encompassing  differentials  in  input 
prices,   199n 

as  fusing  existing  location  and  market 
theories,  250-251 

as  implying  Launhardt-Palander  construc- 
tion, 267 

as  involved  in  the  general  location  prin- 
ciple, 224-253 

as  involving  movement  from  a  higher  value 
to   a   lower   value   isodapane,    123-124 

as  involving  movement  toward  trough  of 
transport  cost  surface,  123-124,  223- 
230 

as  involving  substitution  problems  within 
a  substitution  problem,  33-34,  130, 
275 

as  relating  to  competition  between  land 
uses,  281 

as  relevant  to  new  area  development,  182, 
268 

as  relevant  to  regional  planning,   182,  268 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


337 


Substitution    principle — continued 

as  yielding  agglomeration  analysis,  173- 
188,  265-269 

as  yielding  agricultural  location  theory, 
33-34,  189-199,  205-206.  243-253.  275- 
278,  281 

as  yielding  concentric  zones,   244-245,   246n 

as  yielding  Dean's  results  when  his  index 
is  less  than  unity,   121,  255 

as  yielding  Launhardt's  pole  principle  re- 
sults.  122,  255 

as  yielding  location  of  intermediary  estab- 
lishments.  175n 

as  yielding  location  of  marketing  establish- 
ments.  175n 

as  yielding  Losch  location  theory,  153-154, 
239-242,   267 

as  yielding  market  area  analysis,  147-154, 
231-239,  260-267 

as  yielding  optimum  land-use  patterns  with 
multiple    markets,    198-199.    276 

as  yielding  orientation  to  a  cheap  capital 
site.   133 

as  yielding  orientation  to  a  cheap  material 
source,  133 

as  yielding  orientation  to  a  higher-price 
market,   134-135,  259 

as  yielding  patterns  of  land  use  by  type, 
281 

as  yielding  power  orientation.  132,  259.  275 

as  yielding  rent  functions.  276 

as  yielding  results  of  competitive  locational 
equilibrium  models,   170 

as  yielding  results  of  isodapane  technique, 
122-124.  255 

as  yielding  results  of  traditional  location 
doctrines.   119-125,   221-253,  255 

as  yielding  supply  area  analysis.  154-158. 
235.    238-239,    260-262 

as    yielding    transport-orientation,    113-124, 
222-230,  255 

as  yielding  urban  land  use  theory.  205-206, 
281 

as  yielding  Weber's  labor  orientation.  127- 
131.   196.   259.  275 

as   yielding   Weber's   results,   for   line   case. 
119-120.  255 
when    material    index    less    than    unity, 

120-121 
when     weight     triangle     exists,     121-122, 
223-226.  255 

expanded   to   include  diverse   forces,   34 

extension  to  include  quantity  elasticity, 
41n-42n 

general  value  of.  for  analysis  of  space- 
economy,   35-36,    54,    138-140,    254 

invalidity  of  Palander's  criticism  of,   95n 

limitations  in  the  use  of,  with  fixed  pro- 
portions,   131,    136-137 

limited  value  for  handling  labor,  power, 
and    other   factors,    140,    140n 

limited  value  for  handling  spatially  irregu- 
lar  variables,    140,    140n,   202n,   259 

need  of  a  multicommodity  framework  to 
apply  to  agricultural  location,  243, 
276 

need  to  consider  all  differentials  in  costs 
and  revenues.   135 

need  to  consider  historical  process.  180.  268- 
269 

parallel  use  in  production  and  location 
theory,   135-137,  255 


Substitution     principle — continued 

procedure  in  considering  several  dilTcren- 
tials.    135-137,    137n,    259 

relative  to  total  cost  comparisons,  137, 
137n 

special  value  for  handling  transport  factor, 
140 

superiority  of  use  of.  to  Weberian  tech- 
nique,  108-109 

to  derive  minimum   cost  location,   33-34 

to  embrace  geographic  inequalities  of  re- 
sources, 34 

use    of,    to    fuse    location    and    production 
theory,  221,  252,   255,   259 
to  fuse  location  dogmas,  221,  252,  259 
to  fuse   Thiinen   and   Weberian   doctrines, 
189-199,  275 

value  of,  as  dependent  upon  number  of 
differentials,   137 

see  also  General  location  principle 
Supply,  conditions  of.  as  emphasized  in  Gra- 
ham's trade  theory.  210 
Supply  area(s).  as  a  point.   155n 

as  distinct  from  market  area.   154n 

as  overlapping  with  market  areas  in  the 
general  case.   235.   238-239 

circular,  conditions  for.  155 

conditions  limiting.   155 

definition  of.   154n 

demarcation  of,  as  substitution  in  the 
small.  251 

determination  in  multifirm,  varying  unit 
cost   case,    238-239 

difficulties  in  analysis  of  systems  of,   158 

effect   on,    of   differences   in   supply   prices, 
157,   157n 
of    differences    in    transport    rates,     157, 
157n 

for  a  given  commodity,  as  reducible  to  a 
finite  number  of  points,  250n 

increase  in  delivered  price  with  increase 
of,   155 

introduction  of,  as  involving  changed  paths 
of  substitution,  235,  238-239 

of   raw  materials,   as   embraced   by  an  ex- 
tended   market    area    analysis,    235, 
238-239 
as  included  in  agricultural  location  prob- 
lem,   248-249,   276 

pattern  of,  with  constant  cost  producers, 
235-236 

with  constant  costs,  155 

with    increasing    costs,    155-157 

see  also  Supply  area  analysis  ;  Supply  area 
boundaries 
Supply    area    analysis,    and    changes    in    com- 
modity flows,  156n-157n 

and  demand   changes,   156n-157n 

and  locational  rent,   155n 

and  substitution  among  production  outlays 
at  several  sources,  155-157 

and  substitution  among  transport  inputs 
on  materials  from  several  sources, 
155-157 

and  transport  rate  changes,   156n-157n 

as  embracing  replacement  deposits,   13 In 

as  implied  by  the  general  location  principle, 
235,  238.  252,  286 

as  market  area  analysis  in  reverse,  155-158 

as    systems    of   supply    areas,    and    physical 
space  restrictions,    158 
difficulties  of,   158 


338 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Supply  area  analysis — continued 

as    yielded    by    the    substitution    principle, 
154-158,  235,   238-239,  260-261 

as  yielding  boundaries   of  agricultural  hin- 
terlands   of   cities,    276n 

as  yielding  more  precise  results  than  com- 
petitive  location   analysis,    169 

as    yielding    precise    results    by    abstracting 
from  complex  factors,   169 

for  relatively  few  supply  sources,  155n-157n 

fusion     with     market     area     analysis     and 
transport-orientation,   235,   238 

geographic  inequalities  in  raw  material  de- 
posits and  need  for,   154 

in  a  fused  location-market-production  doc- 
trine,  252-253,   286 

in  several  different  situations,  155-158 

inclusion    in    a   generalized   Thiinen    frame- 
work, 250-251 

inclusion    in    agricultural    location    theory, 
248-249 

need    to    integrate    with    competitive    loca- 
tional  equilibrium,  170 

sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  loca- 
tion-market-trade   doctrines,    256-285 

use  of  aggregate  supply  curve  in,  156n-157n 

see  also  Supply   area  ;   Supply  area  bound- 
aries 
Supply    area    boundaries,     as     circles,     under 
constant  costs,   155 
under  increasing  costs,   155-157 

as  determined  by   condition  of  equal  deliv- 
ered prices,   155,   155n-157n 

as  hyperbolas,   157 

as  hypercircles,   157 

as  straight  lines,   156 

equations  for,  248-249 

for  agricultural  hinterlands,  276n,  277 

socially  efficient,  formation  of,   and  substi- 
tution    among     production     outlays, 
155-157 
formation     of,     and    substitution     among 
transport    inputs,    155-157 

see  also  Supply  area ;  Supply  area  analysis 
Supply    curve,     aggregate,     construction    of, 
155n-156n 
equation   to   aggregate   demand   for   agri- 
cultural   equilibrium,    198-199 
use     in     analysis     of     market    allocation, 

156n-157n 
use  in   supply   area   analysis,    156n-157n 
use  of,  with  aggregate  demand  curve,  157n 

changes    in,    and   output   allocation   to   sev- 
eral  markets,    156n-157n 
effect  on  commodity  flows,   156n-157n 
Supply     sources,     demarcation     of     consumer 
districts  served  by  different  combina- 
tions of,  261-264 

differential  prices  at,  effect  on  supply  area, 
157,   157n 

effect  of  shift  of  demand  curve  on   output 
of,   156n-157n 

number    of,    in    the    classification    of    com- 
modities, 93-94 
and   substitution   possibilities   in   location 
analysis,  94 

output   of,   as   related   to   aggregate   supply 
and  demand   curves,    156n-157n 
effect   on    of   changes    in    transport   rate, 
156n-157n 

shift   of,    and    substitution    among    produc- 
tion outlays,  157 


Supply  sources — continued 

and     substitution    among     transport    in- 
puts,  157 
shift  of,  among  producers,  and  social  wel- 
fare,  157 
Surplus   profits,   see  Profits,   surplus 
Surplus    (social),   conception   of,  as  affecting 
content  of  market  area,  234-235 
as    affecting   paths    of   substitution,    234- 
235 
conditions  for  maximization  of,  232-235 
content  of  conditions  for  maximization  of, 
as  varying  with  conception  of,   234- 
235 
determination  of  maximum,  by  direct  com- 
putation, 233,  238 
form  of  condition  for  maximization  of,   as 
invariant    with    conception    of,    234- 
235 
in  simple  multifirm  market  area  case,  235- 

239 
in    simple    single    firm    market    area    case, 

231-235 
maximization     of,     as     generally     different 
from  minimization  of  transport  cost, 
232n,    233,    233n-234n 
in  Losch  scheme,  240 
in  multifirm,  varying  unit  cost  case,  236- 

239 
under    different    pricing    systems,    236n, 

239n 
with  both  market  and  supply  areas,  235, 

238-239 
with  hexagonal  market  areas,   242 
with  raw  material  supply  areas,  235,  238- 
239 
maximum,  effect  of  constant  consumption 

density  on,   23  3n 
measurement     of,     avoided     in     generalized 

Thiinen   approach,   249 
non-measurable   character   of   existing   con- 
ceptions of,  234n 
problems  in  defining,  236n 
some    simple    conceptions    of,    234 
stationary  points  in  surface  of,  with  vari- 
able   consumption    density,    233 
when    consumer   purchases    more   than    one 

unit  of  product,   234-239 
when     consumer     purchases     one     unit     of 

product,  232-233 
see  also  Welfare,  social 
Synthesis    of    theories,    see    Fusion ;    General 
location  principle 

Tariff  structure,  see  Transport  rate  structure 
Tastes,  consumer,  and  explanation  of  spatial 
pattern   of   population,   144n-145n 
and    explanation    of    transport    inputs    in- 
curred,  144-145 
differences    in,    and    enclaves    of    excluded 
consumers,  146n 
and  noncircularity  of  market  areas,  145- 
146 
need   to  study   relations   with  metropolitan 

structure,  287 
see  also  Space  preference 
Tax  outlays,  as  a  distorting  factor  in  space- 
economy,  138,  260 
differentials   in,   and  the   Launhardt-Palan- 
der  construction,  260 
as  a  location  factor,  133,  138-139 
effect  on  farm  operations,  194n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


339 


Tax    outlays — continued 

unsystematic     geographic     pattern    of    tax 

rates,  138,  140n,  194n,  259 
see  also  Production  outlays 
Technological   advance,    and   decentralization, 
12-13,  79n 
and   geographic   split  of   production,   20 
and  geographic  unemployment,  8 
and    revaluation   of   resources,    7,    22,    79n, 

258 
and  site  selection,  12-13 

effect    of,    on    cultural    values    and    institu- 
tions,  12,   13 
on   Force  of   Unification,   79n 
on    industrial   location,    7,    10,    12-13,    22, 

79n,  258-259 
on   market  areas,    258-259 
on  space  preference,   13 
on  spatial  structure,  258-259 
via      Launhardt-Palander      construction, 
258-259 
in  iron  and  steel  industry,  7-8,   10 
incorporation    of,    in   sketches    of   fused   lo- 
cation-market   doctrines,    256-285 
psychological  impact  of,  13 
see  also  Transport  technology 
Technological  conditions,   and  significance  of 
regional  resources,  3 In 
as  limiting  land  use,  205,  280 
bearing  of,  on  adaptation  to  environment, 

1-2 
effect  of,  on  urban  transit  network,   185 
Telephone  messages,  and  the  Pi  •  P2/D  factor, 
61-62 
variation  with  population  and  distance,  61- 
62 
Terminal  charges,  as  affecting  industrial  loca- 
tion,  107-108,   230,   251 
as  causing  local  minima  on  transport  cost 
surface,  230,  251 
Terminal     locations,     see     Equilibrium     point 

(for   firm   location),   as   end   point 
Tertiary    activities,    relation    to    agricultural 

stratum,  7 
Tertiary  industry,  and  location  analysis,  21 
relation  of,  to  agricultural  stratum,  7 
see    also    Secondary    industry ;    Service    ac- 
tivities 
Textile  Industry,  as  a  basic  industry,  284 
as  a  subsidiary  industry,   10 
as  a  typical  industry  in  trade  doctrine,  211n 
as  having  different  income  effect  than  steel, 

284 
as  having  different  land   use   impact  than 

steel,  284-285 
as    having   different   multiplier    effect   than 

steel,   284 
geographic  shift  of,   10 
international  location  via  opportunity  costs, 

211-219,  282-285 
labor  costs  as  major  in  location  of,  21  In 
location  of,  10,  140n,  211n 

and   substitution    between    transport   and 
labor  outlays,    140n,   189-190 
optimum  location  pattern,  10 
transport    costs    as    minor    in    location    of, 
211n 
Thiinen,   location   theory  of,   see  Agricultural 

location  theory 
Thiinen  rings,  see  Zone  ;  Zone  formation 
Timber    resources    and    relation    to    iron    and 
steel  location,  6-7 


Time  axis,  need  for,  in  analysis,  77-78 
Time-cost    distance,    see    Distance,    effective ; 

Distance,  time-cost 
Time    preference,    as    acquiied   behavior    pat- 
tern,  84-85 
different  forms  of,  84-85 
space   preference   contrasted    with,    83-85 
Time-space   continuum,   as  a  proper  analytic 

framework,  77-78 
Topography,    as    restraining    urban    land-use 
patterns,    206,    276,    280 
effect  of,  on  agglomeration  economies,  140 
on  cost  curves,   202n 
on  location,  2,   3,  6,   138 
on   pattern  of   settlement,    31n 
on  transport  cost  surface,  251 
on   transport   rate,    88,    112 
on  urban  transit  system,   185 
revaluation  by  aircraft,   12 
see  also  Environment,  physical 
Total    cost,    comparisons    of,    as    superior    to 
substitution,  137 
to  determine  firm  location,  137 
Trade,     among     areas     (regions),     and     geo- 
graphic split  of  production,   20 
and    interrelations    of    production    stages, 

21 
effect  of  advance  in  transport  technology 

on,  22 
effect   of  aircraft  on,   12 
effect  of  atomic  energy  on,  13 
effect    of    geographic    inequality    of    re- 
sources on,  18,  75 
hierarchical  order  of,   22 
and  equilibrium  among  spatially  separated 

markets,   167n-169n 
and   location,    interrelation   of,   6-7,   20,   22, 
31n,   50-54,   167n-169n,  207-220,  281 
simplified  case  of,  210-219,  282-285 
simultaneous    determination    of,    6-7,    50- 
54,  207,  215,  219,  282-285 
and  port  development,  9 
and  resources,   interrelation  of,   6,   75 
and  the  need  to  analyze  spatial  relations, 

78n 
as  affected  by  factor  mobility,  282-285 
as    affecting    structure    of    industrial    dis- 
tricts, 282-285 
as  related  to  urban  land  use,  282-285 
as  related  to  urban-metropolitan  structure, 

282-285 
basis   of,  and  economies  of  scale,   17 

and  transport  cost,  17 
changes    in    imports    and   exports   with   in- 
dustrialization, 9 
commodity  composition  of,  and  geographic 
split  of  production,   20 
and  interindustry  linkage,  20-21 
as   related   to  transport   cost  level,    19n 
comparative  advantage  in,  in  simple  three- 
country   case,   213-219,    282-285 
conditions  for,  20,   215n 
development   of,    with   industrialization,   7- 

8 
effect   of   change   in    distance   variable   on, 

5-6,   215-219,   282-285 
effect  of  space  preferences  on,  22-23 
external,   beginning   of,   9 
in  a  Thiinen-Losch  framework,   17 
in    the    Enke-Samuelson    market    problem, 

167n-168n 
interdependence  in   intraregional,   22 


340 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Trade — continued 

international,      and      differences      in      local 
prices,  51 
and    the    distance    variable,    73-75,    208- 
209,  283-285 

intranational  and  the  distance  variable,  70- 
73,   208-209,   282-283 

need  to  develop  gravity  model  to  explain 
more  fully,  209 

need  to  specify  demand  to  determine  pat- 
tern of,  212 

stability  of  flows  and  location  theory,  22 
Trade  routes,   hierarchy   of,   as   characteristic 
of  space-economy,   251,  287 
as  related  to  transport  cost  level,  19n 
need  for  improved  analysis  of,  287 

selection  among,  and  fall  of  transport  rate, 
67 
Trade  theory,  and  location  theory,  fusion  of, 
50-54,   207-220,   281-282 
need     to     explore     relations     comprehen- 
sively, 286 

and  need  to  consider  spatial  framev^ork,  209 

and  spatial  considerations,  25n,  27 

as  derived  from  total  location  analysis  for 
Ohlin's   district,   52-53,   53n 

as  part  of  a  general  localization  theory,  51, 
53-54,  208 

broadly  conceived,  synonymous  with  gen- 
eral location  theory,   53-54,  254 

Classical,    inadequacy    of   mobility    and   im- 
mobility premises  of,  208 
neglect    of    transport-orientation    in,    50, 
53,  208 

complications  from  the  international  vari- 
able, 208,  283-285 

developments  in  long-run,  as  included  in 
an  extended  location  theory,  219- 
220,  282 

evaluations  of  difl'erent  types  of,   209 

extended  to  include  commodities  sensitive 
to  transport  cost  differentials,  217- 
219,  281-282 

extension  of,   through  formulating  location 
theory  in  terms  of  opportunity  cost, 
219,  281-282 
to   include  agglomeration   analysis,   219 
to   include   labor   and    power   orientation, 
219 

fusion    with    transport-orientation,    as    ex- 
tension   of    location    theory,    217-219, 
282 
in  a  simplified  case,  210-219,  282-285 
via  transport  inputs,   210-219,   281-282 

imbalance  in  development  of,  209 

in  terms  of  economic  activity  between 
men,  53n 

introduction  of  distance  variable  into,  211- 
219,  281-282 

limitations  of  Ohlin,  51-53,  52n,  53n 

long-run,     and    assumption    of    fixed    con- 
sumption   pattern,    212n 
as  exemplified  by  Graham's  doctrine,  209- 
218 

Mosaic's,  for  a  one  point  world,  26 

need  to  consider  aggregate  regional  de- 
mand and  income,  207 

need  to  include  transport-orientation  in,  53, 
210,  281-282 

Ohlin  doctrine,  17,  50-53,  208 

Ohlin's  formulation  of,  in  more  concrete 
terms,  217 


Trade    theory — continued 

past    neglect    of    multicountry,    multicom- 

modity  approach   in,   210 
short-run   and   long-run  types  of,   209 
short-run,   activity  analysis  as   appropriate 
for,  209 
gravity   models   as   appropriate  for,   209 
input-output  analysis  as  appropriate  for, 
209 
sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  loca- 
tion-market doctrines,  256-285 
transport  cost  as  a  basic  variable  in,  26n 
Weber's  criticism  of,  50,  53,  208 
as  met,  217 
Transfer  costs,  see  Transport  costs 
Transformation     curve,     see     Transformation 

line 
Transformation  function,  as  reduced  to  varia- 
tion   in    three    distance    variables    in 
locational    triangle    case,    222-223 
definition  of,  96 

fixed  proportions  and  restraints  of,  137 
spatial,  as  a  set  of  efficient  locations,  119 
as    embracing   transport   inputs   as    vari- 
ables, 96,  119,  222,  252,  255 
as    precluding   unnecessary   distance,    96- 

97,  107 
as  restraining  location  of  firm,  223-230 
as  restraining  transport  inputs,  223-253 
mathematical  representation   of,   222 
use   of,    in    fusing   production   and   location 
theory,   252-253,  255,   286 
in  location  theory,   223-253 
see  also  Ti-ansformation   line 
Transformation     line(s),     and     definition    of 
transformation  function,  96 
as  a  continuous  curve  to  facilitate  analysis 

and  synthesis  of  theories,   115 
between    distance    variables,    advantage    in 
use  of,   116 
and  the  locational  line  case,  96-97 
and  the  locational  polygon  case,   98-101 
and  the  locational  triangle  case,   97-98 
convexity   of,   97-100,    107 
location  shifts   associated   with  shifts  of, 

116 
with   finite   number   of   transport  routes, 
101-112 
between    pairs    of    distance    variables,    the 

interrelations  of,  97-101 
between  transport  inputs,  96,  113-119 

and    the    locational    line    case,    117,    119- 

120 
and  the  locational  polygon  case,  117-124 
and  the  locational  triangle  case,  113-124 
convexity  of,  116 
location  shifts  not  required  by  shifts  of, 

116 
shift  of  with  change  in  weights,  115-116 
changed  content  of,  with  use  of  transport 

inputs  as   variables,   115-116 
continuous,     change    of    equilibrium    point 

with  use  of,   115n 
convexity     of,     and     diminishing     marginal 
rate  of  substitution,   116 
second-order    (stability)    condition,    116 
discontinuous,    101-112,    117,    118 
points  on,  correspondence  with  outlay  sub- 
stitution  line,    127-129 
use  of,  with  price-ratio  lines,  to  determine 

equilibrium    location,    101-119,    159 
see  also  Transformation  function 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


341 


Transformation    relations,   between   transport 
inputs     as    embracing     relations    be- 
tween   distance    variables,    114-119 
between    transport    inputs    as    reduced    to 
relations   between   distance  variables, 
96 
see  also  Substitution  ;   Substitution   points  ; 
Transformation  line 
Transportation    analysis     (Koopmans),    as    a 
problem    in    activity    analysis,    168n, 
213n 
as   allied   to   competitive   locational   equilib- 
rium,  167n-169n 
as  allied  to  spatial  price  equilibrium,  167n- 

169n 
as  related  to  general  location  analysis,   22, 

213n,    221n-222n,    286 
as   taking   scale   of   output   as   fixed,    168n- 
169n 
Transport   cost,    and    difficulty    of   defining    a 
unit  of  transportation  service,  186 
and   extent  of  market,   148-151,   153,   173 
and  the  location  of  intermediary  establish- 
ments,  175n 
and    the    location    of    marketing    establish- 
ments,  175n 
as  a  major  location  factor,   138-140 
as   afl'ecting   exchange  ratios,   215n,   217 
as   affecting  farm   output,    190-194 
as   an   implicit  variable   in   production   the- 
ory, 26n 
as  basic  to  Losch's  market  area  system,  44, 

150-151,  153,  267 
as  contrasted  with  storage  costs,   86n 
as    determining    industrial    distribution    by 

regions,   172 
as   imparting   regularity  to  space-economy, 

35,  138-140,  210 
as  imparting  spatial  regularity  to  agglom- 
eration  economies,    139n 
to  labor  costs,   127n,    139n 
to  power  costs,   138n-139n 
as  major  in  iron  and  steel  location,  211n 
as    minor    in    location    of    textile    industry, 

211n 
as  zero,   in   general  equilibrium  theory,   26, 

33,  42,  53 
differentials    in,    need   to   express    in    terms 
of    opportunity    cost,    217-219,    281- 
282 
effect  of   breaks   in   transport   network   on, 

110 
effect    of,     on    commodity    composition     of 
trade,  19n 
on  competitive  locational  equilibrium,  164 
on   geographic  specialization,   5-6 
on  hierarchy  of  sites  and  city-regions,  19n 
on  hierarchy  of  trade  routes,  19n 
on  net  economy  curves  of  diverse  urban 

services,   188 
on  trade,   17,  51 
feasibility  of  introducing  into  general  equi- 
librium theory,  42 
handling  of  irregularities   in,   138 
inconsistency   with   pure   competition,   43 
isodapane  contour  lines  of,   122-123 
isotim  contour  lines  of,   123 
isovector   contour   lines   of,    122-123 
level     of,     and     inter-     and     intraregional 

structure,  22 
minimization    of,    and    international    trade 
theory.  50 


Transport  cost — continued 

and  iron  and  steel  location,  7,  19n,  80n 
and  the  hexagonal   form,   44-45 
and   transport-orientation,    95-124 
and     unnecessary     distance,     96-97,     107, 

113n 
and    Zipf's    theoretical    framework,    68n- 

69n 
as    generally   different    from    maximizing 

social  surplus,  232n,  233,  233n-234n 
as   profit  maximization   in   transport-ori- 
entation,   222-230 
as   yielded   by   the  general  location   prin- 
ciple, 222-230 
minimum  point  of,  as  point  of  agglomera- 
tion,  177-178 
minor    significance    of,    in    Classical    trade 

theory,  215n 
need    to    consider    as    an    explicit    variable, 

26n,   79-80,  80n,  210 
on  inputs,  as  basic  to  Brinkmann's  theory, 

244n-245n 
per    unit    distance,    as    locational    force    in 

mechanical  model,   122 
regular  variation  with  distance  and  spatial 

order,  35,  138-140,  210 
relation  to  zone  formation,   3-6 
relative  neglect  of,  in  Graham's  trade  doc- 
trine,  210,  215n 
restraints   on   total,   in   the  locational  poly- 
gon case,  98-101,  lOln,  117 
rise    of,    and    effect    on    agricultural    zones, 
19n 
and  industrial  agglomerations,  19n 
and   significance  of  resource  inequalities, 

19n 
and  significance  of  space  preferences,  19n 
scale    economies    in,    and    noncircularity    of 

market  areas,  145-146 
total,    need    for    direct    comparisons    of,    in 

locational   polygon,    137,    140n,    230 
urban,   as   dependent  on   power  costs,    187- 

188 
variation  in,  predictability  over  space,  138, 

210,  259 
see  also  Transport  inputs  ;   Transport  out- 
lays ;  Transport  rate  ;  Transport  rate 
structure 
Transport  cost  surface,  as  convex  downward 
in  simple  Weberian  triangle  case,  224 
as  having  single  minimum  point  in  simple 

Weberian   triangle  case,   224 
as  linearly  punctured  because  of  finite  num- 
ber of  routes,  251 
as    multipunctured,    230,    251 
discontinuities  in,  from  rate  abnormalities, 

230,   251 
isodapanes  as  contour  lines  of,   122-124 
local     minima     of,     from     graduated     line 
charges,  229-230 
from  loading  charges,  230,  251 
from  special  transit  privileges,  230,  251 
from  terminal  charges,  230,  251 
from     transshipment,  230,  251 
movement    along,    as    substitution    between 

transport    inputs,    123 
realistic,    as    yielding    discontinuous    space- 
economy,   230,   251 
trough   of,    as   equilibrium   point   in   trans- 
port-orientation,   122-124,    224-230 
Transport  inputs,  and  capital  inputs,  substi- 
tution between,  253 


342 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Transport    inputs — continued 

and    labor   inputs,    inadequacy   of   substitu- 
tion   between,    126-127 
substitution    between,    36,    81-82 

and  the  classification  of  factors,  89-90 

and  the  falling  of  additional  product  with 
increase  in  the  use  of,   86 

and  the  Marshallian  functional  approach, 
90,   119n 

and  the  relative  importance  of  the  several 
types  of  inputs,  90 

and  the  roundaboutness  of  production,  82- 
83,  255 

and  the  space  extent  of  the  economy,  82, 
82n,  255 

as  a  basic  concept  for  location  theory,  35- 
36,  79-90,  113-114,  209,  222,  252, 
286 

as  associated  with  concept  of  space  dis- 
count, 255 

as  associated  with  deglomeration  econo- 
mies, 255 

as  combinations  of  land,  labor,  and  capital 
services,    87n,    89-90 

as  contrasted  with  capital  inputs,  81-86, 
255 

as  factor  services  required  to  overcome 
resistance,  79 

as  involving  distance  variation  only  in 
locational    triangle    case,    222-223 

as  ultimately  stemming  from  labor  and 
land    inputs,    81,    89,    255 

definition  of,   79,   79n,  89-90,   113-114,   255 

definition   of  shipping  in  terms   of,   211 

demand  curve  for,  as  reflected  in  associated 
changes  in  output,  86,  87n,  255 

diminishing  marginal  rate  of  substitution 
between,  and  the  second-order  condi- 
tion,  116 

effect  of  interest  rate  on  supply  curve  of, 
88n-89n 

explicit  incorporation  in  transformation 
function,   222,   252,   255 

function  of,  in  the  transformation  process, 
90,   119 

general   applicability   of,    118n 

in  an  opportunity  cost  formulation  as  a 
superior  approach,  215,  219,  281-282 

in     different     directions,     susbtitution     be- 
tween,   and    circular    market    areas, 
147 
and  Hotelling's  solution,  170 
and   social   welfare,    147-148 

incidence  of,  in  different  producer-con- 
sumer  situations,    144-145 

increase  in  hinterland  with  increase  in 
use  of,   81-82,   255 

increase  in  output  with  increase  in  use  of, 
81-82,  255 

incurred  by  consumers,  as  explained  by 
space  preference,    144-145 

issue  of  physical  productivity  of,  86n-87n 

marginal  rate  of  substitution  between,  and 
the  equilibrium  point,  116-119,  224 
and  the  first-order  condition,   116 
in    the    general    location    principle,    224- 
253,  286 

minimization    of,   and   iron   and   steel   loca- 
tion,  80n,    118n,   215 
as    involved    in    hexagonal   market   areas, 

242 
in  weight  triangle  analysis,   121-122 


Transport    inputs — continued 
momentary  character  of,   89 
need  for  trade  theory  to  consider,  210-219 
need  to  consider  explicitly,   79-80,   80n,  90, 

222,   255,   286 
need  to  consider  in  calculating  opportunity 

costs,  .211-219,   281-282 
non-existence  of  a  stock  of,  89 
non-resource  character  of,  89-90 
on  materials  from  several  sources,  substitu- 
tion among  and  social  welfare,   155- 
157 
on  raw  materials  and  products,  relevance  of 
substitution  between,  227-228 
substitution   between,    in   agricultural   lo- 
cation, 248 
on  raw  materials  as  zero  in  Losch  scheme, 

239-240 
possible   consideration   as   a   factor   from   a 

socio-economic  standpoint,   89 
profit  motive  in  the  use  of,  81-82 
relation  of,  to  space  preference,  255 
requirements    of,    in    simple    three   country 

case,   212.   216 
service   character  of,    89-90 
shift  in  supply  curve  of,  and  fall  in  trans- 
port rate,  87 
substitution    between,    and   friction    of   dis- 
tance,  140 
and   locational  equilibrium,   159 
and  Losch  location  theory,   153-154,  240- 

242 
and     market    boundary    formation,     148, 

233-239,  264 
and  maximization  of  social  surplus,  233- 

239 
and    shifts    from    focal    point    to    focal 

point,   251 
and  the  classification  of  commodities,  94 
and    transport-orientation,     36,     113-124, 

222-230,   255 
as  affecting  size  of  market  area,   233n 
as    movement    along    transport   cost   sur- 
face,   123-124 
as  synonymous  with  various  formulations 

of    transport-orientation,    119-125 
as  yielding  market  area  analysis,  147-154, 

233-239,  260-261 
as  yielding  supply  area  analysis,  154-158, 

235,   238-239,   260-261 
equivalent  to  movement  along  an  isovec- 

tor,   123-124 
equivalent     to     movement     from     subset 
isodapane   to   subset   isodapane,    123- 
124 
for  different  producers  in  multifirm  case, 

238-239 
in  a  fused  location-mai-ket-supply  frame- 
work,  250-251 
in  a  generalized  Thiinen  approach,  250~ 

251 
in  maximizing  social  rent,  246 
in  the  determination  of  rent,  246n 
in  zone  formation,  246n 
involving    same    basic    considerations    as 

isodapane  technique,  123-124 
necessity    of    for    understanding    spatial 

order,   140 
similai-ity    with    substitution    in    produc- 
tion theory,   118 
to  explain  iron  and  steel  location,   118n- 
119n 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


343 


Transpoi-t  inputs — continued 

substitution    between    prroups    of,    and    the 
use  of  ideal  weiKhts,  228 
in    determination     of    equilibrium     point, 

227-228 
statement    of    general    location    principle 
for,   228 
substitution  with  other  inputs  in  the  trans- 
formation process,  90,  119,  253 
supply  curve  of,  as  reflecting  costs  of  ulti- 
mate inputs,   86,   255 
transformation  line  between,  location  shifts 

not  required  by  shifts  of,   116 
transformation    relations    between,    as    em- 
bracinpr    relations    between     distance 
variables,   114-119,   222-223 
transport  rate  as  price  of,  86-88,  255 
use   of,   and   increase  in   the  spatial  extent 
of   production,    82-83,   255 
and     postponement     of     diminishing     re- 
turns,  255 
as  associated  with  exploitation  of  uneven 

resource  endowment,  255 
as     variables     and     changed     content     of 

price-ratio   lines,    115-116 
as     variables     and     changed     content     of 
transformation    lines,    115-116 
a  system  of  equations,   54 
analysis  of  hierarchy  of  cities,  255 
analysis    of    population    distributions, 
255 
firm  location  analysis,  91-124 
multiplant  firm  analysis,   91n 
instead  of  distance  inputs,  pros  and  cons, 

80,    113-114,    116 
instead     of     spatial     coordinates,     35-36, 

49 
to  derive   Dean's   results   when   his   index 

less  than   unity,   121,   255 
to  derive  Launhardt's   pole  principle  re- 
sults,  122,   255 
to  derive  results   of  isodapane  technique, 

122-124,   255 
to   derive   Weber's   results,   for   line   case, 
119-120 
when    material   index    less    than    unity, 

120-121 
when    weight   triangle   exists,    121-122, 
255 
to  extend  location  theory  to  include  pro- 
duction  theory,    118-119 
to   extend   production   theory,    118-119 
to  fuse  Weberian  and  production  theories, 
91,   113,    118-119 
values     of,     as     restrained     by    the    spatial 

transformation   function,   223-253 
with  respect  to  groups  of  consumers,  sub- 
stitution  between,    235n 
Transport    gradient    line(s),    as    a    delivered 
price   line,    148-149 
effect  of  rate  structures  on,   148n-149n 
use    of,     to    construct     aggregate     demand 
curve,    156n-157n 
to     construct     aggregate     supply     curve, 

155n-156n 
to  derive  net  farm  price,   194,   194n 
Transport  junctions,  see  Transport  network, 

breaks  in 
Transport  network,  and  government  subsidy, 
9,  12 
and  urban-metropolitan  structure,   11,  272- 
273 


Transport  network — continued 

as  critical  in  definition  of  effective  distance, 

205 
as  distorting   agricultural  zones,   276-277 
breaks  in,  effect  on  industrial  location,  110- 
112,   230,   251 
effect  on   iso-outlay   lines,    110-112 
effect  on  transport  cost,  110,  230,  251 
types  of,  110 
changes    in,   as   provoking   complex   adjust- 
ments, 205 
geographic   inequalities   of,   52 
in   Losch  scheme,  270-271 
in  modified  Losch  scheme,  272 
optimum  mix  of  facilities,  9 
optimum,     simultaneous    determination     of, 
with      optimum      location      pattern, 
221n-222n 
optimum   spatial  pattern,   9,   221n-222n 
realistic,  as  a  hierarchy  of  transport  routes, 

251 
relation  of,  to  hierarchy  of  sites,   272-273 
to  industrial  traffic,  9 
to  population   density,   272-273 
to  population  movement,  9 
to  production   concentration,   272-273 
to  structure  of  market  areas,  272-273 
to  structure  of  space-economy,  272-273 
role  of  aircraft  in,   12 

urban,    as   affected   by   population   distribu- 
tion,  185 
as  affected  by  physical  environment,  185- 

187 
as  affected  by  social  organization,  185 
as  affected  by  state  of  technology,  185 
as  affected  by  topography,   185 
as  dependent  on  city  size,  185-186 
economies  in  operation  of  subset  of,  185 
economies  in  operation  of  with  urbaniza- 
tion,  185,  273n 
net   economy   curve   in   the   operation   of, 
185 
variations  of  transport  rates  for  media  of, 

112,   227n 
see  also  Transport  routes 
Transport-orientation,     and     comparison     of 
relative   minimum   points,   108,   108n, 
230 
and  locational  equilibrium  of  the  firm,  91- 

124,   222-230 
and     market     area     framework,      complex 
boundaries   in,   262-264 
discontinuous  markets  in,   264 
introduction   of  scale  economies   in,   265- 
267 
and   profit  maximization   as  transport  cost 

minimization,   222-230 
and  relaxation  of  certain  assumptions,   126 
as  generalized  with  use  of  general  location 

principle,   226-230,   252 
as  market  location  for  farm  enterprise,  196 
as  substitution   between  distance  variables, 

96-112,  222-230 
as    substitution    between    transport    inputs, 

36,   113-124,  222-230,  255 
as  the  heart  of  location  analysis,   140,  210 
as    yielded    by   general    location    theory   via 

specific  assumptions,   252n 
as    yielded    by    general    location    principle, 

222-230,    252,   252n,   286 
case  of  intranationally,  as  other  orientation 
internationally,    219,    281-282 


344 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Transport-orientation — continued 

conversion  into  generalized  location  prob- 
lem via  Launhardt-Palander  con- 
struction,  256-269 

definition  of,  in  international  framework, 
217,    281-282 

deviations    from,    because    of    cheap    labor, 
216-219 
in    agglomeration    because    of    side    pay- 
ments,   180-181.    ISln 

dominance  of  variations  in  transport  out- 
lays  in,   113 

effect  of  economies   of  scale  on,   175n-17Gn 

extension  of  opportunity  cost  doctrine  to 
include,    211-215,    281-282 

extension    of,    to    include   equalizing   differ- 
ences  in   labor  costs,   127n-128n 
to  include  food  as  a  raw  material,  127n- 
128n 

for  infinite  number  of  market  points  as 
market   area   analysis,    231 

fusion  of,  in  location-market-trade  doctrine, 
252-253,   286 
with  market  area  analysis,  231-239 
with   market   and    supply   area    analyses, 

235,   238-239 
with  production  theory,   118-119,  255 
with    trade    theory,    as    a    superior    ap- 
proach,   119,    281-282 
in   a   simphfled   case,    210-219,    282-285 
via  opportunity  costs,  210-219,  281-282 

improved  formulation  of,  via  opportunity 
costs,   211-215,   281-282 

in  iron  and  steel  location,  19n,  80n,  118n, 
211n,  215-219 

in  terms  of  minimizing  ton-kilometers,  36n, 
215-216 

in  terms  of  technical  data,  36n 

inclusion   in,    of   many   market   points,    98- 
101,  104,  226-230,  255-258 
of    many    raw    material    points,    98-101, 
104,  226-230,  255-256 

international,  neglect  of  in  Graham's  trade 
theory,  210 

line  case,  95-97,  117,  119-120 

different  degrees  of  determinacy,  119-120 

mathematical   presentation   of,   222-230 

need  for  complete  framework  to  fuse  theo- 
ries,  113 

need  for  concept  of  transport  inputs,  113- 
114,  222 

need  to  consider  other  variables  than  dis- 
tance,  113 

need  to  consider,  to  understand  interna- 
tional  commodity  flows,   210 

need  to  state  in  terms  of  opportunity  costs, 
210-219,   281-282 

neglect  of,  in  Classical  trade  theory,  50,  53, 
208 

partial  deviation  from,  in  international 
steel  location,  217-219 

polygon  case,  98-101,   117,  226-230 

sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  lo- 
cation-market-trade doctrines,  256- 
285 

solution  by  Varignon's  mechanical  model, 
121-122 

techniques  of,  to  identify  point  of  agglom- 
eration,  178 

triangle  case,  97-98,  101-119,  222-226 

under    simplified    conditions,    95-104,    222- 


Transport-orientation — continued 

use   of   isodapanes   to  derive  solution,    122- 

124 
use  of  Launhardt-Palander  construction  in, 

256-258 
use  of  pole  principle  to  derive  solution,  122, 

256-258 
use  of  transformation  function  in,  222-230, 

255 
use  of  weight  triangles  to  derive  solution, 

120-122 
various  formulations  of,   119-125 
Weberian     doctrine     reformulated,     96-112, 

222-230 
with    finite    number    of    transport    routes, 

101-112,  255 
with  fixed  markets,  as  inapplicable  to  mar- 
ket theory,  231 
with  many  market  points  as  involving  mar- 
ket area  analysis,   260 
with  realistic  rate  structures,  104-112,  117, 
229-230,  255 
Transport  outlays,  additional,   as  represented 
by  isodapanes,   130n,   141 
incurred    in    labor    orientation,     127-131, 

141-142 
incurred  in  power  orientation,   132 
ratio  of  labor  cost  savings  to,  see  Labor 
cost   savings,    ratio   of,   to   additional 
transport  outlays 
and  labor  outlays,  susbtitution  between  and 
boundary  formation,  264 
substitution  between  in  labor  orientation, 
127-131,  140n,  189-190,  196,  259,  264, 
275 
and  power  outlays,  substitution  between  in 
power  orientation,  132,  189-190,  259, 
275 
and     production     outlays,     substitution    be- 
tween, and  concentration  of  produc- 
tion, 174 
and  Hotelling's  solution,   170n 
and  localization,   179,   179n,   182,   267 
and  location  of  marketing  establishments, 

175n 
and  optimum  size  of  firm,   175n-176n 
and  social  welfare,   182,   262 
and  urbanization,   188 
as    induced    by   economies    of    scale,    174, 

265,  267 
in    determining    point    of    agglomeration, 
174-175 
and    rent    outlays,    substitution    between    in 
farm     enterprise     location,     189-190, 
196,  196n,  275 
and   substitution   with  labor   outlays,   36 
as  depressing  net  farm  price,  205 
as  explicitly  considered  in  agricultural  loca- 
tion theory,  205,  280 
as   implicitly  considered   in   urban  land  use 

theory,  205,  280 
differentials     in,     incorporation    in    outlay- 
substitution    Hne,    127-129 
dominance   of   variations   of,    in   transport- 
orientation,   113 
in  different  directions,  substitution  between, 
and  Hotelling's  solution,   170,   170n 
effect    on,    of    economies    of    scale,    175n- 
176n 
in  Predohl's  framework,  33 
localization    as    involving    increase   of,    179, 
267 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


345 


Transport    outlays — continued 

substitution    among,    and    optimum    size    of 
firm,   175n-176n 
in    the    location    of    marketing    establish- 
ments,  175n 
time-cost    by    consumer,    as    affecting    firm 
revenues,  205 
as  basic  to  urban   land  use  theory,   205 
as  determining  accessibility,   205 
Transport  rate(s),  as  contrasted  with  inter- 
e.^t  rate,   88 
as  determined  by  the  supply  curve  of,  and 
demand  curve  for,  transport  inputs, 
86,  255 
as  the  price  of  a  transport  input,   35,   86- 

88,  255 
as  the  rate  of  discount  in  space,  85 
assumption  by  location  theory  of  monopoly 

elements  in,   213n 
assumption    of    invariance    of,    with    direc- 
tion in  concentric  zone  theory,  245 
bearing  on  labor  orientation,  141,   142 
changes  in,  and  output  allocation  to  several 
markets,   156n-157n 
effect   on    commodity    flows,    156n-157n 
effect  on  output  of  supply  sources,  156n- 
157n 
differences   in,   and   effect  on  market  areas 
of   competing   firms,    146-147 
and  effect  on  supply  areas,  157,  157n 
directional  variation  of,  and  non-circularity 

of  market  areas,  231n 
discriminatory,    and    the   possibility   of   un- 
necessary  distance,    97n,    lOln,    113n, 
130n 
effect  of  interest  rate  on,   88n-89n 
effect     on     distance     between     isodapanes, 

141 
fall  of,   and   change  in  consumer  behavior, 
87-88 
and  dispersion  of  urban  population,  87-88 
and  increase  in  geographic  specialization, 

87 
and    increase    in    share    of    income    spent 

on   travel,    88 
and  increase   in  space  extent  of  produc- 
tion,  87,  255 
and  increase  in  the  consumption  of  trans- 
port inputs,  88 
and    increased    concentration    of    produc- 
tion, 87 
and   population   mobility,    87-88,    88n 
and  scale  effects,   87-88,   255 
and  selection  among  sites,   87 
and  selection   among  trade  routes,   87 
and    substitution    between    transport    in- 
puts and  other  inputs,   87 
and  substitution  effects,  87-88,  255 
and   urban    population    shifts    by    income 

groups,  88n 
as  a  decrease  in  the  time  and  money  cost 

of  population   movement,   87-88 
from  a  shift  in  the  supply  curve  of  trans- 
port inputs,  87 
from    advances    in    transport   technology, 
87 
ratios  of,  as  involved  in  the  general  location 

principle,  224 
use  of  a  single  fictitious  rate  to  represent 

a  multitude  of  rates,  88 
use   of   ideal   weights   to    adjust   for   differ- 
ences in,   109n,   120,  228 


Transport    rate(s) — continued 

variations  in,  and  adjustment  of  transport 
cost  scales,  112 
by    commodity    characteristics,     88,     112, 

118n,  227n 
by  degree  of  competition,  88 
by  direction  of  movement,   112,  227n 
by  haul  characteristics,  88 
by  nature  of  topography,  88,  112 
by  type  transport  facility,   112,  227n 
by  type  transport  route,  112 
by  volume  and  speed  of  movement,  112 
effect  of  on  determination  of  equilibrium 

point,   112 
incorporation  in  iso-outlay  lines,   112 
see    also    Transport    cost ;    Transport    rate 
structure 
Transport  rate  structures,  and  regular  varia- 
tion with  distance,   138 
and  the  possibility  of  unnecessary  distance, 

107,   113n 
as  dependent  on  flow  volume,  neglect  of  by 

traditional  location   theory,   213n 
assumed    as    fixed    by    traditional    location 

theory,  213n 
characteristics  of,  in  modern  industrialized 
societies,    105,    107,    112,    113n,    227n, 
229-230 
in  primitive  societies,   105 
complications  of,  and  substitution  analysis, 

36,   104-112 
eccentricities  in,  effect  on  equilibrium  firm 

location,   113n 
effect  of  zonal  chai-acter  of,  on  price-ratio 

lines,   105-112 
effect  on  transport  gradient  line,  148n-149n 
first  zone  charge,  and  end  point  solutions, 
107-112,  230 
and  tails  of  price-ratio  lines,   106-108 
graduated,  significance  of,  105-112,  229-230 
graduation  of,  and  convexity  of  price-ratio 
lines,   106-107,   120 
and   determinacy   of  locational   line   case, 

120 
and   end   point  solutions,    107-112 
because    of    overhead    and    terminal    ex- 
penses,  105 
in  industrialized  areas,  and  end  point  solu- 
tions, 107-112,  230,  230n 
need    to    consider    as    variable    in    location 

theory,  213n,  286 
realistic,    and    construction    of    price-ratio 
lines,    105-112,    112n-113n 
and    firm   equilibrium   locations,    104-112, 

113n,    117,    229-230,   255 
and  modification  of  first-order  conditions, 

229-230 
and    modification    of   second-order    condi- 
tions,    229-230,  230n 
as   distorting   market   boundaries,   239n 
as  yielding  multipunctured  transport  cost 

surface,  230,  251 
embraced  by  isodapane  technique,  122n 
inability    of    Weberian    theory   to   encom- 
pass,  108-109 
use    of    ideal    weights    to    adjust    for    com- 
modity  rates,    109n,   228 
see  also  Transport  rate  ;  Transport  cost 
Transport  routes,  and  variations  in  transport 
rates,   112 
development  of,   with  industrialization,  7-8 
effect  of   finite  number,   3,    16,   113n,   251 


346 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Transport   routes — continued 
effect  on  farm  operations,   194 
effect  on   intensity  of  cultivation,   3 
finite  number,  and  the  transport-orientation 

problem,   101-112,   113n 
hierarchy    of,    in    realistic    space-economy, 

251 
radial,   and  urban  land-use  patterns,   11 
as  boundaries  of  sectors,  273n 
as  centers  of  sectors,  273,  273n 
size  of  market  area  as  increasing  with  dis- 
tance from,  274n 
sketches   of,    in   urban-metropolitan   region, 

270-279 
see  also   Transport  network 
Transport  system,  see  Transport  network 
Transport  technology,  advance  in,  and  acces- 
sibility of  resources,  3 In 
and  effect  on  agricultural  zones,   16,   19n 
and    effect    on    internal    development    of 

regions,  22 
and  effect  on  interregional  trade,  22 
and  geographic   specialization,   22 
state  of,  and  inter-  and  intraregional  struc- 
ture, 22 
and  urban-metropolitan  structure,  11,  12, 
19n 
see  also  Technological  advance 
Trenton     steel    location,     explanation     of,     in 
terms  of  substitution  between  trans- 
port inputs,  118n-119n 
TrifRn,    see   Monopolistic   competition,   theory 
of 

Ubiquitous   materials,    and   the   Losch   frame- 
work,  16,  274 
general  locational  effects  of,   120 
implications     of,     in     simplified     transport- 
orientation,  96n 
industries   using,   as   affected   by   urban   in- 
come, 278 
as  affected  by  urban  numbers,  278 
as  pulled  by  localized   material  using  in- 
dustries, 278 
use  of,   and  determinacy   in   locational  line 
case,   120 
Uniformity    assumptions,     in    Launhardt-Pa- 
lander  construction,  256 
inconsistency  with  hierarchy  of  sites,   153- 

154,  271 
Losch's,  and  market  area  analysis,  44,  152- 
153,  239 
and   supply  area  analysis,    155-157 
need  to  relax  in  extension  of  Losch,  153-154 
use     of     Losch's     in     Launhardt-Palander 
model,  267 
United    States,    cities    in,    rank-size    findings 
for,  56-57,  57n 
map   of  population   potential,   67 
metropolitan  regions,  rank-size  findings  on, 
56 
Unnecessary  distance,   see  Distance,   unneces- 
sary 
Urban    decentralization,    see   Decentralization 
Urban   hierarchy,   see   Hierarchy 
Urban    land    price     (rent),    increase    in,    and 
urban  diseconomies,   186 
with  city  size,  186 
relation   of,   to   accessibility,   200-205 

to  complementarity  of  land  uses,  200-205 
to  distance  from  the  core,  200-205 
to  site  competition,   200-205 


Urban    land    price     (rent) — continued 

use  of  cost  curves  to  determine,  201-202 
Urban  land  use,   along   radials,   11 

and   agricultural  land   use,   competition  be- 
tween, 281 
and  the  allocation  of  relatively  few  sites  to 

any  one  activity,  204-205 
and   the    clustering    of    economic   activities, 

204-205 
as  affected  by  accessibility,  200,  280 
as    affected    by    complementarity    of    land 

uses,  200,  280 
as  affected  by  distance  from  core,   11,   200, 

280 
as   affected  by  price  mark-up,   200-201 
as   affected  by  service  quality,   200-201 
as  affected  by  site  competition,  200,  280 
as  associated  with  population  flows,  281 
as    determined   by   rent   functions,    204-205, 

280 
as    involving    substitution    among    revenues 

and  outlays,  205-206 
as  involving  substitution  in  choice  of  prod- 
uct,  205-206 
broad  classification  of  types,  280n 
by    type,    as    yielded    by    substitution    prin- 
ciple, 281 
commercial,  as  related  to  type  of  basic  in- 
dustry, 284-285 
determinants  of,   11-12,  202-206 
effect  on,   of  journey  to  work  pattern,  281 
of   quality   competition,    281 
of  shopping  trip   pattern,   281 
increase  in  intensity  of,  and  deglomeration, 

139 
industrial,   as   related   to   type   of  basic   in- 
dustry, 284-285 
intensities    of,    and    optimum    structure    of 

cities,   183 
interdependence  of  types  of,  281,  287 
limits  to,  as  precluding  analysis  of  systems 

of  supply  areas,   158 
optimal,   as   yielded   by   substitution   princi- 
ple,  205-206,  281 
patterns  of,  as  a  fusion  of  localized  mate- 
rial   using    industries    and    modified 
Losch   market  system,    274-275,   278- 
280 
a  simple  sketch  of,  278-280 
desirable  changes  in,   183 
industrial,     commercial,     residential     and 

recreational,  278-280 
logic  for  variety  of,  206 
optimum,    need    for    improved    theory    to 

determine,   280,   287 
process  of  determination  of,  202-206 
relation  of,  to  advertising  outlays,  200-201, 
281 
to  agricultural  land  use,  281,  285 
to  distance  variable,  282-285 
to  factor  mobility,  282-285 
to   geographic   specialization,    282-285 
to   the   political   variable,   283-285 
to  trade,  282-285 
residential,   as   related   to  type  of  basic  in- 
dustry,  284-285 
restraints   imposed   on,   as   differing  among 
areas,  206 
by   cultural   values   and   institutions,   205, 

206,  280 
by  existing  physical  structures,  206 
by  physical  environment,  206,  280 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


347 


Urban   land   use — continued 
by   technology,   205,   280 
by  total  demand,  206 
by  total  Income,  206 

structure  of,   11-12 

transition  from  line  to  area  case,  205n 

use  of  average  cost  curves  to  determine, 
201-202 

use  of  marginal  cost  curves  to  determine, 
201-202 

use  of  sales  volume  curves  to  determine, 
200-201 

see  also  Urban  land-use  theory 
Urban  land-use  theory,  and  agricultural  loca- 
tion  theory,   competition   as   basic  to 
both,  205 
complementarity  as  basic  to  both,  205 
rent    functions    as    basic    to    both,    205, 

280 
some  dissimilar  forces   in,   281 

as  an  integral  part  of  general  location 
theory,  205-206 

as  implicitly  considering  transport  outlays, 
205,  280 

as  yielded  by  the  substitution  principle, 
205-206,  281 

interconnections  with  agricultural  location 
theory,  200-206,  280 

need  to  study  bonds  v(fith  agricultural  loca- 
tion  theory,   280 

sketches  shovcing  fusion  of,  with  other  lo- 
cation-market-trade theories,  256- 
285 

traditionally  excluded  from  location  theory, 
200 

transition  from  line  to  area  case,  205n 

transport  outlays  (time-cost)  by  consumers 
as  basic  to,  205,  280 

undeveloped  state  of,  280 

use  of  multicommodity  framework  in,  204- 
206 

see  also  Urban  land  use 
Urban-metropolitan     region  (s),     a     modified 
Losch  diagram  of,   272 

a  simple  Losch  diagram  of,  270 

and  decentralization  policy,   13-15 

and  distribution  of  functions,   12 

and  interactivity  relations,  11 

and  step-by-step   migration,   40-41 

applicability  of  Losch's  analytic  approach, 
154 

as  a  hierarchy  of  sites,  11-12,   183,  273 

determination  of  optimum  land-use  pat- 
terns for,  200-206 

differentials  in  land  outlays  as  major  to 
analysis  of,  189 

dispersion  within,  by  income  groups,  88n 

dynamic  processes  of  growth,  11-12 

hierarchy  of  industrial  districts  in,  278-280 

importance  of  internal  spatial  dimensions 
of,  189 

meaningful  sectors  of,   13-14,  270-273 

need  for  deeper  analysis  of,  as  a  socio- 
economic organism,  287 

population  of,  as  affected  by  basic  indus- 
tries,   11,   278 

population  pattern  and  consumer  tastes, 
144n-145n 

population  pattern  and  space  preferences, 
144n-145n,  145 

rank-size  rule  for,   56 

relocation   of  sectors,   13-15 


Urban-metropolitan      region  (s) — continued 

service  activities  as  basic  industry  in,  274n- 
275n 

sketch  of,  as  fusion  of  modified  Losch  mar- 
ket system  and  agricultural  land-use 
patterns,  272,  277-278 

sketch  of  agricultural  hinterlands  of,  276- 
278 

sketch  of  land-use  patterns  in,  278-280 

spatial  configuration  of,   11,   68-70 

specialization   among,   12 

structure  of  core  of,  12 

tie  to  basic  economic  industry,  11 

see     also     Cities  ;     City-regions ;     Regions ; 
Space-economy  ;    Urban-metropolitan 
structure ;    Urban    land    use 
Urban-metropolitan    structure,    and    aircraft, 
12,  87-88 

and  automobile  and  bus,   87-88 

and  clustering  of  economic  activities,  204- 
205 

and  fall  in  the  time  and  money  cost  of  pop- 
ulation  movement,    87-88 

and  street  and  electric  railway,  87-88 

applicability  of  Losch  approach,   154 

as  a  hierarchy  of  centers,  273 

as  fusion  of  modified  Launhardt-Palander 
and  Losch  schemes,  274-275 

as  localized  material  using  activities  plus 
market-oriented  activities,  274-275, 
278-280 

as  reflecting  the  joint  geographic  distribu- 
tion   of   economic    activities,    183-184 

as  related   to  distance  variable,   282-285 

as  related  to  factor  mobility,  282-285 

as  related  to  geographic  specialization,  282- 
285 

as  related  to  the  political  variable,  283-285 

as  related  to  trade,  282-285 

as  related  to  type  of  basic  industry,  284-285 

fluidity  of,  and  identification  of  secondary 
peaks  of  sales  volume,   201n 

impact  of  technological  change,   12-13 

importance  of  commercial  activities  in, 
200n-201n 

importance  of  retail  activities  in,  200n-201n 

interrelation  of  size  and  number  of  produc- 
tion sites  in,  273 

Losch's  simple  conception  of,  270-271 

need  for  general  equilibrium  approach  in 
determining,  201n 

need  to  develop  operational  models  of,  287 

need  to  study  relations,  with  labor  produc- 
tivity, 287 
with  location  decisions,  287 
with  regional  income,  287 
with  resources,  287 
with  tastes  and  consumption,  287 

non-existence  of  regular  hexagons  in,  274n 

some  basic  elements  of,   11-15 

study  of  restraints  on,  as  involved  in  re- 
gional science,   287 

see  also  Cities  ;  Space-economy  ;  Urban  land 
use  ;  Urban-metropolitan  region 
Urban  region,  see  Urban-metropolitan  region 
Urban    structure,    see    Urban-metropolitan 

structure 
Urbanization,  a  simple  case  of,  268-270 

analysis  as  overlapping  with  localization 
analysis,   182 

and  comparison  of  advantages  and  disad- 
vantages by  the  firm,  183,  188,  269 


348 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Urbanization — continued 
and  inflexibility  of  inherited  physical  struc- 
ture,  183 
as   substitution   between   outlays   and   reve- 
nues,  188,  269 
in  a  modified   Losch  approach,   270-275 
limited    application    of    Weber's    approach 

to,  183,  188,  269 
need   for    evolutionary    approach    in    analy- 
sis of,   183 
the     Weber-Launhardt-Palander     approach 

to,  265-270 
theory    of,    use    of    multicommodity    frame- 
work  in,    185-188,    268-270 
theory,    sketches    showing    fusion    of,    with 
other  location-market-trade  doctrines, 
256-285 
use   of    critical    isodapanes    in    analysis    of, 
183,   188 
Urbanization  economies   (diseconomies),  addi- 
tion   of,    to    modified    Launhardt-Pa- 
lander  model,  268-270 
and  interdependence  of  net  economy  curves, 

187-188 
and   need   for  research  on   interdependence 

of  net  economy  curves,  188 
and  need  for  weighting  net  economy  curves, 

186-187 
and   scale   economies   in    power   generation, 

184-185,   185n 
as    a   location    factor,    elementary    state    of 

analysis   of,    183,   268-269 
as    included     in    agglomeration     economies, 

139,    172,    265,    268 
definition  of,   172,  268 
effect    of,    on    structure    of    space-economy, 

269-270,   273-274 
from  increase  in  congestion,  183,  185,  186 
from  increase  in  living  cost,  183,  185,  186 
from  increase  in  rents,  183,  186 
from  industrial  articulation,   182-183 
in  large  lot  buying  and  selling,   182 
in    providing    a    subset    of    transportation 

services,   185 
in   providing  diverse  urban  services,    186 
in  providing  educational  services,   186 
in  providing  fire  and  police  protection,  186 
in   providing  recreational  services,   186 
in  providing  sanitation  services,  186 
in    providing    transportation    services,    185, 

273n 
in  the  generation  of  power,  184-185,  185n 
in  the  Losch  approach,  270-275 
in  the  use  of  auxiliary  facilities,  182 
in  the  use  of  skilled  labor,  182,  185 
in  the  use  of  urban  apparatus,  182 
in  transit  operations,  185-186,  273n 
in  transportation,  as  distorting  agricultural 

zones,  276-277 
incorporation  of,  in  sketches  of  fused  loca- 
tion-market-trade  doctrines,    256-285 
index   of,    as    a   sum   of   representative   net 

economy  curves,  186-187 
invalid    use    of    the    sum    of    net    economy 

curves,   188 
locational  shifts  from,  269-270 
need  for  deeper  insights  into,  287 
non-additive  character  of,   188 
overlapping     with     localization     economies, 

182,  265 
see  also  Agglomeration  economies  ;  Deglom- 
eration    economies ;    Urbanization 


Usher  and  the  historical  approach,  15,  31n 

Value  added  by  manufacture,  decrease  of, 
with  distance  from  urban  core,  68-70 

Varignon    mechanical    model,    and    transport 
cost  as  basic  location  force,   122 
use  of,  to  determine  equilibrium  of  location 
forces,   121-122 

Viner  and  the  effect  of  transport  cost  on 
trade,  215n 

Vining's  approach  to  spatial  analysis  via  dis- 
tributional stability  of  flows,   22 

von  Neumann  and  Morgenstern,  see  Game 
theory 

Vulnerability,    and    geographic   balance,    14 
and  urban  decentralization,  12 

Weber  (location  theory  of),  agglomeration 
analysis  of,  as  substitution  analysis, 
179 

agglomerative    forces    as    not    affecting    in- 
dustrial distribution   by  regions,    172 

and   assumption   of  fixed  production   coeffi- 
cients, 222 

and  assumption  of  given  prices,  222 

and  concept  of  dominant  weight,  120,  225n 

and  emphasis  on  firm  location,  92-93,  188- 
189 

and  function  of  economy  of  agglomeration, 
178 

and    limited    aggregative    analysis    within, 
92-93 

and  minimizing  ton-kilometers,  36n 

and  optimum  resource  utilization,  182 

and   size  of  agglomeration,   178 

and    the    accepted     dualism    with    Thiinen 
analysis,   92-93,    188-189,    275 

and   the   classification    of   commodities,    93- 
94,  94n 

and   the   evolutionary   approach,    15,    27-30, 
40n-41n 

and  underestimate  of  significance  of  corner 
locations,   109 

as  a  supplementary  empirical  theory,  36n- 
37n 

as  element  of  a  general  location  theory,  23 

as  a  supplement  to  a  Thiinen-Losch  model, 
16-19,   19n 

as  based  on  technical  knowledge,  36n-37n 

bound  capitalism  and  immobile  labor,  40n- 
41n 

conditions  for  agglomeration,   176-177 

criticism  of,  by  Dean,  225n 

for  ignoring  differential  bargaining  abil- 
ity in  agglomeration,   180-181 
for  ignoring  historical  process  in  agglom- 
eration,  180 
for  ignoring  relocation  costs,   180 

criticism  of  trade  theory,  50,  53,  208 

criticism  of  trade  theory  as  met,  217 

decrease    in    validity    of    assumptions    with 
size  of  agglomeration,    179n 

definition   of  critical  isodapane  in   agglom- 
eration  analysis,    176n 

definition  of  isodapane,    130n 

determination     of     agglomeration      center, 
177-178,   265-270 

emphasis  on  cost  conditions,  210n 

emphasis   on   distance   variable  by   assump- 
tion of  constant  weights,  96,  222-223 

emphasis  on  transport-orientation  in  inter- 
national trade,   50,   53,   208 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


349 


Weber    (location   theory  of) — continued 

exceptions  to  conditions  for  agglomeration, 
178-179 

failure  to  distinguish  types  of  agglomera- 
tion, 176 

failure  to  treat  market  area  analysis,  143n, 
260 

firm  analysis  in,  as  applicable  to  farm  en- 
terprise, 189-190,   196-197,  275 

free  capitalism  and  mobile  labor,  40n-41n 

fusion  of,  with  production  theory,  91,  118- 
119 

greater  validity  for  German  economy,  109n 

inability  to  encompass  realistic  rate  struc- 
tures,  108,   109 

incorporation  with  Thiinen  analysis  in  one 
framework,   92-93,   188-189,  275 

invalidity  of  certain  criticisms  of,   92-93 

invalidity  of  the  use  of  fictitious  distances, 
109,   109n 

labor  cost  differentials  as  determining  in- 
dustrial distribution  by  regions,  172 

labor  locations  as  centers  of  agglomera- 
tions, 179 

limited  analysis  of  urbanization  economies, 
182-183 

limited  application  of  agglomeration  analy- 
sis  of,    179,   268-269 

limited  application  to  urbanization  analysis, 
183,   188,  268-269 

mathematical   formulation    of,    222-230 

modified,    fusion    of    in    a    location-market- 
production  doctrine,  222-253 
fusion  of  in  a  location-market-trade  doc- 
trine, 256-285 

need  to  integrate  with  competitive  loca- 
tional  equilibrium,  170 

overestimate  of  pull  of  weight-losing  ma- 
terials in,   225n 

propositions  of,  for  line  case  as  derived  via 
transformation  and  price-ratio  lines, 
119-120 

reformulation  of  labor  orientation  doctrine, 
127-131,   141-142 

reformulation  of  transport-orientation  doc- 
trine. 96-112,  211-215,  281-282 

relative  neglect  of  demand,   210n 

role  of   agglomeration   in,    172-188 

role  of  replacement  deposits  in  labor  orien- 
tation,  131n,   135 

sketches  showing  fusion  of,  with  other  loca- 
tion-market-trade   doctrines,    256-285 

sketch  of  his  industrial  location  problem, 
28n,  104n 

strength  in  treating  localized  raw  mate- 
rials, 158,  274 

transport  cost  differentials  as  determining 
industrial  distribution  by  region,  172 

underestimate  of  pull  of  pure  materials  in, 
225n 

use  by,   Ohlin,  52 

use   of   critical   isodapane,    130-131 

use  of   labor  coefficient,    141-142 

use  of  side  payment  to  induce  agglomera- 
tion,  179n 

valid  use  of  ideal  weights  to  adjust  for 
commodity   rates,    109n 

validity   of   agglomeration    analysis    of,    for 
new  area  development,   179,   181-192, 
268 
for  regional  planning,  181-182,  182n,  268 

value  for  general  location  theory,  36n-37n 


Weber  (location  theory  of) — continued 

value  for   iron   and   steel  location   analysis, 

37n 
see  also  Agglomeration  theoi-y  ;  Labor  orien- 
tation ;  Transport-orientation 
Weight  (s),  actual,   and   price-ratio  lines,   104 
and    the   concept    of    transport    inputs,    35, 

79,   113-114,  222 
as  a  variable  in  transport-orientation  analy- 
sis,  113,  222-223 
ideal,   see  Ideal  weights 

relative,     as    determining    slope    of    price- 
ratio   lines,    104 
effect  on  firm's  equilibrium  location,   104 
see  also  Weight  triangle 
Weight    loss,    and    determinacy    in    the    line 
case,   120 
and    substitution     possibilities     in     location 

analysis,  94 
general   locational  effect  of,   120 
in  the  classification  of  commodities,  93-94 
infinite,  and  immobile  commodities,  32n,  94 
overemphasis  of,  by  Weber,   225n 
Weight  triangle,   as  a  counterpart  to   Varig- 
non  mechanical  model,   121 
as     a     shortcut     to     determine    equilibrium 

point,   122 
existence    of,    and    the    generalized    index, 
121 
and  the  material  index,   120-121 
failure  to   identify   transport  cost  as   basic 

economic  force,    122 
less  flexible  than  isodapane  technique,  122n 
need  to  use  ideal  weights,   122n 
nonexistence    of,    when    a    weight   is    domi- 
nant,  120-121,   258n 
restricted  use  of,  122n 

use    of,    in    Launhardt-Palander    construc- 
tion,  256-258 
in     transport-orientation     problem,     120- 

122,   256-258 
to     determine     equilibrium     of     location 
forces,   121-122,   256-258 
Weigmann,   and   structure   of   markets,   39-41 
concept  of  basic  form,  38-42 
concept   of   competition   field,   38-39 
concept  of  quantity  elasticity,   42n 
concept  of  statics   and  dynamics,   38-41 
contribution  to  general  location  theory,  37- 

42,   54 
criticism  of  classical  trade  theory,   208 
principle  of  limited  competition,  37-39 
total    localization    theory,    41n-42n 
use   of  Gestalt  analysis,   38-42 
Welfare,  analysis  of,   invalidity  of  pure  com- 
petition  norms  in,   50n 
need  for  monopolistic  competition  theory 
in,  50 
individual,    conflict    with    optimum    spatial 

patterns,  23 
social,    and   production   concentration   from 
scale   economies,    174 
and  shift  of  consumer  allegiance,  147-152 
and  shift  of  supply  sources  among  pro- 
ducers,  157 
and   substitution   among   production   out- 
lays at  several  sources,   155-157,   262 
and  substitution  among  transport  inputs 
on    materials    from    several    sources, 
155-157,  262 
and  substitution  between  production  and 
transport   outlays,   182,  262 


350 


SUBJECT  INDEX 


Welfare — continued 

and    substitution    between    transport    in- 
puts in  different  directions,  147 
and    substitution    between    transport    in- 
puts on   products  of  two  producers, 
147-148 
and    the    use    of    Weber's    agglomeration 

analysis,   182 
approach  of,  as  yielding  clearest  localiza- 
tion analysis,  268 
in  simplified  market  cases,   232-238 
maximization  of,  with  hexagonal  market 

patterns,    153,   252 
need  to  study  spatial  aspects  of,  287 
optimum  as  different  from  minimization 

of  transport  cost,  232n 
problems  in  defining,  236n 
see  also  Surplus,  social 
Wholesale    sales,    decrease    of,    with    distance 

from  urban   core,   68-70 
Williams'  criticism  of  mobility  and  immobility 

premises  of  trade  theory,  208 
Women  labor,  see  Labor,  cheap 

Zeuthen  as  bearing  out  Hotelling's  solutions 
on  competitive  locational  equilibrium, 
160 
Zipf,  and  concentrative  effects  of  innovation, 
79n 
and  Principle  of  Least  Effort,  60,  78n-79n 
empirical  findings  on  rank-size  rule,   56-57 
explanation  of  spatial  framework,  78n-79n 
Forces    of    Unification    and    Diversification, 

60,  78n-79n 
inconsistency    of,    and    deposits    of    highly 

localized  raw  materials,   79n 
interpretation     of     deviations     from     rank- 
size  rule,  57n 
needed  extensions  of,  79n 
number    of    families    moving    varying    dis- 
tances, 63-64 
on  length  and  number  of  one-way  passen- 
ger car  trips,  62n 
on    length    and    number    of    one-way    truck 

trips,  62n 
on    number   of   marriage   licenses    and   dis- 
tance  separating   applicants,   62n 
the    P/D    factor    and    charge    accounts    of 

Jordan  Marsh  Co.,  62n 
the  Pi  •  P2/D  factor,  and  airway  passenger 
movements,  62  n 
and  average  circulation   per   day  of   The 

New   York  Times,  62n 
and  bus   passenger  movements,   61-63 
and   number   of   different   news   items   in 

The  Chicago  Tribune,  62n 
and    number    of    obituaries    in    The   New 

York  Times,  62n 
and   railway   express   shipments,    60-61 
and  railway  passenger  movements,  62n 
and  telephone  messages,  61-62 
Zonal   boundaries,   as   defined  by   equation   of 
marginal  rents  on  two  crops,  247 


Zonal    boundaries — continued 

as    defined    by    intersection    of    rent    func- 
tions, 247,  276 
determination  of  equations  of,  246-247 
forces    generating    irregularities    in,    276- 

277 
multiplication  of,  when  each  farm  produces 

unique  crop   combination,   248 
shifts    of,    along    substitution    paths,    246- 
247 
as   involving  substitution  between   trans- 
port inputs,   246n 
simple  form  of  equations  of,  246-247 
see  also  Zone  formation 
Zone(s),  concentric,  3,  5,  33n,  52 

as  cut  off  by  city-region  boundaries,  249n, 

276-277 
as   distorted   by   legal   and   social   institu- 
tions, 276 
as  distorted  by  physical  barriers,  276 
as  distorted  by  raw  material  supply,  248, 

276 
as  distorted  by  resource  content  of  land, 

276 
as  distorted  by  scale  economies  in  trans- 
portation, 276-277 
as   distorted   by  transport  network,   276- 
277 
finite    number    of    production    points    as    a 

special  case  of,  250n 
for   a   given    commodity    as   reducible   to   a 

finite   number   of  points,    250n 
intensity  of  land  use  among,   as   rising  or 
falling    with    distance    from    market, 
247n-248n 
more   precise    determination    of,    with    firm 

equilibrium  analysis,   199 
multiple,  existence  of  for  single  crop  when 

not  classified  by  market,   250n 
multiplication    of,    when    each    farm    pro- 
duces unique  crop  combination,  248 
transition  of,  3,  4,  5,  8,  16,   18,  19 
see  also  Agricultural  land  use  ;  Zonal  boun- 
daries ;  Zone  formation 
Zone    formation,    and    advance    in    transport 
technology,   16 
and  interrelations  of  strata,  29 
and  Losch's  framework,   16 
and  the  development  process,  3-6,  8 
as  obtainable  from  analysis  along  a  straight 

line  from  a  city,  245n,  248n 
concentric,   as  yielded  by  the  general  loca- 
tion   principle,    244-246 
based    on    invariance    of    transport    rate 

with   direction   from   city,    245 
implied  by  substitution  principle,  244-245 
identification  of,   by  use  of  rent  functions, 

195,  199 
logic  of,  244-251 
role  of  competition  in,   198-199 
role  of  price  change  in,  243 
substitution    between    transport    inputs    in, 
246n 


AUG? 


2  '57 


Date    Due 


Library  West  /ALF 
Date  Due  Slip 

Date  Due  Date  Returned 


JA^J  0  9  ?f^?g- 


THnrnnDT 


Online  Renewal  @  http://www.uflib.ufl.edu/ 

A  fine  of  25  cent,  per  day  «  Charged  w^en  th«  rtem  »  ov«^ie____ 


e 


Location  and  space-economy,  a  genera  afa 
3381761 


3  laba  D2171  7D11 


ARCH  « 
AllJEO  ARTS 


'^^'^OUAGE 


Mo